The Ottoman Empire was founded in the early fourteenth century by
Osman I, a prince of Asia Minor who began pushing the eastern border of
the Byzantine Empire westward toward Constantinople. Present-day
European Turkey and the Balkans, among the first territories conquered,
were used as bases for expansion far to the West during the fifteenth
and sixteenth centuries. The capture of Constantinople in 1453 completed
Ottoman subjugation of major Bulgarian political and cultural
institutions. Nevertheless, certain Bulgarian groups prospered in the
highly ordered Ottoman system, and Bulgarian national traditions
continued in rural areas. When the decline of the Ottoman Empire began
about 1600, the order of local institutions gave way to arbitrary
repression, which eventually generated armed opposition. Western ideas
that penetrated Bulgaria during the 1700s stimulated a renewed concept
of Bulgarian nationalism that eventually combined with decay in the
empire to loosen Ottoman control in the nineteenth century.
Introduction of the Ottoman System
Ottoman forces captured the commercial center of Sofia in 1385.
Serbia, then the strongest Christian power in the Balkans, was
decisively defeated by the Ottomans at the Battle of Kosovo Polje in
1389, leaving Bulgaria divided and exposed. Within ten years, the last
independent Bulgarian outpost was captured. Bulgarian resistance
continued until 1453, when the capture of Constantinople gave the
Ottomans a base from which to crush local uprisings. In consolidating
its Balkan territories, the new Ottoman political order eliminated the
entire Bulgarian state apparatus. The Ottomans also crushed the nobility
as a landholding class and potential center of resistance. The new
rulers reorganized the Bulgarian church, which had existed as a separate
patriarchate since 1235, making it a diocese under complete control of
the Byzantine Patriarchate at Constantinople. The sultan, in turn,
totally controlled the patriarchate.
The Ottomans ruled with a centralized system much different from the
scattered local power centers of the Second Bulgarian Empire. The single
goal of Ottoman policy in Bulgarian territory was to make all local
resources available to extend the empire westward toward Vienna and
across northern Africa. Landed estates were given in fiefdom to knights
bound to serve the sultan. Peasants paid multiple taxes to both their
masters and the government. Territorial control also meant cultural and
religious assimilation of the populace into the empire. Ottoman
authorities forcibly converted the most promising Christian youths to
Islam and trained them for government service. Called pomaks,
such converts often received special privileges and rose to high
administrative and military positions. The Ottoman system also
recognized the value of Bulgarian artisans, who were organized and given
limited autonomy as a separate class. Some prosperous Bulgarian peasants
and merchants became intermediaries between local Turkish authorities
and the peasants. In this capacity, these chorbadzhi (squires)
were able to moderate Ottoman policy. On the negative side, the Ottoman
assimilation policy also included resettlement of Balkan Slavs in Asia
Minor and immigration of Turkish peasants to farm Bulgarian land. Slavs
also were the victims of mass enslavement and forcible mass conversion
to Islam in certain areas.
Bulgarian Society under the Turks
Traditional Bulgarian culture survived only in the smaller villages
during the centuries of Ottoman rule. Because the administrative
apparatus of the Ottoman Empire included officials of many
nationalities, commerce in the polyglot empire introduced Jews,
Armenians, Dalmatians, and Greeks into the chief population centers.
Bulgarians in such centers were forcibly resettled as part of a policy
to scatter the potentially troublesome educated classes. The villages,
however, were often ignored by the centralized Ottoman authorities,
whose control over the Turkish landholders often exerted a modifying
influence that worked to the advantage of the indigenous population.
Village church life also felt relatively little impact from the
centralized authority of the Greek Orthodox Church. Therefore, between
the fourteenth and seventeenth centuries, the villages became isolated
repositories of Bulgarian folk culture, religion, social institutions,
and language.
Early Decay and Upheaval in the Empire
Notable Bulgarian uprisings against the Ottomans occurred in the
1590s, the 1680s and the 1730s; all sought to take advantage of external
crises of the empire, and all were harshly suppressed. Beginning in the
1600s, local bandits, called hajduti (sing., hajdutin),
led small uprisings. Some writers now describe these uprisings as
precursors of a Bulgarian nationalist movement. Most scholars agree,
however, that hajdutin activities responded only to local
misrule and their raids victimized both Christians and Muslims. Whatever
their motivation, hajdutin exploits became a central theme of
national folk culture.
By 1600 the Ottoman Empire had reached the peak of its power and
territorial control. In the seventeenth century, the empire began to
collapse; the wealth of conquest had spread corruption through the
political system, vitiating the ability of the central government to
impose order throughout the farflung empire. For the majority of people
in agricultural Bulgaria, centralized Ottoman control had been far from
intolerable while the empire was orderly and strong. But the growing
despotism of local authorities as the central government declined
created a new class of victims. Increasingly, Bulgarians welcomed the
progressive Western political ideas that reached them through the Danube
trade and travel routes. Already in the 1600s, Catholic missionaries in
western Bulgaria had stimulated creation of literature about Bulgaria's
national past. Although the Turks suppressed this Western influence
after the Chiprovets uprising of 1688, the next century brought an
outpouring of historical writings reminding Bulgarian readers of a
glorious national heritage.
Bulgaria - NATIONAL REVIVAL, EARLY STAGES
Revolution in the Balkans
In 1804 Serbia began a series of uprisings that won it autonomy
within the Ottoman Empire by 1830. Especially in the campaigns of 1804
and 1815, many Bulgarians in areas adjacent to Serbia fought beside the
Serbs. When the Greeks revolted against Turkish rule in 1821, Bulgarian
towns provided money and soldiers. Several hundred Bulgarians fought in
the six-year Greek uprising, some of them as commanders, and some became
part of the government of independent Greece. Bulgarians also fought the
Turks in Crete, with the Italian revolutionary Giuseppe Garibaldi, and
in other nationalist uprisings against the Habsburgs in 1848-49. In
spite of Bulgarian sympathy for national liberation movements nearby,
and although the ideals of those movements permeated the Balkans from
1804 on, the anarchy of the early 1800s confined expression of Bulgarian
national feeling primarily to the cultural realm until the 1860s.
Cultural Expressions of Nationalism
In 1824 Dr. Petur Beron, a member of the Bulgarian emigrant community
in Romania, published the first primer in colloquial Bulgarian. His book
also explained a new system of secular education to replace the outdated
precepts of monastery pedagogy, and Beron's suggestions strongly
influenced the development of Bulgarian education in the nineteenth
century. In 1835 a school was opened in Gabrovo according to Beron's
design. Under direction of the monk Neofit Rilski, it was the first
school to teach in Bulgarian. Similar schools opened in the ensuing
years, and in 1840 the first school for girls opened in Pleven.
Education grew especially fast in trading towns such as Koprivshtitsa
and Kalofer in the foothills of the Balkans, where textiles and other
trades created a wealthy merchant class. In the 1840s, the first
generation of Western-educated Bulgarians returned home. Forming a
cosmopolitan intelligentsia, they diversified and expanded Bulgarian
schools in the following decades.
In the first half of the 1800s, special educational and cultural ties
developed with Russia and France. In 1840 the Russian government began
awarding grants for Bulgarian students to study in Russia. The total
number of students in the Russian program was never high, but several
graduates were leaders in the independence drive of the 1870s. Several
notable Bulgarians of that generation also were educated in France and
at Robert College, founded as a missionary institution in
Constantinople.
Parallel with educational advancement, Bulgarian book printing
advanced substantially after 1830. Before that date only seventeen
original Bulgarian titles had been printed; but by mid-century, printing
had replaced manuscript copying as the predominant means of distributing
the written word. The first periodical was printed in Bulgarian in 1844,
beginning an outpouring of mostly ephemeral journals through the
nineteenth century. Censorship before 1878 meant that the majority of
such journals were printed in the Romanian emigrant centers, outside the
Ottoman Empire. Most Bulgarian-language periodicals printed within the
empire came from Constantinople, showing the cultural importance of that
city to the Bulgarian National Revival. After 1850 Bulgarian �migr�
periodicals, supporting a wide variety of political views toward the
national independence movement, played a vital role in stimulating
Bulgarian political consciousness.
In the mid-1800s, a number of cultural and charitable organizations
founded in Constantinople supported and directed Bulgarian national
institutions that resisted Ottoman and Greek influence. The social
institution of the chitalishte (literally "reading
room") played an important cultural role beginning in 1856.
Established in population centers by adult education societies, the chitalishte
was a center for social gatherings, lectures, performances, and debates.
Because it was available to the entire public, this institution spread
national cultural and political ideals beyond the intelligentsia to the
larger society. By 1878 there were 131 such centers.
The Bulgarian National Revival also stimulated the arts in the
nineteenth century. Dobri Chintulov wrote the first poetry in modern
Bulgarian in the 1840s, pioneering a national literary revival that
peaked in the 1870s. Translation of Western European and Russian
literature accelerated, providing new influences that broke centuries of
rigid formalism. Painting and architecture now also broke from the
prescribed forms of Byzantine church art to express secular and folk
themes. Bulgarian wood-carving and church singing assumed the forms that
survive today.
Religious Independence
The Bulgarian church achieved new independence in the nineteenth
century. The Ottoman Empire had left the Bulgarian church hierarchy
under the Greek Patriarchate of Constantinople for four centuries,
disregarding the differences between the two Orthodox churches. (The
last separate Bulgarian church jurisdiction, the archbishopric of Ohrid,
was absorbed in 1767.) Early in the 1800s, few of the Bulgarian church
leaders most closely connected with Enlightenment ideas sought
separation from the Greek Orthodox Church. But in 1839, a movement began
against the Greek Metropolitan of Turnovo, head of the largest Bulgarian
diocese, in favor of local control. In 1849 the active Bulgarian
community of Constantinople began pressing Turkish officials for church
sovereignty. Other large Bulgarian dioceses both inside and outside
Bulgaria sought a return to liturgy in the vernacular and appointment of
Bulgarian bishops. The first concession came in 1848, when the Greek
patriarch of Constantinople allowed one Bulgarian church in that city.
Because a decade of petitions, demonstrations, and Ottoman reform
suggestions had brought no major change, in 1860 Bishop Ilarion
Makariopolski of Constantinople declared his diocese independent of the
Greek patriarchate. This action began a movement for ecclesiastical
independence that united rural and urban Bulgarians and began a bitter
Greek-Bulgarian dispute. The Turks and the Russians began to mediate in
1866, seeking a compromise that would ensure the security of each in the
face of increasing regional unrest. In 1870 the Ottoman sultan
officially declared the Bulgarian church a separate exarchate. The Greek
patriarchate, which never recognized the separation, excommunicated the
entire Bulgarian church; but the symbolism of the Ottoman decree had
powerful political effect. The new exarchate became the leading force in
Bulgarian cultural life; it officially represented the Bulgarians in
dealing with the Turks, and it sponsored Bulgarian schools. The novel
administrative system of the exarchate called for lay representation in
governing bodies, thus introducing a note of self-government into this
most visible institution.
Early Insurrections
The social and cultural events of the National Revival moved parallel
to important political changes. Bulgarian aid to the Russians in the
Russo-Turkish wars of 1806-12 and 1828-29 did nothing to loosen Ottoman
control. Then the Ottoman Empire ruthlessly quelled major Bulgarian
uprisings in 1835 (in Turnovo), 1841 (in Nis), and in 1850-51 (in
Vidin). Those uprisings still bore the disorganized qualities of the hajduti,
but, together with smaller movements in intervening years, they
established a tradition of insurrection for the next generation.
Meanwhile, beset by European enemies and internal revolutions, the Turks
entered a reform period in 1826. They replaced the elite but
increasingly untrustworthy Janissary forces with a regular army and
officially abolished the feudal land system. These changes reduced
oppression by the local Turkish rulers in Bulgaria. In the 1830s, Sultan
Mahmud II recentralized and reorganized his government to gain control
over his corrupt officials and follow European administrative models.
Although these changes had little direct effect on Bulgaria, they
clearly signaled to the Slavic subjects of the empire that reform was
now possible.
Balkan Politics of the Mid-Nineteenth Century
By 1850 the emerging Bulgarian nationalist movement had split into
two distinct branches. The moderates, concentrated in Constantinople,
favored gradual improvement of conditions in Bulgaria through
negotiations with the Turkish government. This was the approach that
created a separate Bulgarian exarchate in 1870. This group believed that
the protection of the Ottoman Empire was necessary because a free
Bulgaria would be subject to Balkan politics and great-power
manipulation. The radical faction, however, saw no hope of gradual
reform. Following their understanding of European liberal tradition and
Russian revolutionary thought, the leaders of this faction aimed first
for liberation from all outside controls. Liberation, they believed,
would automatically lead to complete modernization of Bulgarian society.
The crushing of the large-scale Vidin peasant revolt in 1851 brought
intervention by Britain and France, who bolstered and protected the
Ottoman Empire throughout the nineteenth century as a counterweight to
Russian expansion. To prevent destabilizing unrest, Britain and France
forced the Turks to introduce land reform in western Bulgaria in the
early 1850s and a series of major social reforms in 1856 and 1876.
Nominally, those measures included equal treatment for non-Muslims in
the empire and parliamentary representation for Bulgarians and Serbs.
These changes, however, were the cosmetic product of Turkey's need for
Western support in major wars with Russia. They did nothing to blunt the
nationalist drive of the Bulgarian radicals.
The First Independence Organizations
In 1862 Georgi Rakovski assembled the first armed group of Bulgarians
having the avowed goal of achieving independence from the Ottoman
Empire. Rakovski, well-educated and experienced in the 1841 uprising and
the drive for ecclesiastical independence, envisioned a federal republic
including all Balkan nations except Greece. His fighters were to stir a
full-scale national uprising after crossing into Bulgaria from assembly
points in Romania and Serbia. But the Serbs, who had supported the
Bulgarians while they were useful in opposing the Turks, disbanded the
Bulgarian legions in Serbia when they no longer served that purpose.
Although Rakovski died in 1867 without achieving Bulgarian independence,
he united the �migr� intelligentsia, and the presence of his army
influenced Turkish recognition of the Bulgarian church in 1870.
The Bulgarian Secret Central Committee, founded by �migr�
Bulgarians in Bucharest in 1866, continued Rakovski's mission under the
leadership of Vasil Levski and Liuben Karavelov. These ideologues
refined Rakovski's idea of armed revolutionary groups, creating a cadre
of intellectuals who would prepare the people to rise for independence.
Beginning in 1868, Levski founded the first revolutionary committees in
Bulgaria. Captured by the Turks, he became a national hero when he was
hanged in 1873. In 1870 Karavelov founded the Bulgarian Revolutionary
Central Committee (BRCC) in Bucharest. The death of Levski temporarily
shattered the group, but the committee resumed its activities when
Georgi Benkovski joined its leadership in 1875. By this time, the
political atmosphere of the Balkans was charged with revolution, and the
Ottoman Empire looked increasingly vulnerable. Britain, Russia, and
Austria-Hungary were growing concerned about the implications of those
trends for the European balance of power. In 1875 Bosnia and Hercegovina
revolted successfully against the Turks, and the next year Serbia and
Montenegro attacked the Ottoman Empire.
The Final Move to Independence
In the early 1870s, the BRCC had built an intricate revolutionary
organization, recruiting thousands of ardent patriots for the liberation
struggle. Finally, in 1875 the committee believed that external
distractions had weakened the Ottoman Empire enough to activate that
struggle. Local revolutionary committees in Bulgaria attempted to
coordinate the timing and strategy of a general revolt. Armed groups
were to enter Bulgaria from abroad to support local uprisings, and
diversionary attacks on Ottoman military installations were planned.
Despite these efforts at coordination, the BRCC strategy failed.
Although planned as a general revolt, the September Uprising of 1875
occurred piecemeal in isolated locations, and several local
revolutionary leaders failed to mobilize any forces. The Turks easily
suppressed the uprising, but the harshness of their response attracted
the attention of Western Europe; from that time, the fate of Bulgaria
became an international issue.
Following the failure of the September Uprising, Benkovski
reorganized the BRCC and made plans for a new revolt. The April Uprising
of 1876 was more widespread, but it also suffered from poor
coordination. Poor security allowed the Turks to locate and destroy many
local groups before unified action was possible. Massacres at Batak and
other towns further outraged international opinion by showing the
insincerity of recent Turkish reform proposals. The deaths of an
estimated 30,000 Bulgarians in these massacres spurred the Bulgarian
national movement. An international conference in Constantinople
produced proposals to curb the Muslim fanaticism responsible for the
Bulgarian massacres and give local self-government to the Christians on
European territory in the empire. Two autonomous Bulgarian regions were
proposed, one centered at Sofia and the other at Turnovo. When the
sultan rejected the reforms, Russia declared war unilaterally in early
1877. This was Russia's golden opportunity to gain control of Western
trade routes to its southwest and finally destroy the empire that had
blocked this ambition for centuries. Shocked by the Turkish massacres,
Britain did not oppose Russian advances.
San Stefano, Berlin, and Independence
In eight months, Russian troops occupied all of Bulgaria and reached
Constantinople. At this high point of its influence on Balkan affairs,
Russia dictated the Treaty of San Stefano in March 1878. This treaty
provided for an autonomous Bulgarian state (under Russian protection)
almost as extensive as the First Bulgarian Empire, bordering the Black
and Aegean seas. But Britain and Austria-Hungary, believing that the new
state would extend Russian influence too far into the Balkans, exerted
strong diplomatic pressure that reshaped the Treaty of San Stefano four
months later into the Treaty of Berlin. The new Bulgaria would be about
onethird the size of that prescribed by the Treaty of San Stefano;
Macedonia and Thrace, south of the Balkans, would revert to complete
Ottoman control. The province of Eastern Rumelia would remain under
Turkish rule, but with a Christian governor.
Whereas the Treaty of San Stefano called for two years of Russian
occupation of Bulgaria, the Treaty of Berlin reduced the time to nine
months. Both treaties provided for an assembly of Bulgarian notables to
write a constitution for their new country. The assembly would also
elect a prince who was not a member of a major European ruling house and
who would recognize the authority of the Ottoman sultan. In cases of
civil disruption, the sultan retained the right to intervene with armed
force.
The final provisions for Bulgarian liberation fell far short of the
goals of the national liberation movement. Large populations of
Bulgarians remained outside the new nation in Macedonia, Eastern
Rumelia, and Thrace, causing resentment that endured well into the next
century. (Bulgarians still celebrate the signing of the Treaty of San
Stefano rather than the Treaty of Berlin as their national independence
day.) In late 1878, a provisional Bulgarian government and armed
uprisings had already surfaced in the Kresna and Razlog regions of
Macedonia. These uprisings were quelled swiftly by the Turks with
British support. During the next twenty-five years, large numbers of
Bulgarians fled Macedonia into the new Bulgaria, and secret liberation
societies appeared in Macedonia and Thrace. One such group, the Internal
Macedonian Revolutionary Organization (IMRO), continued terrorist
activities in the Balkans into the 1930s.
Bulgaria - DECADES OF NATIONAL CONSOLIDATION
Despite strong dissatisfaction with the frontiers imposed by the
European powers, a new Bulgarian state was born in 1878. And despite
early political uncertainty, the first thirty-four years of modern
Bulgaria were in many ways its most prosperous and productive.
Forming the New State
In 1879 a constituent assembly was duly convened in Turnovo. Partly
elected and partly appointed, the assembly of 230 split into
conservative and liberal factions similar to those that had existed
before independence. The liberals advocated continuing the alliance of
peasants and intelligentsia that had formed the independence movement,
to be symbolized in a single parliamentary chamber; the conservatives
argued that the Bulgarian peasant class was not ready for political
responsibility, and therefore it should be represented in a second
chamber with limited powers. The framework for the Turnovo constitution
was a draft submitted by the Russian occupation authorities, based on
the constitutions of Serbia and Romania. As the assembly revised that
document, the liberal view prevailed; a one-chamber parliament or subranie
would be elected by universal male suffrage. Between the annual fall
sessions of the subranie, the country would be run jointly by
the monarch and a council of ministers responsible to parliament. The
liberals who dominated the assembly incorporated many of their
revolutionary ideals into what became one of the most liberal
constitutions of its time. The final act of the Turnovo assembly was the
election of Alexander of Battenburg, a young German nobleman who had
joined the Russians in the war of 1877, to be the first prince of modern
Bulgaria.
From the beginning of his reign, Alexander opposed the liberal wing
in Bulgaria and the Turnovo constitution. After two years of conflict
with the liberal council of ministers headed by Dragan Tsankov,
Alexander received Russian backing to replace Tsankov. When the Russian
Tsar Alexander II was assassinated, Russian policy changed to allow a
grand national assembly to consider the constitutional changes desired
by Prince Alexander. The assassination had spurred conservatism in
Russia, and the Bulgarian liberals had alarmed the Russians by refusing
foreign economic aid in the early 1880s. To the dismay of the liberals,
Russia intervened in the election of the constitutional subranie,
frightening voters into electing a group that passed the entire package
of amendments. Liberal influence was sharply reduced by amendments
limiting the power of the subranie. But, because the
conservative approach to governing Bulgaria had little popular support,
Alexander made a series of compromises with liberal positions between
1881 and 1885. The Turnovo constitution was essentially restored by
agreement between Tsankov and the conservatives in 1883, and the
constitutional issue was resolved. In only the first two years of
Bulgaria's existence, two parliaments and seven cabinets had been
dissolved, but more stable times lay ahead.
By 1884 the conservative faction had left the government, but the
liberals split over the high price of purchasing the Ruse-Varna Railway
from the British, as required by the Treaty of Berlin. As on earlier
issues, the more radical faction sought to reduce the influence of the
European powers who had imposed the Treaty of Berlin. This group was led
by Petko Karavelov, brother of revolutionary leader Liuben Karavelov and
prime minister in the mid-1880s.
The most important issue of that period was Bulgaria's changing
relationship with Russia. Bulgarian hostility towards the Russian army,
refusal to build a strategic railway for the Russians through Bulgaria,
and poor relations between Prince Alexander and Tsar Alexander III of
Russia all contributed to increasing alienation. Because conservative
Russia now feared unrest in the Balkans, Karavelov tried to appease the
tsar by quelling the uprisings that continued in Macedonia. Radical
factions in Bulgaria were persuaded to lower their goals from annexation
of Macedonia and Thrace to a union between Bulgaria and Eastern Rumelia.
When a bloodless coup achieved this union in 1885, however, Russia
demanded the ouster of Prince Alexander and withdrew all Russian
officers from the Bulgarian army. Greece and Serbia saw their interests
threatened, and the latter declared war on Bulgaria.
The Bulgarian army won a brilliant victory over Serbia, with no
Russian aid, at the Battle of Slivnitsa. Although the victory was a
source of great national pride for Bulgaria, Russia continued to
withhold recognition of the union with Eastern Rumelia until Prince
Alexander abdicated. Finally, Russian-trained Bulgarian army officers
deposed the prince in August 1886.
The Stambolov Years
When Alexander left behind a three-man regency headed by Stefan
Stambolov, the Bulgarian government was as unstable as it was in its
first year. A Russian-educated liberal, Stambolov became prime minister
in 1887 and ceased tailoring Bulgarian policy to Russian requirements.
The tsar's special representative in Bulgaria returned to Russia after
failing to block a subranie called to nominate a new prince.
Russo-Bulgarian relations remained chilly for the next ten years, and
this break further destabilized Bulgarian politics and society.
Stambolov brutally suppressed an army uprising in 1887 and began seven
years of iron control that often bypassed the country's democratic
institutions but brought unprecedented stability to Bulgaria. Meanwhile,
Ferdinand of SaxeCoburg -Gotha, a Catholic German prince, accepted the
Bulgarian throne in August 1887.
Independence from the Ottoman Empire brought drastic economic and
social changes to Bulgaria at the end of the nineteenth century.
Industrialization proceeded rapidly (thirty-six major factories opened
between 1878 and 1887), and a new class of industrial labor formed from
displaced artisans and agricultural workers. Harsh working conditions
led the urban poor to the cause of socialism, and in 1891 the Social
Democratic Party was formed. (Later transformation of one of its
factions into the Bulgarian Communist Party made that organization the
oldest communist party in the world.) Town-centered trade and the guild
structure were swept away by an influx of West European commerce to
which Bulgaria had been opened by the terms of the Treaty of Berlin.
Despite industrialization, Bulgaria remained primarily an
agricultural country. Liberation eliminated the Ottoman feudal
landholding system. Bulgarian peasants were able to buy land cheaply or
simply occupy it after Turkish landlords left, and a system of
village-based small landholding began. Agricultural production rose in
spite of heavy government land taxes. Many peasants were forced into the
urban work force by taxes or high interest on borrowings for land
purchase. Until the end of the nineteenth century, the vast majority of
the Bulgarian population were small landholders or independent small
tradesmen.
Russia and the other great powers did not recognize Ferdinand as
rightful prince of Bulgaria until 1896. Supporters of Prince Alexander
who remained in power used this failure as a weapon against the policies
of Ferdinand and Stambolov. In 1890 a widespread plot against the
government was discovered. As before, the basis of the plot was
dissatisfaction with Stambolov's refusal to intercede with the Turks on
behalf of Macedonian independence. In a masterful diplomatic stroke,
Stambolov represented the insurrection to the Turks as an example of
potential chaos that could be avoided by minor concessions. Fearing the
Balkan instability that would follow an overthrow of Ferdinand, the
Turks then ceded three major Macedonian dioceses to the Bulgarian
exarchate. Stambolov thus gained solid church support and an
overwhelming victory in the 1890 election, which legitimized his
government among all Bulgarian factions and reduced the threat of
radical plots.
In the next years, Stambolov and the People's Liberal Party he had
founded in 1886 exerted virtually dictatorial power to suppress extreme
nationalism and opposing parties and create conditions for economic
growth. After the 1886 coup, the army was strictly controlled. Voters
were intimidated to ensure the reelection of incumbent officials, and
political patronage grew rampant. Using his own and Ferdinand's ties
with Germany and Austria-Hungary, Stambolov built a capitalist Bulgarian
economic system on foreign loans, protectionism, an expanded industrial
and transport infrastructure, and a strict tax system for capital
accumulation. Especially important to the Bulgarian economy were
completion of the Vienna-to-Constantinople Railway through Bulgaria in
1888 and the Burgas-Yambol Railway in the early 1890s. Stambolov derived
strong political support from the entrepreneurs who benefited from his
industrial policy. The Stambolov era marked the victory of executive
over legislative power in the Bulgarian political system.
Legitimacy of the Bulgarian throne remained an important symbolic
issue in the early 1890s, and the threat of assassination or overthrow
of the prince remained after Stambolov consolidated his power.
Therefore, Stambolov found a Catholic wife for Ferdinand and maneuvered
past Orthodox Church objections in 1893 to ensure Ferdinand an heir that
would stabilize the throne. That heir, Boris, was born the next year.
Meanwhile, Stambolov's autocratic maneuvering and tough policies won him
many enemies, especially after the stabilization of the early 1890s
appeared to make such tactics unnecessary. In 1894 Ferdinand dismissed
his prime minister because the prince sought more power for himself and
believed that Stambolov had become a political liability. The next year,
Macedonian radicals assassinated Stambolov.
The Rule of Ferdinand
The new administration was mainly conservative, and Ferdinand became
the dominant force in Bulgarian policy making. His position grew
stronger when Russia finally recognized him in 1896. The price for
recognition was the conversion of Prince Boris to Orthodoxy from
Catholicism. The Russian attitude had changed for two reasons: Alexander
III had died in 1894, and new Turkish massacres had signaled a collapse
of the Ottoman Empire that would threaten Russian and Bulgarian
interests alike. In the next twenty years, no strong politician like
Stambolov emerged, and Ferdinand was able to accumulate power by
manipulating factions. Several liberal and conservative parties, the
descendants of the two preliberation groups, held power through 1912 in
a parliamentary system that seldom functioned according to the
constitution. The Bulgarian Social Democratic Party took its place in
the new political order, advocating class struggle, recruiting members
from the working class, and organizing strikes.
After relations with Russia had been repaired, Bulgaria's
international position stabilized, allowing the economy to continue
growing undisturbed until 1912. In this period, the government continued
active intervention in agriculture and industry; it promoted new
agricultural methods that improved the yield from fertile lands still
being reclaimed from the Turks in 1900. Bulgarian economic growth
continued growing because of a combination of factors: borrowing from
West European industrial countries, a strong banking system, and a
generally sound investment policy. Between 1887 and 1911, the number of
industrial plants grew from 36 to 345. But the government's financial
policy greatly increased the national debt, which by 1911 was three
times the national budget and required 20 percent of the budget for
interest payment. New land taxes and grain tithes were levied in the
1890s, leading to peasant revolts. In 1899 the Bulgarian Agrarian Union
was founded, the result of a decade of growing rural discontent and
resentment against the intellectual and governing class. Within two
years, the union had evolved into an official party, the Bulgarian
Agrarian National Union (BANU), which was accepted by most Bulgarian
peasants as truly representing their interests. Soon, Bulgarian
politicians viewed BANU as the most potent political group in the
country.
The Macedonian Issue
Macedonian unrest continued into the twentieth century. Between 1894
and 1896, the government of Konstantin Stoilov reversed Stambolov's
policy of controlling Macedonian extremists. When he sought to negotiate
with the Turks for territorial concessions in Macedonia at the end of
the century, Stoilov found that he could not control IMRO. By 1900 that
group, which advocated Macedonian autonomy over the standard Bulgarian
policy goal of annexation, had gained control of the Macedonian
liberation movement inside Bulgaria. Russia and the Western powers now
held Ferdinand responsible for all disruptions in Macedonia, causing
suspicion of all Bulgarian activity in the Balkans. Greece and Serbia
also laid claim to parts of Macedonia, giving them vital interests in
the activities of IMRO as well. In 1902 Russia and Austria-Hungary
forced Serbia and Bulgaria to cut all ties with IMRO.
In 1903 Macedonian liberation forces staged a widespread revolt, the
Ilinden-Preobrazhensko Uprising. Despite strong public support for the
Macedonian cause, Bulgaria sent no help, and the Turks again suppressed
opposition with great violence. Large numbers of refugees now entered
Bulgaria from Macedonia.
In the next four years, Austria-Hungary and Russia sought a formula
by which to administer Macedonia in a way satisfactory to Bulgarian,
Serbian, and Greek interests and approved by Constantinople. Although
nominal agreement was reached in 1905, Serbian, Greek, and Bulgarian
sympathizers clashed in Macedonia in 1906 and 1907. After the death of
its leader Gotse Delchev in the 1903 uprising, IMRO's influence
decreased. Bulgarian public sympathy for the Macedonian cause also
diminished, and by 1905 the government's attention turned to internal
matters.
Inspired by the 1905 uprisings in Russia, a series of riots and
demonstrations between 1905 and 1908 were a reaction by workers, the
poor, and some of the intelligentsia to several issues: domestic
repression, government corruption, and the handling of the Macedonian
issue. In 1906 anti-Greek riots and destruction of Greek property were
ignited in some parts of Bulgaria by Greek claims to Macedonia. In spite
of heavy fines and prohibitions against striking, a rail strike occurred
in 1906, and in 1907 Prime Minister Nikola Petkov was assassinated.
Full Independence
The strikes and demonstrations remained isolated and had little
practical effect, so Ferdinand remained in firm control. In 1908 the
Young Turks, an energetic new generation of reformers, gained power in
the Ottoman Empire. Their ascendancy temporarily restored the
international self-confidence of the empire and threatened a renewed
Turkish influence in the Balkans. To protect the territory it occupied
in Bosnia and Hercegovina, Austria-Hungary annexed those regions. While
the Turks were preoccupied with that situation, Ferdinand nationalized
the Bulgarian section of his main international rail line and declared
himself tsar of a fully independent Bulgaria. The Western powers, again
seeing the threat of Ottoman collapse, were appeased by Russian-arranged
financial compromises that saved face for the Turks. But tension between
Bulgaria and Turkey increased dramatically after Ferdinand's
declaration.
The arbitrary nature of Ferdinand's declaration also brought loud
criticism from democratic-minded Bulgarian factions. Nonetheless, the
grand national assembly held at Turnovo in 1911 to incorporate the terms
of independence into the constitution, ratified Ferdinand's title and
expanded his power in conducting foreign affairs.
By 1911 the BANU, led by Aleksandur Stamboliiski, had become the
largest and most vocal opposition faction. Although the BANU never
gained more than 15 percent of a national vote before World War I, the
party had a large, unified following in the peasant class victimized by
poor harvests, usurious interest rates, and high taxes. Stamboliiski's
political philosophy put the peasant and rural life ahead of all other
classes and lifestyles. Hating bureaucrats and urban institutions, he
proposed a government that would provide representation by profession
rather than party, to ensure a permanent peasant majority. His goal was
to establish a peasant republic that would replace the conventional
parliamentary apparatus established at Turnovo. The BANU was a
controversial and powerful force in Bulgarian politics for the next two
decades.
Bulgaria - THE BALKAN WARS
The settlement of the Second Balkan War had also inflamed Bosnian
nationalism. In 1914 that movement ignited an AustrianSerbian conflict
that escalated into world war when the European alliances of those
countries went into effect.
Prewar Bulgarian Politics
Supported by Ferdinand, the government of Prime Minister Vasil
Radoslavov declared neutrality to assess the possible outcome of the
alliances and Bulgaria's position relative to the Entente (Russia,
France, and Britain) and the Central Powers (AustriaHungary and
Germany). From the beginning, both sides exerted strong pressure and
made territorial offers to lure Bulgaria into an alliance. Ferdinand and
his diplomats hedged, waiting for a decisive military shift in one
direction or the other. The Radoslavov government favored the German
side, the major opposition parties favored the Entente, and the
agrarians and socialists opposed all involvement. By mid-1915 the
Central Powers gained control on the Russian and Turkish fronts and were
thus able to improve their territorial offer to Bulgaria. Now victory
would yield part of Turkish Thrace, substantial territory in Macedonia,
and monetary compensation for war expenses. In October 1915, Bulgaria
made a secret treaty with the Central Powers and invaded Serbia and
Macedonia.
Early Successes
Catching the Entente by surprise, Bulgarian forces pushed the Serbs
out of Macedonia and into Albania and occupied part of Greek Macedonia
by mid-1916. British, French, and Serbian troops landed at Salonika and
stopped the Bulgarian advance, but the Entente's holding operation in
Greece turned into a war of attrition lasting from late 1916 well into
1917. This stalemate diverted 500,000 Entente troops from other fronts.
Meanwhile, Romania had entered the war on the Entente side in 1916.
Bulgarian and German forces pushed the poorly prepared Romanians
northward and took Bucharest in December 1916. The Bulgarians then faced
Russia on a new front in Moldavia (the part of Romania bordering
Russia), but little action took place there.
Stalemate and Demoralization
Once the Bulgarian advance into Romania and Greece halted, conditions
at the front deteriorated rapidly and political support for the war
eroded. By 1916 poor allocation of supplies created shortages for both
civilians and soldiers, and a series of government reorganizations
provided no relief. By 1917 the military stalemate and poor living
conditions combined with news of revolution in Russia to stir
large-scale unrest in Bulgarian society. The agrarians and socialist
workers intensified their antiwar campaigns, and soldiers' committees
formed in army units. Bolshevik antiwar propaganda was widely
distributed in Bulgaria, and Russian and Bulgarian soldiers began
fraternizing along the Moldavian front. In December 1917, Dimitur
Blagoev, founder and head of the Social Democratic Party, led a meeting
of 10,000 in Sofia, demanding an end to the war and overthrow of the
Bulgarian government. A wave of unrest and riots, including a
"women's revolt" against food and clothing shortages, swept
through the country in 1918.
The government position weakened further when the Treaty of
Bucharest, which divided the territory of defeated Romania among the
central powers, left part of the disputed Romanian territory of Dobruja
outside Bulgarian control. Having failed to secure even the least
important territory promised by its war policy, the Radoslavov
government resigned in June 1918. The new prime minister, Aleksandur
Malinov, tried to unite the country by appointing the agrarian
Aleksandur Stamboliiski to his cabinet. But Malinov had vowed to fight,
and the BANU leader refused the post as long as Bulgaria remained in the
war. By September the Bulgarian army was thoroughly demoralized by
antiwar propaganda and harsh conditions. A battle with the British and
French at Dobro Pole brought total retreat, and in ten days Entente
forces entered Bulgaria. On September 29, the Bulgarians signed an
armistice and left the war.
Capitulation and Settlement
The retreat from Dobro Pole brought a soldier revolt that was crushed
by German troops near Sofia. But the parties in power forced Ferdinand
to abdicate at the end of September because they feared full-scale
revolution and blamed the tsar for the country's chaotic state.
Ferdinand's son Boris was named tsar, becoming Boris III. The immediate
cause of social upheaval ended with the armistice, but shortages and
discontent with the Bulgarian government continued. An ineffective
coalition government ruled for the next year, then a general election
was called. Meanwhile, Bulgaria was again left far short of the
territorial goals for which it had declared war. In the Treaty of
Neuilly-sur-Seine (November 1919), Thrace was awarded to Greece,
depriving Bulgaria of access to the Aegean Sea. The newly formed Kingdom
of the Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes took Macedonian territory adjoining
its eastern border, and Southern Dobruja went to Romania.
The treaty limited the postwar Bulgarian Army to a small volunteer
force; Yugoslavia, Romania, and Greece were to receive reparations in
industrial and agricultural goods; and the victorious Allies were to
receive monetary reparations for the next thirty-seven years. On the
other hand, the payment schedule was significantly improved in 1923, and
Bulgaria's loss of 14,100 square kilometers was much less than the
territorial losses of its wartime allies. Nationalist resentment and
frustration grew even stronger because of this outcome, however, and
Bulgaria remained close to Germany throughout the interwar period.
Bulgaria - Stamboliiski
The period after World War I was one of uneasy political coalitions,
slow economic growth, and continued appearance of the Macedonia problem.
Although social unrest remained at a high level, Boris kept firm control
of his government as World War II approached.
Stamboliiski and Agrarian Reform
The 1919 election reflected massive public dissatisfaction with the
war reparations, inflation, and rising taxes that prolonged the chaotic
living conditions of the war. The socialist and agrarian parties
tightened their organizations and increased membership. The left wing of
the Bulgarian Workers' Socialist-Democratic Party (BWSDP) numbered only
25,000 in 1919, and the BANU emerged as the largest party in the
country. The BANU received 28 percent of the 1919 vote, giving it a
plurality but not a majority in the new subranie. Stamboliiski
sought to include the Bulgarian Communist Party (BCP)--which had
finished second in the election-- and the BWSDP in a coalition
government. (The BCP and the BWSDP were the two factions of the
Bulgarian communist movement that had sprung from the Social Democratic
Party founded in 1891; they would remain separate until the former was
disbanded after World War II.) Stamboliiski could not permit the two
factions the control they desired, however, so they refused
participation.
The postwar governing coalition thus included only factions to
Stamboliiski's right. The first major test for the Stamboliiski
government was a transport strike that lasted from December 1919 until
February 1920. Fomented by the communists and the social democrats and
joined by urban workers and middle-class Bulgarians, the striker
protests were quelled harshly by the army and the Orange Guard, a
quasi-military force that Stamboliiski formed to counter mass
demonstrations by the parties of the left.
Suppression of the strike, mobilization of the peasant vote, and
intimidation at the polls gave the BANU enough support to win the
parliamentary election of 1920 over the communists and form a
non-coalition government. Tsar Boris and much of the Bulgarian middle
class preferred the agrarians to the communists and social democrats,
whom they feared much more. Stamboliiski immediately began drastic
economic reforms. He abolished the merchants' trade monopoly on grain,
replacing it with a government consortium; broke up large urban and
rural landholdings and sold the surplus to the poor; enacted an
obligatory labor law to ease the postwar labor shortage; introduced a
progressive income tax; and made secondary schooling compulsory. All
aspects of the radical reform policy aimed at ridding society of
"harmful" classes of society such as lawyers, usurers, and
merchants, distributing capital and obligations more evenly through
society, and raising the living standards of the landless and poor
peasants.
In foreign policy, Stamboliiski officially abandoned Bulgaria's
territorial claims, which he associated with a standing army, monarchy,
large government expenditures, and other prewar phenomena that the
agrarians deemed anachronistic. After the war, no major power was
available to protect Bulgarian interests in the Balkans. For this
reason, the traditional approach to foreign policy was discarded in
favor of rapprochement with all European powers and the new government
of Kemal Atat�rk in Turkey, membership in the League of Nations, and
friendship with the new Kingdom of the Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes
(later the Kingdom of Yugoslavia). Relations with Turkey were greatly
improved by Bulgarian support of Atat�rk's revolutionary Turkish
Republic in 1920.
Reconciliation with Yugoslavia was a necessary step toward
Stamboliiski's ultimate goal of a multiethnic Balkan peasant federation.
Improved Yugoslav relations required a crackdown on the powerful
Macedonian extremist movement. Accordingly, Stamboliiski began a
two-year program of harsh suppression of IMRO in 1921; in 1923
Yugoslavia and Bulgaria agreed at the Nis Convention to cooperate in
controlling extremists.
The Fall of Stamboliiski
Led by a large Macedonian group in Sofia, the strong nationalist
elements remaining in Bulgaria found the new pacifist policy alarming.
The urban working class, unaided by agrarian reforms, gravitated to the
communists or the socialist workers. Inflation and industrial
exploitation continued. Many of Stamboliiski's subordinates inflamed
social tensions by taking very dogmatic positions in favor of peasant
rights. The Bulgarian right, silent since the war, reorganized into a
confederation called the National Alliance. Stamboliiski's Orange Guard
jailed the leaders of that group in 1922, temporarily stopping its
momentum. Meanwhile, in late 1922 and early 1923, Macedonian
nationalists occupied Kiustendil along the Yugoslav border and attacked
government figures to protest rapprochement with Yugoslavia and Greece.
Stamboliiski responded with mass arrests, an accelerated campaign
against IMRO terrorism, a purge of his own fragmented and notoriously
corrupt party, and a new parliamentary election. These dictatorial
measures united the agrarians' various opponents (IMRO, the National
Alliance, army factions, and the social democrats) into a coalition led
by Aleksandur Tsankov. The communists remained outside the group.
Bulgaria's Western creditors would not protect a government that had
rejected their reparations policy. In June 1923, Stamboliiski was
brutally assassinated by IMRO agents, and the conspirators shortly took
control of the entire country with only scattered and ineffectual
agrarian resistance.
Bulgaria - The Tsankov and Liapchev Governments
Political Disorder and Diplomatic Isolation
The world economic crisis that began in 1929 devastated the Bulgarian
economy: The social tensions of the 1920s were exacerbated when 200,000
workers lost their jobs, prices fell by 50 percent, dozens of companies
went bankrupt, and per capita income among peasants was halved between
1929 and 1933. A wave of strikes hit Bulgaria in 1930-31, and in 1931
the Liapchev government was defeated in what would be the last open
election with proportional representation of parliamentary seats.
Liapchev's coalition fell apart, his defeat hastened by the rise of a
supra-party organization, Zveno--a small coalition with connections to
most of the major Bulgarian parties and to fascist Italy. The main goal
of Zveno was to consolidate and reform existing political institutions
so that state power could be exerted directly to promote economic
growth. After 1931 Zveno used the economic crisis to instill this idea
in the Bulgarian political system. In 1931 the new government coalition,
the People's Bloc, readmitted the BANU in an attempt to reunite
Bulgarian factions. But the BANU had become factionalized and isolated;
its representatives in the coalition largely pursued political spoils
rather than the interests of their peasant constituency.
Meanwhile, the Macedonian situation in the early 1930s blocked
further attempts to heal Balkan disputes. Four Balkan conferences were
held to address the Macedonian problem; but Bulgaria, fearing IMRO
reprisals, steadfastly refused to drop territorial demands in Macedonia
or quell Macedonian terrorist activities in the region. Such activities
had continued under all Bulgaria's postwar governments, but the People's
Bloc was especially inept in controlling them. The situation eventually
led to the Balkan Entente of 1934, by which Yugoslavia, Greece, Turkey,
and Romania pledged to honor existing borders in the Balkans. For
Bulgaria the isolation inflicted by this pact was a serious diplomatic
setback in southeastern Europe.
In 1932 Aleksandur Tsankov founded Bulgaria's first serious fascist
party, the National Socialist Movement, which imitated the methods of
Hitler's Nazi party. Although Tsankov's party never attracted a large
following, its activities added to the chaotic fragmentation that forced
the People's Bloc from power in May 1934.
Fragmentation of the People's Bloc coalition and the threat posed by
the Balkan Entente led Zveno and various military factions to stage a
right-wing coup. Under the leadership of Colonel Damian Velchev and
Kimon Georgiev, the new prime minister, the new government began taking
dictatorial measures. The government also took immediate steps to
improve relations with Yugoslavia and made overtures to Britain and
France. Diplomatic relations resumed with the Soviet Union in 1934,
despite a marked increase in internal repression of communists and
suspected communists. A concerted drive by the Bulgarian military
against IMRO permanently reduced the power of that organization, which
by 1934 had exhausted most of its support in Bulgarian society. The fact
that sponsorship of Balkan terrorism finally ceased to hinder Bulgarian
foreign policy was the single lasting contribution of the
Velchev-Georgiev government.
The Zveno group abolished all political parties, citing the failure
of such institutions to provide national leadership. The press was
muzzled. Henceforeward the state would be authoritarian and centralized;
the subranie would represent not political parties but the
classes of society: peasants, workers, artisans, merchants, the
intelligentsia, bureaucrats, and professionals. Velchev also proposed a
wide-ranging program of social and technical modernization. In 1935,
however, Tsar Boris III became an active political force in Bulgaria for
the first time. Disillusioned by the results of the 1934 coup, Boris
took action to regain his power, which the new regime had also
curtailed. Boris used military and civilian factions alarmed by the new
authoritarianism to maneuver the Zveno group out of power and declare a
royal dictatorship.
The Royal Dictatorship
In the years following 1935, Boris relied on a series of
uncharismatic politicians to run Bulgaria, weaken the political power of
Zveno and the military, and keep other factions such as the BANU, the
communists, and the national socialists from forming alliances against
him. Boris chose not to restore the traditional political supremacy of
the subranie and ignored demands by many public figures to
write a new Bulgarian constitution. In 1936 a broad coalition, the
People's Constitutional Bloc, brought together nearly all leftist and
centrist factions in a nominal opposition that had the blessing of the
tsar. Boris delayed holding a national election until 1938. At that
time, only individual candidates were allowed in a carefully controlled
election procedure that excluded party candidate lists. Boris claimed
that domination of the new subranie by pro-government
representatives justified his nonparty system, although the People's
Constitutional Bloc seated over sixty delegates. Elections in the next
two years were strictly limited in order to maintain Boris's control
over his parliament.
Bulgaria - The Interwar Economy
As in the case of World War I, Bulgaria fought on the losing German
side of World War II but avoided open conflict with the Russian/Soviet
state. Again the strains of war eroded public support and forced the
wartime Bulgarian government out of office. But World War II heralded a
drastic political change and a long era of totalitarian governance.
The Passive Alliance
Having failed to remain neutral, Boris entered a passive alliance
with the Axis powers. The immediate result was Bulgarian occupation (but
not accession) of Thrace and Macedonia, which Bulgarian troops took from
Greece and Yugoslavia respectively in April 1941. Although the
territorial gains were initially very popular in Bulgaria, complications
soon arose in the occupied territories. Autocratic Bulgarian
administration of Thrace and Macedonia was no improvement over the
Greeks and the Serbs; expressions of Macedonian national feeling grew,
and uprisings occurred in Thrace. Meanwhile, the Germans pressured
Bulgaria to support the eastern front they had opened by invading the
Soviet Union in June 1941. Boris resisted the pressure because he
believed that Bulgarian society was still sufficiently Russophile to
overthrow him if he declared war. After the Japanese attack on Pearl
Harbor ended United States neutrality, Bulgaria declared war on Britain
and the United States, but continued diplomatic relations with the
Soviet Union throughout World War II. Acceleration of domestic war
protests by the BCP in 1941 led to an internal crackdown on dissident
activities of both the right and left. In the next three years,
thousands of Bulgarians went to concentration and labor camps.
The German eastern front received virtually no aid from Bulgaria, a
policy justified by the argument that Bulgarian troops had to remain at
home to defend the Balkans against Turkish or Allied attack. Hitler
reluctantly accepted this logic. Boris's stubborn resistance to
committing troops was very popular at home, where little war enthusiasm
developed. Nazi pressure to enforce anti-Jewish policies also had little
support in Bulgarian society. Early in the war, laws were passed for
restriction and deportation of the 50,000 Bulgarian Jews, but
enforcement was postponed using various rationales. No program of mass
deportation or extermination was conducted in Bulgaria.
Wartime Crisis
In the summer of 1943, Boris died suddenly at age 49, leaving a
three-man regency ruling for his six-year-old son, Simeon. Because two
of the three regents were figureheads, Prime Minister Bogdan Filov, the
third regent, became de facto head of state in this makeshift structure.
The events of 1943 also reversed the military fortunes of the Axis,
causing the Bulgarian government to reassess its international position.
Late in 1943, the Allies delivered the first of many disastrous air
raids on Sofia. The heavy damage sent a clear message that Germany could
not protect Bulgaria from Allied punishment. Once the war had finally
intruded into Bulgarian territory, the winter of 1943-44 brought severe
social and economic dislocation, hunger, and political instability. The
antiwar factions, especially the communists, used urban guerrilla
tactics and mass demonstrations to rebuild the organizational support
lost during the government crackdown of 1941. Partisan activity, never
as widespread as elsewhere in the Balkans during the war, increased in
1944 as the Red Army moved westward against the retreating Germans. To
support antigovernment partisan groups, in 1942 the communists had
established an umbrella Fatherland Front coalition backing complete
neutrality, withdrawal from occupied territory, and full civil
liberties.
Early in 1944, Bulgarian officials tried to achieve peace with the
Allies and the Greek and Yugoslav governments-in-exile. Fearing the
German forces that remained in Bulgaria, Filov could not simply
surrender unconditionally; meanwhile, the Soviets threatened war if
Bulgaria did not declare itself neutral and remove all German armaments
from Bulgaria's Black Sea coast. Unable to gain the protection of the
Allies, who had now bypassed Bulgaria in their strategic planning,
Bulgaria was caught between onrushing Soviet forces and the last gambits
of the retreating Nazis. At this point, the top priority of Bulgarian
leaders was clearing the country of German occupiers while arranging a
peace with the Allies that would deprive Soviet forces of an excuse to
occupy Bulgaria. But in September 1944, the Soviet Union unexpectedly
declared war on Bulgaria, just as the latter was about to withdraw from
the Axis and declare war on Germany.
The Soviet Occupation
When Soviet troops arrived in Bulgaria, they were welcomed by the
populace as liberators from German occupation. On September 9, 1944,
five days after the Soviet declaration of war, a Fatherland Front
coalition deposed the temporary government in a bloodless coup. Headed
by Kimon Georgiev of Zveno, the new administration included four
communists, five members of Zveno, two social democrats, and four
agrarians. Although in the minority, the communists had been the driving
force in forming the coalition as an underground resistance organization
in 1942. The presence of the Red Army, which remained in Bulgaria until
1947, strengthened immeasurably the communist position in dealing with
the Allies and rival factions in the coalition. At this point, many
noncommunist Bulgarians placed their hopes on renewed relations with the
Soviet Union; in their view, both Germany and the Allies had been
discredited by the events of the previous fifteen years. In 1945 the
Allies themselves expected that a benign Soviet Union would continue the
wartime alliance through the period of postwar East European
realignment.
The armistice signed by Bulgaria with the Soviet Union in October
1944 surrendered all wartime territorial gains except Southern Dobruja;
this meant that Macedonia returned to Yugoslavia and Thrace to Greece.
The peace agreement also established a Soviet-dominated Allied Control
Commission to run Bulgaria until conclusion of a peace treaty. Overall
war damage to Bulgaria was moderate compared to that in other European
countries, and the Soviet Union demanded no reparations. On the other
hand, Bulgaria held the earliest and most widespread war crimes trial in
postwar Europe; almost 3,000 were executed as war criminals. Bulgaria
emerged from the war with no identifiable political structure; the party
system had dissolved in 1934, replaced by the pragmatic balancing of
political factions in Boris's royal dictatorship. This condition and the
duration of the war in Europe eight months after Bulgaria's surrender
gave the communists ample opportunity to exploit their favorable
strategic position in Bulgarian politics.
Bulgaria - COMMUNISM
Initial Maneuvering
In the months after the surrender, the communist element of the
Fatherland Front gradually purged opposition figures, exiled Tsar Simeon
II, and rigged elections to confirm its power. In December 1945, a
conference of foreign ministers of the United States, Britain, and the
Soviet Union theoretically allocated two seats to the newly consolidated
opposition BANU in the Bulgarian Council of Ministers, but BANU leaders
demanded an immediate national election and removal of communist
ministers. Because the BANU was now a unified party with substantial
political backing, these demands created a governmental stalemate with
the Fatherland Front for one year. In a national referendum in September
1946, however, an overwhelming majority voted to abolish the monarchy
and proclaim Bulgaria a people's republic.
The next month, a national election chose a subranie to
draft a new constitution. In a widely questioned process, Fatherland
Front candidates won 70 percent of the votes. At this point, however,
opposition to the front remained strong, as communist power grew
steadily. In early 1947, opposition to aggressive communist tactics of
confiscation and collectivization generated a loose anticommunist
coalition within and outside the Fatherland Front, under BANU leader
Nikola Petkov. The power struggle, which centered on the nature of the
new constitution, reached its peak when the Paris peace treaty of
February 1947 required that Soviet forces and the Allied Control
Commission leave Bulgaria immediately. Once the United States ratified
its peace treaty with Bulgaria in June 1947, the communist-dominated
Fatherland Front arrested and executed Petkov and declared Bulgaria a
communist state. Petkov's coalition was the last organized domestic
opposition to communist rule in Bulgaria until 1989.
After 1946 Fatherland Front governments maintained nominal
representation of noncommunist parties. But those parties increasingly
bowed to the leadership of communist Prime Minister Georgi Dimitrov, who
had been appointed in 1946. After two years of postwar turmoil,
Bulgarian political and economic life settled into the patterns set out
by the new communist constitution (referred to as the Dimitrov
Constitution) ratified in December 1947. Dimitrov argued that previous
Bulgarian attempts at parliamentary democracy were disastrous and that
only massive social and economic restructuring could ensure stability.
By the end of 1947, Bulgaria had followed the other East European states
in refusing reconstruction aid from the Marshall Plan and joining the
Communist Information Bureau. In 1948 the Fatherland Front was
reorganized into an official worker-peasant alliance in accordance with
Cominform policy. In December 1947, BANU leader Georgi Traikov had
repudiated traditional agrarian programs; after a thorough purge that
year, his party retained only nominal independence to preserve the
illusion of a two-party system. All other opposition parties disbanded.
The Dimitrov Constitution
Dimitrov guided the framing of the 1947 constitution on the model of
the 1936 constitution of the Soviet Union. The Bulgarian document
guaranteed citizens equality before the law; freedom from
discrimination; a universal welfare system; freedom of speech, the
press, and assembly; and inviolability of person, domicile, and
correspondence. But those rights were qualified by a clause prohibiting
activity that would jeopardize the attainments of the national
revolution of September 9, 1944. Citizens were guaranteed employment but
required to work in a socially useful capacity. The constitution also
prescribed a planned national economy. Private property was allowed, if
its possession was not "to the detriment of the public good."
By the end of 1947, all private industry had been confiscated and
financial enterprises nationalized in the culmination of a gradual
government takeover that began in 1944. The first two-year plan for
economic rehabilitation began in 1947.
Chervenkov and Stalinism in Bulgaria
In 1948 the newly formed Soviet empire in Eastern Europe was
threatened by a split between Yugoslav President Josip Broz Tito and
Soviet leader Joseph V. Stalin. After expelling Yugoslavia from the
Cominform, Stalin began exerting greater pressure on the other East
European states, including Bulgaria, to adhere rigidly to Soviet foreign
and domestic policy. He demanded that the communist parties of those
countries become virtual extensions of the Communist Party of the Soviet
Union (CPSU) by purging all opposition figures. The Bulgarian government
curtailed religious freedom by forcing Orthodox clergy into a Union of
Bulgarian Priests in 1948, taking control of Muslim religious
institutions, and dissolving Bulgarian branches of Roman Catholic and
Protestant churches in 1949. The most visible political victim of the
new policy was Traicho Kostov, who with Georgi Dimitrov and Vasil
Kolarov had led the BCP to power in 1944. Accused by Dimitrov of
treason, Kostov was shot in December 1949. Dimitrov died before Kostov's
execution, Kolarov soon afterward. To fill the power vacuum left by
those events, Stalin chose Vulko Chervenkov, a trusted prot�g�.
Chervenkov would complete the conversion of the BCP into the type of
one-man dictatorship that Stalin had created in the Soviet Union.
Chervenkov assumed all top government and party positions and quickly
developed a cult of personality like that of his Soviet mentor. At
Stalin's command, Chervenkov continued purging party members from 1950
until 1953, to forestall in Bulgaria the sort of Titoist separatism that
Stalin greatly feared. Rigid party hierarchy replaced the traditional
informal structures of Bulgarian governance, and the purges eliminated
the faction of the BCP that advocated putting Bulgarian national
concerns ahead of blind subservience to the CPSU.
The Chervenkov period (1950-56) featured harsh repression of all
deviation from the party line, arbitrary suppression of culture and the
arts along the lines of Soviet-prescribed socialist realism, and an
isolationist foreign policy. By early 1951, Chervenkov had expelled one
in five party members, including many high officials, in his campaign
for complete party discipline. In 1950 a new agricultural
collectivization drive began. In spite of intense peasant resistance,
the collectivization drive continued intermittently until the process
was virtually complete in 1958.
Foreign and Economic Policies
The independent course taken by Tito's Yugoslavia in 1948 caused
Bulgaria to seal the Yugoslav border; a 1953 Balkan Pact among Greece,
Yugoslavia, and Turkey further isolated Bulgaria, which by that time had
cut all relations with Western countries. The Soviet Union now was
Bulgaria's only ally. It supplied military and economic advisers and
provided the model for Bulgarian social services, economic planning, and
education in the early 1950s. Over 90 percent of Bulgarian exports and
imports involved Soviet partnership, although the Soviets often paid
less than world prices for Bulgarian goods. Because the primitive,
mainly agricultural Bulgarian economy closely resembled that of the
Soviet Union, Soviet-style centralized planning in five-year blocks had
more immediate benefits there than in the other European states where it
was first applied in the early 1950s.
After Stalin
The death of Joseph Stalin in March 1953 had strong repercussions in
Bulgaria. By that time, Chervenkov had already moved slightly away from
hard-line Stalinist domestic repression and international isolation, but
the lack of clear ideological guidance from post-Stalin Moscow left him
in an insecure position. Official approval in 1951 of Dimitur Dimov's
mildly heretical novel Tiutiun (Tobacco) had loosened somewhat
the official constraints on literature and other cultural activities. In
1953 Bulgaria resumed relations with Greece and Yugoslavia, some
political amnesties were granted, and planners discussed increasing
production of consumer goods and reducing the prices of necessities. At
the Sixth Party Congress in 1954, Chervenkov gave up his party
leadership but retained his position as prime minister. Todor Zhivkov,
leader of the postwar generation of Bulgarian communist leaders, assumed
the newly created position of first secretary of the party Central
Committee. Several purged party leaders were released from labor camps,
and some resumed visible roles in the party hierarchy.
In spite of the 1954 party shifts, Chervenkov remained the
unchallenged leader of Bulgaria for two more years. The economic shift
away from heavy industry toward consumer goods continued in the
mid-1950s, and direct Soviet intervention in Bulgarian economic and
political life diminished. By 1955, some 10,000 political prisoners had
been released. In an attempt to win political support from the peasants,
Chervenkov eased the pace of collectivization and increased national
investment in agriculture. However, events in the Soviet Union ended
this brief period of calm.
The Fall of Chervenkov
In 1955 the Belgrade Declaration restored Soviet-Yugoslav friendship
and reinstated Tito to the fraternity of world communist leaders.
Because Chervenkov had branded Tito and the Yugoslavs as arch-villains
during his rise to power, this agreement eroded his position. Then, in
February 1956, Nikita S. Khrushchev denounced Chervenkov's patron Stalin
and Stalin's cult of personality at the twentieth congress of the CPSU.
Unwilling to stray from the Soviet party line, the BCP also condemned
the cult of personality (and, implicitly, Chervenkov's
authoritarianism), advocating instead collective leadership and
inner-party democracy. In his 1956 report to party leaders, Zhivkov
expressed this condemnation and promised that the party would make
amends for past injustices--a clear reference to the fate of Kostov and
Chervenkov's other purge victims in the party. Having had his entire
regime repudiated by the party leader, Chervenkov resigned. Zhivkov, who
had thus far remained below Chervenkov in actual party power, now
assumed the full powers of his party first secretary position. The 1956
April Plenum became the official date of Bulgarian de-Stalinization in
party mythology; after that event, the atmosphere of BCP politics
changed significantly.
Intellectual Life
The thaw in Bulgarian intellectual life had continued from 1951 until
the middle of the decade. Chervenkov's resignation and the literary and
cultural flowering in the Soviet Union encouraged the view that the
process would continue, but the Hungarian revolution of fall 1956
frightened the Bulgarian leadership away from encouragement of dissident
intellectual activity. In response to events in Hungary, Chervenkov was
appointed minister of education and culture; in 1957 and 1958, he purged
the leadership of the Bulgarian Writers' Union and dismissed liberal
journalists and editors from their positions. His crackdowns effectively
ended the "Bulgarian thaw" of independent writers and artists
inspired by Khrushchev's 1956 speech against Stalinism. Again mimicking
the Soviet party, which purged a group of high officials in 1957, the
BCP dismissed three party leaders on vague charges the same year. Among
those removed was deputy prime minister Georgi Chankov, an important
rival of Zhivkov. The main motivation for this purge was to assure the
Soviet Union that Bulgarian communists would not fall into the same
heretical behavior as had the Hungarian party in 1956. Through the
political maneuvers of the mid-1950s, Todor Zhivkov enhanced his
position by identifying with the "Bulgarian" rather than
"Soviet" branch of the BCP at the same time as he aligned
himself with the new anti-Stalinist faction in the Soviet Union. He
established especially close ties with Khrushchev at this time.
Domestic Policy and Its Results
Most aspects of life in Bulgaria continued to conform strongly to the
Soviet model in the mid-1950s. In 1949 the Bulgarian educational system
had begun a restructuring process to resemble the Soviet system, and the
social welfare system followed suit. In the mid-1950s, Soviet-style
centralized planning produced economic indicators showing that
Bulgarians were returning to their prewar lifestyle in some respects:
real wages increased 75 percent, consumption of meat, fruit, and
vegetables increased markedly, medical facilities and doctors became
available to more of the population, and in 1957 collective farm workers
benefited from the first agricultural pension and welfare system in
Eastern Europe.
In 1959 the BCP borrowed from the Chinese the phrase "Great Leap
Forward" to symbolize a sudden burst of economic activity to be
injected into the Third Five-Year Plan (1958-1962), whose original scope
was quite conservative. According to the revised plan, industrial
production would double and agricultural production would triple by
1962; a new agricultural collectivization and consolidation drive would
achieve great economies of scale in that branch; investment in light
industry would double, and foreign trade would expand. Following the
Chinese model, all of Bulgarian society was to be propagandized and
mobilized to meet the planning goals. Two purposes of the grandiose
revised plan were to keep Bulgaria in step with the Soviet bloc, all of
whose members were embarking on plans for accelerated growth, and to
quell internal party conflicts. Zhivkov, whose "theses" had
defined the goals of the plan, purged Politburo members and party rivals
Boris Taskov (in 1959) and Anton Yugov (in 1962), citing their criticism
of his policy as economically obstructionist. Already by 1960, however,
Zhivkov had been forced to redefine the impossible goals of his theses.
Lack of skilled labor and materials made completion of projects at the
prescribed pace impossible. Harvests were disastrously poor in the early
1960s; peasant unrest forced the government to raise food prices; and
the urban dissatisfaction that resulted from higher prices compounded a
crisis that broke in the summer of 1962. Blame fell on Zhivkov's
experiments with decentralized planning, which was totally abandoned by
1963.
Bulgaria - THE ZHIVKOV ERA
Beginning in 1961, Todor Zhivkov skillfully retained control of the
Bulgarian government and the BCP. His regime was a period of
unprecedented stability, slavish imitation of Soviet policies, and
modest economic experimentation.
Zhivkov Takes Control
Zhivkov was able to weather the social unrest of 1962 by finding
scapegoats, juggling indicators of economic progress, and receiving help
from abroad. In 1961 Khrushchev had once again denounced Stalin,
requiring similar action in the loyal Soviet satellites. In October
Chervenkov, who had retained considerable party power, was ousted from
the Politburo as an unrepentant Stalinist and obstructor of Bulgarian
economic progress. When Khrushchev visited Bulgaria in 1962, the Soviet
leader made clear his preference for Zhivkov over other Bulgarian party
leaders. Within months Yugov had lost his party position and Chervenkov
was expelled from the party. Thus, in spite of disastrously unrealistic
economic experimentation of the sort that contributed to Khrushchev's
ouster in 1964, Zhivkov had greatly strengthened his position as party
first secretary by the time his Soviet patron had fallen.
In the early 1960s, Zhivkov improved ties with the Bulgarian
intelligentsia by liberalizing censorship and curbing the state security
forces. He also mended relations with the agrarians by granting
amnesties to BANU members and appointing the leader of the party as head
of state. These measures gave Zhivkov a political base broad enough to
survive the fall of Khrushchev, but they did not prevent an army plot
against him in 1965. Zhivkov used the plot as a reason to tighten
control over the army and move security functions from the Ministry of
the Interior to a new Committee of State Security, under his personal
control. Several other plots were reported unofficially in the late
1960s, but after 1962 Zhivkov's position as sole leader of Bulgaria went
without serious challenge.
Zhivkov's Political Methodology
In the 1960s, Zhivkov moved slowly and carefully to replace the
deeply entrenched Old Guard in party positions. He believed that only an
energetic, professional party cadre could lead Bulgaria effectively.
Therefore, he gradually moved a younger group, including his daughter
Liudmila Zhivkova and future party leader Aleksandur Lilov, into
positions of power. At the same time, he juggled party positions enough
to prevent any individual from becoming a serious rival. Unlike
Chervenkov, with his Stalinist personality cult, Zhivkov cultivated an
egalitarian persona that kept him in contact with the Bulgarian people.
Unlike contemporaneous communist leaders in other countries, Zhivkov
displayed a sense of humor even in formal state speeches. Because of the
strong tradition of egalitarianism in Bulgarian political culture, the
contrast of his approach with that of Chervenkov served Zhivkov very
well.
The Constitution of 1971
In 1968 the Prague Spring outbreak of heretical socialism in
Czechoslovakia caused the BCP to tighten control over all social
organizations, calling for democratic centrism and elimination of
unreliable elements from the party. This policy kept the BCP on a
unified path in complete support of Soviet interests; it also led to a
new Bulgarian constitution and BCP program in 1971. Approved by the
Tenth Party Congress and a national referendum, the 1971 constitution
detailed for the first time the structure of the BCP (highly
centralized, in keeping with policy after 1968) and its role in leading
society and the state. BANU was specified as the partner of the BCP in
the cooperative governing of the country. A new State Council was
created to oversee the Council of Ministers and exercise supreme
executive authority. In 1971 Zhivkov resigned as prime minister to
become chairman of the State Council, a position equivalent to Bulgarian
head of state. The new constitution also defined four forms of property:
state, cooperative, public organization, and private. Private property
was limited to that needed for individual and family upkeep.
Foreign Affairs in the 1960s and 1970s
In the first decade of the Zhivkov regime, Balkan affairs remained
central to Bulgarian foreign policy, and relations with the Soviet Union
remained without significant conflict. Because the Soviet Union showed
relatively little interest in the Balkans in the 1950s and 1960s,
Bulgaria was able to improve significantly its relations with its
neighbors. In 1964 an agreement with Greece ended the long postwar
freeze caused by Greek membership in the North Atlantic Treaty
Organization. Bulgaria paid partial wartime reparations to Greece, and
relations were normalized in culture, trade, and communications after
the initial agreement. Turkish-Bulgarian relations were hindered by
irritation over the Turkish minority issue: throughout the postwar
period, wavering Bulgarian policy on internal treatment and emigration
of Bulgarian Turks was the chief obstacle to rapprochement, although
bilateral agreements on emigration and other issues were reached in the
1960s and 1970s.
Relations with Yugoslavia also were strained in the postwar years.
The age-old Macedonian dispute was the principal reason that Yugoslavia
remained untouched by Zhivkov's Balkan d�tente policy. In the
mid-1960s, Tito and Zhivkov exchanged visits, but by 1967 official
Bulgarian spokesmen were again stressing the Bulgarian majority in
Yugoslav-ruled Macedonia, and a new decade of mutually harsh propaganda
began. Although the polemic over Macedonia continued through the 1980s,
it served both countries mainly as a rallying point for domestic
political support, and Bulgaria avoided taking advantage of Yugoslav
vulnerabilities such as the unrest in the province of Kosovo. In the
early 1980s, much of Bulgaria's anti-Yugoslav propaganda aimed at
discrediting heretical economic policy applications (feared by every
orthodox communist neighbor of Yugoslavia) in Yugoslav Macedonia. In
1981 Zhivkov called for establishment of a Balkan nuclear-free zone that
would include Romania, Greece, Turkey, and Yugoslavia. The concept was
notable not because of its practical implications (Bulgaria was
generally unsupportive of regional cooperation, and the potential
participants had strongly differing international positions), but as a
Soviet device to remove NATO nuclear weapons from Greece and Turkey at a
time of superpower tension over European weapons installations.
In the 1970s, Zhivkov actively pursued better relations with the
West, overcoming conservative opposition and the tentative,
tourism-based approach to the West taken in the 1960s. Emulating Soviet
d�tente policy of the 1970s, Bulgaria gained Western technology,
expanded cultural contacts, and attracted Western investments with the
most liberal foreign investment policy in Eastern Europe. Between 1966
and 1975, Zhivkov visited Charles de Gaulle and the pope and established
full diplomatic relations with the Federal Republic of Germany (West
Germany). As in 1956 and 1968, however, Soviet actions altered
Bulgaria's position. The Soviet invasion of Afghanistan in late 1979,
which Bulgaria supported vigorously, renewed tension between Bulgaria
and the West. Bulgarian implication in the attempted assassination of
Pope John Paul II in 1981 exacerbated the problem and kept relations
cool through the early 1980s.
Bulgaria also followed the Soviet example in relations with Third
World countries, maintaining the image of brotherly willingness to aid
struggling victims of Western imperialism. Student exchanges already
were common in the 1960s, and many Bulgarian technicians and medical
personnel went to African, Asian, and Latin American countries in the
1970s and 1980s. Cultural exchange programs targeted mainly the young in
those countries. Between 1978 and 1983, Zhivkov visited seventeen
Third-World countries and hosted leaders from at least that many.
Throughout the 1960s and 1970s, Bulgaria gave official military
support to many national liberation causes, most notably in the
Democratic Republic of Vietnam, (North Vietnam), Indonesia, Libya,
Angola, Afghanistan, the Horn of Africa, and the Middle East. In 1984
the 9,000 Bulgarian advisers stationed in Libya for military and
nonmilitary aid put that country in first place among Bulgaria's
Third-World clients. Through its Kintex arms export enterprise, Bulgaria
also engaged in covert military support activities, many of which were
subsequently disclosed. In the 1970s, diplomatic crises with Sudan and
Egypt were triggered by Bulgarian involvement in coup plots. Repeated
discoveries of smuggled arms shipments from Bulgaria to Third-World
countries gave Bulgaria a reputation as a major player in international
arms supply to terrorists and revolutionaries. Arms smuggling into
Turkey periodically caused diplomatic problems with that country in the
1970s.
Domestic Policy in the 1960s and 1970s
Zhivkov's domestic policy in the late 1960s and 1970s emphasized
increased production by Bulgaria's newly completed base of heavy
industry, plus increased consumer production. The industrial base and
collectivization of Bulgarian agriculture had been achieved largely by
emulating Khrushchev's approaches in the early 1960s; but after
Khrushchev fell, Zhivkov experimented rather freely in industrial and
agricultural policy. A 1965 economic reform decentralized decision
making and introduced the profit motive in some economic areas. The
approach, a minor commitment to "planning from below" in
imitation of Yugoslavia's self-management program, was abandoned in
1969. Taking its place, a recentralization program gave government
ministries full planning responsibility at the expense of individual
enterprises.
Meanwhile, a new program for integration and centralization of
agriculture was born in 1969. The agricultural-industrial complex
(agropromishlen kompleks--APK) merged cooperative and state farms and
introduced industrial technology to Bulgarian agriculture. In the 1970s
the APK became the main supporting structure of Bulgarian agriculture.
The social and political goal of this program was to homogenize
Bulgarian society, ending the sharp dichotomy that had always existed
between rural and town populations and weakening the ideological force
of the BANU. If the traditional gulf between Bulgarian agricultural and
industrial workers were eliminated, the BCP could represent both groups.
Despite this large-scale reorganization effort, the Bulgarian tradition
of small peasant farming remained strong into the 1980s.
In keeping with the d�tente of the 1970s, Bulgaria sought
independent trade agreements with the West throughout that decade, to
furnish technology and credit not available within the Council for
Mutual Economic Assistance. Economic cooperation and license agreements
were signed with several West European countries, most notably West
Germany. Although the Western demand for Bulgarian goods remained
generally low and Western commodities proved unexpectedly expensive in
the late 1970s, Bulgaria's expansion of Western trade in that decade was
unusually high for a Comecon member nation.
The Political Atmosphere in the 1970s
Through the mid-1970s, Zhivkov continued balancing the older and
younger generations and the reformist and conservative factions in his
party, with only occasional purges of key officials. But in 1977, the
purge of liberal Politburo member Boris Velchev introduced a massive
reorganization of provincial party organizations that ousted 38,500
party members. This move was designed to limit the atmosphere of
liberalization that had followed the 1975 Helsinki Accords. That mood
and an economic crisis caused by oil shortages in the 1970s aroused
discontent and demonstrations in Bulgaria in the late 1970s.
At the end of the decade, two more crises confronted Zhivkov: in 1978
the murder of exiled writer Georgi Markov was widely attributed to
Bulgarian State Security, damaging the country's international image;
and in 1980 the Polish Solidarity movement alarmed the entire Soviet
Bloc by attracting an active anticommunist following in a key Warsaw
Pact country. Although the magnitude of Bulgarian social discontent was
much less than that in Poland, the BCP ordered production of more
consumer goods, a reduction of party privileges, and limited media
coverage of Poland in the early 1980s as an antidote to the "Polish
infection."
Meanwhile, in 1980 Zhivkov had improved his domestic position by
appointing his daughter Liudmila Zhivkova as chair of the commission on
science, culture, and art. In this powerful position, Zhivkova became
extremely popular by promoting Bulgaria's separate national cultural
heritage. She spent large sums of money in a highly visible campaign to
support scholars, collect Bulgarian art, and sponsor cultural
institutions. Among her policies was closer cultural contact with the
West; her most visible project was the spectacular national celebration
of Bulgaria's 1,300th anniversary in 1981. When Zhivkova died in 1981,
relations with the West had already been chilled by the Afghanistan
issue, but her brief administration of Bulgaria's official cultural life
was a successful phase of her father's appeal to Bulgarian national
tradition to bind the country together.
Bulgaria in the 1980s
Despite the resumption of the Cold War, by 1980 several longstanding
problems had eased in Bulgaria. Zhivkova had bolstered national pride
and improved Bulgaria's international cultural image; Zhivkov had eased
oppression of Roman Catholics and propaganda against the Bulgarian
Orthodox Church in the 1970s, and used the 1,300th anniversary of the
Bulgarian state for formal reconciliation with Orthodox church
officials; the Bulgarian media covered an expanded range of permissible
subject matter; Bulgaria contributed equipment to a Soviet space probe
launched in 1981, heralding a new era of technological advancement; and
the New Economic Model (NEM), instituted in 1981 as the latest economic
reform program, seemingly improved the supply of consumer goods and
generally upgraded the economy.
However, Zhivkova's death and East-West tensions dealt serious blows
to cultural liberalization; by 1984 the Bulgarian Writers' Conference
was calling for greater ideological content and optimism in literature.
Once fully implemented in 1982, NEM was unable to improve the quality or
quantity of Bulgarian goods and produce. In 1983 Zhivkov harshly
criticized all of Bulgarian industry and agriculture in a major speech,
but the reforms generated by his speech did nothing to improve the
situation. A large percentage of high-quality domestic goods were
shipped abroad in the early 1980s to shrink Bulgaria's hard-currency
debt, and the purchase of Western technology was sacrificed for the same
reason, crippling technical advancement and disillusioning consumers. By
1984 Bulgaria was suffering a serious energy shortage because its
Soviet-made nuclear power plant was undependable and droughts reduced
the productivity of hydroelectric plants. Like the cutback in technology
imports, this shortage affected all of Bulgarian industry. Finally,
Bulgarian implication in the plot to assassinate Pope John Paul II in
1981 and in international drugs and weapons trading impaired the
country's international image and complicated economic relations with
the West.
The problem of the Turkish minority in Bulgaria continued into the
1980s. Because birth rates among the Turks remained relatively high
while Bulgarians approached a zero-growth birth rate in 1980, Bulgarian
authorities sought to mitigate the impact of growing Turkish enclaves in
certain regions. While Bulgaria discontinued its liberal 1969 emigration
agreement with Turkey (presumably to prevent a shortage of unskilled
labor resulting from free movement of Turkish workers back to their
homeland), in 1984 Bulgaria began a massive campaign to erase the
national identity of Turkish citizens by forcing them to take Bulgarian
names. Official propaganda justified forced assimilation with the
assertion that the only "Turks" in Bulgaria were descended
from the Bulgarians who had adopted Islam after the Ottoman occupation
in the fourteenth century. This campaign brought several negative
results. Bulgaria's international image, already damaged by events in
the early 1980s, now included official discrimination against the
country's largest ethnic minority. The resumption of terrorist attacks
on civilians, absent for many years, coincided with the new policy. And
Bulgaria's relations with Turkey, which had improved somewhat after a
visit by Turkish President Kenan Evren to Bulgaria in 1982, suffered
another setback.
Bulgaria's close reliance on the Soviet Union continued into the
1980s, but differences began to appear. Much of Zhivkov's success had
come from the secure support of Nikita Khrushchev's successor, Leonid
Brezhnev, with whom Zhivkov had a close personal relationship. By
contrast, relations between Zhivkov and Brezhnev's successor, Iurii V.
Andropov, were tense because Zhivkov had supported Andropov's rival
Konstantin Chernenko as successor to Brezhnev. The advent of Mikhail S.
Gorbachev as Soviet party leader in 1985 defined a new generational
difference between Soviet and Bulgarian leadership. Gorbachev
immediately declared that Bulgaria must follow his example in party
reform if traditional relations were to continue.
By this time, the image of the BCP had suffered for several years
from well-publicized careerism and corruption, and from the remoteness
and advancing age of the party leadership (Zhivkov was seventy-four in
1985). The state bureaucracy, inordinately large in Bulgaria since the
first post-liberation government of 1878, constituted 13.5 percent of
the total national work force in 1977. Periodic anticorruption campaigns
had only temporary effects. The ideological credibility of the party
also suffered from the apparent failure of the NEM, whose goals were
being restated by 1984. Although the BCP faced no serious political
opposition or internal division in the early 1980s, the party launched
campaigns to involve Bulgarian youth more fully in party activities. But
these efforts had little impact on what party leaders perceived as
serious and widespread political apathy. Thus, by 1985 many domestic and
international signs indicated that the underpinning of the long, stable
Zhivkov era was in precarious condition.
Bulgaria - The Society and Environment
The land area of Bulgaria is 110,550 square kilometers, slightly
larger than that of the state of Tennessee. The country is situated on
the west coast of the Black Sea, with Romania to the north, Greece and
Turkey to the south, and Yugoslavia to the west. Considering its small
size, Bulgaria has a great variety of topographical features. Even
within small parts of the country, the land may be divided into plains,
plateaus, hills, mountains, basins, gorges, and deep river valleys.
Boundaries
Although external historical events often changed Bulgaria's national
boundaries in its first century of existence, natural terrain features
defined most boundaries after 1944, and no significant group of people
suffered serious economic hardship because of border delineation.
Postwar Bulgaria contained a large percentage of the ethnic Bulgarian
people, although numerous migrations into and out of Bulgaria occurred
at various times. None of the country's borders was officially disputed
in 1991, although nationalist Bulgarians continued to claim that
Bulgaria's share of Macedonia--which it shared with both Yugoslavia and
Greece--was less than just because of the ethnic connection between
Macedonians and Bulgarians.
In 1991 Bulgaria had a total border of about 2,264 kilometers. Rivers
accounted for about 680 kilometers and the Black Sea coast for 400
kilometers; the southern and western borders were mainly defined by
ridges in high terrain. The western and northern boundaries were shared
with Yugoslavia and Romania, respectively, and the Black Sea coastline
constituted the entire eastern border. The Romanian border followed the
Danube River for 464 kilometers from the northwestern corner of the
country to the city of Silistra and then cut to the east-southeast for
136 kilometers across the northeastern province of Varna. The Danube,
with steep bluffs on the Bulgarian side and a wide area of swamps and
marshes on the Romanian side, was one of the most effective river
boundaries in Europe. The line through Dobruja was arbitrary and was
redrawn several times according to international treaties. In that
process, most inhabitants with strong national preferences resettled in
the country of their choice. Borders to the south were with Greece and
Turkey. The border with Greece was 491 kilometers long, and the Turkish
border was 240 kilometers long.
Topography
The main characteristic of Bulgaria's topography is alternating bands
of high and low terrain that extend east to west across the country.
From north to south, those bands are the Danubian Plateau, the Balkan
Mountains (called Stara Planina, meaning old mountains in Bulgarian),
the central Thracian Plain, and the Rhodope Mountains. The easternmost
sections near the Black Sea are hilly, but they gradually gain height to
the west until the westernmost part of the country is entirely high
ground.
More than two-thirds of the country is plains, plateaus, or hilly
land at an altitude less than 600 meters. Plains (below 200 meters) make
up 31 percent of the land, plateaus and hills (200 to 600 meters) 41
percent, low mountains (600 to 1,000 meters) 10 percent, medium-sized
mountains (1,000 to 1,500 meters) 10 percent, and high mountains (over
1,500 meters) 3 percent. The average altitude in Bulgaria is 470 meters.
The Danubian Plateau extends from the Yugoslav border to the Black
Sea. It encompasses the area between the Danube River, which forms most
of the country's northern border, and the Balkan Mountains to the south.
The plateau slopes gently from cliffs along the river, then it abuts
mountains of 750 to 950 meters. The plateau, a fertile area with
undulating hills, is the granary of the country.
The southern edge of the Danubian Plateau blends into the foothills
of the Balkan Mountains, the Bulgarian part of the Carpathian Mountains.
The Carpathians resemble a reversed S as they run eastward from
Czechoslovakia across the northern portion of Romania, swinging
southward to the middle of Romania and then running westward, where they
are known as the Transylvanian Alps. The mountains turn eastward again
at the Iron Gate, a gorge of the Danube River at the Romanian-Yugoslav
border. At that point, they become the Balkan Mountains of Bulgaria.
The Balkan Mountains originate at the Timok Valley in Yugoslavia and
run southward towards the Sofia Basin in west central Bulgaria. From
there they run east to the Black Sea. The Balkans are about 600
kilometers long and 30 to 50 kilometers wide. They retain their height
well into central Bulgaria, where Botev Peak, the highest point in the
Balkan Mountains, rises to about 2,376 meters. The range then continues
at lower altitude to the cliffs of the Black Sea. Through most of
Bulgaria, the Balkans form the watershed from which rivers drain north
to the Danube River or south to the Aegean Sea. Some smaller rivers in
the east drain directly to the Black Sea. The Sredna Gora (central
hills) is a narrow ridge about 160 kilometers long and 1,600 meters
high, running east to west parallel to the Balkans. Just to the south is
the Valley of Roses, famous for rose oil used in perfume and liqueurs.
The southern slopes of the Balkan Mountains and the Sredna Gora give
way to the Thracian Plain. Roughly triangular in shape, the plain
originates at a point east of the mountains near Sofia and broadens
eastward to the Black Sea. It includes the Maritsa River valley and the
lowlands that extend from the river to the Black Sea. Like the Danubian
Plateau, much of the Thracian Plain is somewhat hilly and not a true
plain. Most of its terrain is moderate enough to cultivate.
The Rhodope Mountains occupy the area between the Thracian Plain and
the Greek border to the south. The western Rhodopes consist of two
ranges: the Rila Mountains south of Sofia and the Pirin Mountains in the
southwestern corner of the country. They are the most outstanding
topographic feature of Bulgaria and of the entire Balkan Peninsula. The
Rila range includes Mount Musala, whose 2,975-meter peak is the highest
in any Balkan country. About a dozen other peaks in the Rilas are over
2,600 meters. The highest peaks are characterized by sparse bare rocks
and remote lakes above the tree line. The lower peaks, however, are
covered with alpine meadows that give the range an overall impression of
green beauty. The Pirin range is characterized by rocky peaks and stony
slopes. Its highest peak is Mount Vikhren, at 2,915 meters the
secondhighest peak in Bulgaria.
The largest basin in Bulgaria is the Sofia Basin. About twentyfour
kilometers wide and ninety-six kilometers long, the basin contains the
capital city and the area immediately surrounding it. The route through
basins and valleys from Belgrade to Istanbul (formerly Constantinople)
via Sofia has been historically important since Roman times, determining
the strategic significance of the Balkan Peninsula. Bulgaria's largest
cities were founded on this route. Paradoxically, although the mountains
made many Bulgarian villages and towns relatively inaccessible, Bulgaria
has always been susceptible to invasion because no natural obstacle
blocked the route through Sofia.
A significant part of Bulgaria's land is prone to earthquakes. Two
especially sensitive areas are the borders of the North Bulgarian Swell
(rounded elevation), the center of which is in the Gorna Oryakhovitsa
area in north-central Bulgaria, and the West Rhodopes Vault, a wide area
extending through the Rila and northern Pirin regions to Plovdiv in
south-central Bulgaria. Especially strong tremors also occur along
diagonal lines running between Skopje in the Republic of Macedonia and
Razgrad in northeast Bulgaria, and from Albania eastward across the
southern third of Bulgaria through Plovdiv. Sixteen major earthquakes
struck Bulgaria between 1900 and 1986, the last two in Strazhitsa on the
SkopjeRazgrad fault line. Together the two quakes damaged over 16,000
buildings, half of them severely. One village was almost completely
leveled, others badly damaged. Many inhabitants were still living in
temporary housing four years later.
Drainage
The Balkan Mountains divide Bulgaria into two nearly equal drainage
systems. The larger system drains northward to the Black Sea, mainly by
way of the Danube River. This system includes the entire Danubian
Plateau and a stretch of land running forty-eight to eighty kilometers
inland from the coastline. The second system drains the Thracian Plain
and most of the higher lands of the south and southwest to the Aegean
Sea. Although only the Danube is navigable, many of the other rivers and
streams in Bulgaria have a high potential for the production of
hydroelectric power and are sources of irrigation water.
Of the Danube's Bulgarian tributaries, all but the Iskur rise in the
Balkan Mountains. The Iskur flows northward to the Danube from its
origin in the Rila Mountains, passing through Sofia's eastern suburbs
and through a Balkan Mountain valley.
The Danube gets slightly more than 4 percent of its total volume from
its Bulgarian tributaries. As it flows along the northern border, the
Danube averages 1.6 to 2.4 kilometers in width. The river's highest
water levels usually occur during June floods; it is frozen over an
average of forty days per year.
Several major rivers flow directly to the Aegean Sea. Most of these
streams fall swiftly from the mountains and have cut deep, scenic
gorges. The Maritsa with its tributaries is by far the largest draining
all of the western Thracian Plain, all of the Sredna Gora, the southern
slopes of the Balkan Mountains, and the northern slopes of the eastern
Rhodopes. After it leaves Bulgaria, the Maritsa forms most of the
Greek-Turkish border. The Struma and the Mesta (which separate the Pirin
Mountains from the main Rhodopes ranges) are the next largest Bulgarian
rivers flowing to the Aegean. The Struma and Mesta reach the sea through
Greece.
Climate
Considering its small area, Bulgaria has an unusually variable and
complex climate. The country lies between the strongly contrasting
continental and Mediterranean climatic zones. Bulgarian mountains and
valleys act as barriers or channels for air masses, causing sharp
contrasts in weather over relatively short distances. The continental
zone is slightly larger, because continental air masses flow easily into
the unobstructed Danubian Plain. The continental influence, stronger
during the winter, produces abundant snowfall; the Mediterranean
influence increases during the summer and produces hot, dry weather. The
barrier effect of the Balkan Mountains is felt throughout the country:
on the average, northern Bulgaria is about one degree cooler and
receives about 192 more millimeters of rain than southern Bulgaria.
Because the Black Sea is too small to be a primary influence over much
of the country's weather, it only affects the immediate area along its
coastline.
The Balkan Mountains are the southern boundary of the area in which
continental air masses circulate freely. The Rhodope Mountains mark the
northern limits of domination by Mediterranean weather systems. The area
between, which includes the Thracian Plain, is influenced by a
combination of the two systems, with the continental predominating. This
combination produces a plains climate resembling that of the Corn Belt
in the United States, with long summers and high humidity. The climate
in this region is generally more severe than that of other parts of
Europe in the same latitude. Because it is a transitional area, average
temperatures and precipitation are erratic and may vary widely from year
to year.
Average precipitation in Bulgaria is about 630 millimeters per year.
Dobruja in the northeast, the Black Sea coastal area, and parts of the
Thracian Plain usually receive less than 500 millimeters. The remainder
of the Thracian Plain and the Danubian Plateau get less than the country
average; the Thracian Plain is often subject to summer droughts. Higher
elevations, which receive the most rainfall in the country, may average
over 2,540 millimeters per year.
The many valley basins scattered through the uplands have temperature
inversions resulting in stagnant air. Sofia is located in such a basin,
but its elevation (about 530 meters) tends to moderate summer
temperature and relieve oppressive high humidity. Sofia also is
sheltered from the northern European winds by the mountains that
surround its troughlike basin. Temperatures in Sofia average -2�C in
January and about 21�C in August. The city's rainfall is near the
country average, and the overall climate is pleasant.
The coastal climate is moderated by the Black Sea, but strong winds
and violent local storms are frequent during the winter. Winters along
the Danube River are bitterly cold, while sheltered valleys opening to
the south along the Greek and Turkish borders may be as mild as areas
along the Mediterranean or Aegean coasts.
Environment
Like the other European members of the Council for Mutual Economic
Assistance (Comecon), Bulgaria saw unimpeded industrial growth as a
vital sign of social welfare and progress toward the socialist ideal.
Because this approach made environmental issues a taboo subject in
socialist Bulgaria, the degree of damage by postwar industrial policy
went unassessed until the government of Todor Zhivkov (1962-89) was
overthrown in late 1989. The Zhivkov government's commitment to heavy
industry and lack of money to spend on protective measures forced it to
conceal major environmental hazards, especially when relations with
other countries were at stake. Factories that did not meet environmental
standards paid symbolic fines and had no incentive to institute real
environmental protection measures. Even as late as 1990, socialist
officials downplayed the effects on Bulgaria of radiation from the 1986
nuclear power plant accident at Chernobyl'. Citizens were informed that
they need not take iodine tablets or use any other protective measures.
In 1991 Bulgarian environmentalists estimated that 60 percent of the
country's agricultural land was damaged by excessive use of pesticides
and fertilizers and by industrial fallout. In 1991 twothirds of
Bulgarian rivers were polluted, and the Yantra River was classified as
the dirtiest river in Europe. By that time, about two-thirds of the
primary forests had been cut. However, despite its recognition of the
need for greater environmental protection, Bulgaria budgeted only 10.4
billion leva to remedy ecological problems in 1991.
Perhaps the most serious environmental problem in Bulgaria was in the
Danube port city of Ruse. From 1981 to 1989, the chemical pollution that
spread from a chlorine and sodium plant across the Danube in Giurgiu,
Romania, was a forbidden subject in Bulgaria because it posed a threat
to good relations between two Warsaw Pact countries. Chemical plants in
Ruse also contributed to the pollution. Citizen environmentalists
opposing the situation in Ruse organized the first demonstrations and
the first independent political group to oppose the Zhivkov regime.
During the Giurgiu plant's first year of operation, chlorine levels in
Ruse almost doubled, reaching two times the permissible maximum in the
summer of 1990. Over 3,000 families left the city in the 1980s despite
government restrictions aimed at covering up the problem. Besides
chlorine and its byproducts , the plant produced chemical agents for the
rubber industry, and in 1991 some sources reported that the plant was
processing industrial waste from Western countries--both activities
likely to further damage Ruse's environment. International experts
claimed that half of Ruse's pollutants came from Giurgiu, and the others
came from Bulgarian industries. In response to the formidable Bulgarian
environmental movement, some Bulgarian plants have been closed or have
added protective measures; the Giurgiu plant, however, was planning to
expand in 1991.
Pollution of agricultural land from a copper plant near the town of
Srednogorie provoked harsh public criticism. The plant emitted toxic
clouds containing copper, lead, and arsenic. In 1988 it released toxic
wastewater into nearby rivers used to irrigate land in the
Plovdiv-Pazardzhik Plain, which includes some of Bulgaria's best
agricultural land. The groundwater beneath the plain also was poisoned.
Work has begun on a plan to drain toxic wastewater from the plant's
reservoir into the Maritsa River. Environmental improvements for the
copper plant and three other factories in the Plovdiv area (a lead and
zinc factory, a chemical factory, and a uranium factory) also were
planned, but they would take years to implement.
None of Bulgaria's large cities escaped serious environmental
pollution. Statistics showed that 70 to 80 percent of Sofia's air
pollution is caused by emissions from cars, trucks, and buses.
Temperature inversions over the city aggravated the problem. Two other
major polluters, the Kremikovtsi Metallurgy Works and the Bukhovo
uranium mine (both in southwestern Bulgaria), contaminated the region
with lead, sulfur dioxide, hydrogen sulfide, ethanol, and mercury. The
city of Kurdzhali became heavily polluted with lead from its lead and
zinc complex. In 1973 the petroleum and chemical plant near the Black
Sea port of Burgas released large amounts of chlorine in an incident
similar to the one in Srednogorie. Environmentalists estimated that the
area within a thirty-kilometer radius of the plant was rendered
uninhabitable by that release. The air in Burgas was also heavily
polluted with carbon and sulfur dioxide in 1990.
In 1990 environmental scientists claimed that two-thirds of
Bulgaria's population suffered from the polluted environment to some
degree. In 1991 Bulgaria began seeking international assistance in
solving environmental problems. Besides joining Romania, Turkey, and the
Soviet Union in joint scientific studies of the critically polluted
Black Sea, Bulgaria actively sought environmental technology and
expertise from Western Europe and the United States.
Bulgaria - Population
Since ancient times, Bulgaria has been a crossroads for population
movement. Early settlement occurred mainly in the most fertile
agricultural lands. After World War II, however, Bulgarian cities grew
rapidly at the expense of rural population in concert with state
industrialization policy.
Administrative Subdivisions
In 1991 Bulgaria was divided into nine provinces (oblasti--sing.
oblast). These administrative units included the city of Sofia
(Grad Sofiya) and eight provincial districts: Burgas, Khaskovo, Lovech,
Mikhaylovgrad, Plovdiv, Razgrad, Sofiya (the region outside the city),
and Varna. Each province was named for the city that was its
administrative center. Excluding the city of Sofia, the provinces
encompassed territories ranging from 9.5 percent of the country to 17.2
percent, and their population ranged from 7.5 percent to 14 percent of
the national total. The eight provinces were divided into a total of 273
communities (obshtini--sing. obshtina); the city of
Sofia was divided into districts (raioni--sing. raion).
Because this system was established in 1987, references to another type
of district, the okrug (pl. okruzi), remained common
in the early 1990s. The new government that took office in 1991
announced that yet another change was needed in Bulgaria's political
subdivisions because the 1987 system reflected the discredited policies
of the Zhivkov regime.
Settlement Patterns
The first settlements sprang up in Bulgaria very early in the area's
history. The biggest and most numerous villages appeared on fertile
lands such as the Danubian Plateau, the Dobruja region, and the Maritsa
and Tundzha river valleys. Settlements also took hold at very high
altitudes (up to 1,500 meters in the Rhodope Mountains and up to 1,200
meters in the Balkans), but only in areas where it was warm enough to
grow grain or other crops. During the rule of the Ottoman Empire, many
Bulgarians were forced to move into villages at higher altitudes. After
Bulgaria became independent in 1878, many people returned to the lower
altitudes, but most of the upland villages remained. The process of
urbanization began at that point, but it progressed slowly because of
wars, lack of employment in population centers, and the emigration of
the ethnic Turks who had supported the economies of some cities during
the Ottoman era. The massive industrialization of the communist era
again stimulated temporary settlement at high altitudes for mining or
forestry. Generally, only the highest areas in the Rila, Pirin, and
Rhodope mountains remained comparatively unsettled. These regions became
known for their national parks and seasonal resort areas.
Cities
Bulgaria's cities grew much more rapidly after 1944. In 1946 only
Sofia and Plovdiv had populations numbering over 100,000. By 1990, there
were ten cities having populations exceeding 250,000: Burgas, Dobrich
(formerly Tolbukhin), Pleven, Plodiv, Ruse, Shumen, Sliven, Sofia, Stara
Zagora, and Varna. In 1990 nearly one-third of Bulgaria's population
lived in the ten largest cities; two-thirds of the population was urban.
Although the urban birth rate declined after the mid-1970s, largescale
migration from rural areas to cities continued through 1990. At the same
time, migration from cities to rural areas more than doubled from the
1960s to the 1980s, mainly because more mechanical and service jobs
became available in agriculture during that period. In cities such as
Sofia and Plovdiv, where industrialization started earliest, the
population stabilized and the repercussions of rapid population growth
slowed down in the 1980s.
The population of the average Bulgarian city grew by three to four
times between 1950 and 1990. The rapidity of this growth caused some
negative trends. The cities often lacked the resources to serve the
needs of their growing populations: in particular, housing and social
services could not grow fast enough. The cities' great need for social
resources in turn diverted resources from smaller, more scattered
population centers. The overall rural-to- urban migration pattern caused
shortages of agricultural labor, especially in the villages surrounding
large cities. The government discouraged new industries from locating in
outlying areas because of the lack of workers.
Sofia was founded by the Thracians and has remained an important
population center for 2,000 years. Its location in a basin sheltered by
the Vitosha Mountains was strategically and esthetically desirable.
Long-established communication routes pass though Sofia, most notably
the route from Belgrade to Istanbul. Sofia's climate and location caused
the Roman Emperor Constantine to consider the city when he selected an
eastern capital for his empire in the early fourth century. Hot springs,
which still exist today, were an added attraction. After it became the
Bulgarian capital in 1879, Sofia became the administrative, educational,
and cultural center of the country. Because of Sofia's rapid postwar
growth (it grew by 36 percent between 1965 and 1986), in 1986 its city
government closed the city to all internal immigrants except scholars
and technical experts.
Plovdiv, the country's second most important city, was founded in the
fourth century B.C. by Philip of Macedonia. Its exposed location on the
route from Belgrade to Istanbul gave the city a violent history that
included several instances of capture and devastation--both by
non-Christian invaders and by Christian armies during the Crusades. At
the end of the twentieth century, Plovdiv remained an important
commercial city. More rail lines radiated from Plovdiv than from Sofia,
and the city had a university, important museums and art treasures, and
an old town center with a unique mid-nineteenth century architectural
style. Part of old Plovdiv was declared a national monument.
The three main port cities were Varna and Burgas on the Black Sea and
Ruse on the Danube River. A relatively young city, Burgas gained most of
its size in the late 1800s. Until the 1950s, it was the most active
Bulgarian port. Varna, which was founded by Greeks in the sixth century
B.C., eclipsed Burgas by attracting the naval academy and the chief
naval base and acquiring most of Bulgaria's shipbuilding industry. Ruse,
founded by the Romans in the first century B.C., grew into a major
industrial center and transportation hub after World War II. The first
bridge across the Danube between Bulgaria and Romania was built just
north of Ruse.
Internal Migration
The urbanization of Bulgaria began with independence from the Ottoman
Turks, but the process did not become widespread until the massive
industrialization of the communist era. In 1900 city dwellers composed
barely 20 percent of Bulgaria's population, and in 1945 they made up
only 24 percent. By the end of 1990, however, more than 6 million people
lived in the cities while fewer than 3 million lived in the villages.
Bulgarian demographers predicted that 75 percent of the population would
live in cities by the year 2000.
During the 1950s and 1960s, when the industrialization process was
most intense, most Bulgarians who moved were of working age, had a basic
education or less, and wished to obtain new jobs in industry. Fully 85
percent of internal migrants in the early 1960s went to work in an
industry. The trend of moving to locations with industrial jobs
continued at a reduced rate in the next decades, and migrants in the
1980s tended to be younger and better educated than those of earlier
years. The migrant population generally included more women than men.
This reflected women who moved to join the work force as well as women
who married and moved to join their husbands.
About two-thirds of migrant Bulgarians relocated within the same
province, so no region showed a marked population decline. The decline
in village population, however, concerned demographers, who feared that
villages would be completely vacated and the country's population
distribution severely skewed. By 1990 this had occurred most noticeably
in the southeastern and southern regions, but a similar trend was
evident in the northwest.
As workers continued to leave, village populations aged
demographically. The share of villages with an average population age
above fifty increased from 23 percent in 1956 to 41 percent in 1985.
Natural growth in villages, negative after 1975, fell to negative 6
percent in 1985. Some villages recorded no births for an entire year. As
the younger population decreased, schools and health facilities closed.
This in turn drove more people to leave their villages.
Meanwhile, demographers and sociologists encouraged younger
Bulgarians to return to the villages. Generally, those who followed this
advice because of housing shortages, transportation problems, or
pollution in the cities found hard, uncongenial work, a lower standard
of living, and scant public services and recreation. Many village
workers were forced to raise animals to supplement their regular income.
The beginning of democratization in 1990 sparked much debate about
whether the rural standard of living would rise if the government's
agricultural privatization program could stimulate agricultural
activity.
Foreign Citizens in Bulgaria
During the Zhivkov era, Bulgaria signed several friendship treaties
with other Comecon nations to ease the exchange of workers. In the
1980s, for example, a large number of Bulgarians worked in the
construction and timber industries of the Komi Autonomous Soviet
Socialist Republic (Komi ASSR) under an exchange agreement with the
Soviet Union. Workers were expected to return to their own countries
when their contracts ended, but they did not always do so. For example,
some Vietnamese construction workers sent to Bulgaria under Comecon
agreement in the 1980s remained, and in 1991 the Vietnamese population
of Bulgaria was 11,000. Because they arrived completely unprepared for
life in Bulgaria and began working after only one month of training and
language courses, the Vietnamese who remained in Bulgaria generally
received the hardest and lowest-paying jobs and often became involved in
criminal activity. In 1991 several violent incidents involving
Vietnamese provoked calls for their repatriation. In response, the
government made plans to expel all resident Vietnamese from Bulgaria in
1992.
Population Trends
The 1985 census recorded Bulgaria's population at 8,948,649, an
increase of 220,878 over the 1975 census figure. At the end of 1990, the
Central Statistical Bureau had estimated an updated figure of 8,989,172,
including about 100,000 more women than men. However, the estimates for
1989 and 1990 did not account for major emigrations in those years:
first the massive emigration of Turks in 1989, then the emigration of
ethnic Bulgarians in 1990. Adjusting for emigration figures, the
population figure actually decreased between 1985 and 1990. Bulgaria's
1989 population density figure of eighty-one people per square kilometer
made it one of the least densely populated countries in Europe.
Bulgaria's rate of population growth began a steady decrease in the
mid-1920s, and the trend accelerated thereafter. Before World War II, a
man's status in his community was determined by how many children
(especially sons) he had. Women who did not marry, or who married but
had no children, were seen as failures. As the country became more
urbanized, however, such traditional views gradually disappeared. Large
families were no longer the economic necessity they had been in
agricultural society, and extra children became a burden rather than a
boon. As women became more educated and less accepting of the
traditional patriarchal family norms, their attitude toward childbearing
changed. In 1990 the majority of Bulgarian women believed two children
ideal for a family, but because of economic and social conditions, their
personal preference was to raise only one. By the 1980s, this change in
attitude had begun to prevail even in villages and with less-educated
women. In 1985, 75 percent of Bulgarian women indicated that they would
not like to have any more children. Families with three or more children
became a rarity, and women who opted for more than two children had a
lower standard of living and were generally less respected in society.
Although few social planners advocated a return to the large families
of the past, Bulgarian policy makers were dismayed that the population
did not increase. During the Zhivkov era, the mass media and scholarly
journals expressed concern that the nine millionth Bulgarian had not yet
been born, and that families were unwilling to have two children instead
of one. By 1985 population experts were urging that 30 to 40 percent of
families have three children to make up for those which had none or only
one. Meanwhile, although the 1973 Politburo had affirmed a family's
right to decide how many children to have and when they should be born,
in the 1970s and 1980s contraceptives were not available in sufficient
quantity for family planning. Strict restrictions on abortions
established by the Zhivkov regime were repealed in 1990. Partly because
contraceptives were in short supply, abortions had surpassed births by
1985 despite the restrictions. Until 1990 bachelors and unmarried women
had to pay a 5 to 15 percent "bachelors' tax" depending on
their age. In a more positive step, laws provided family allowances for
children under sixteen. The age limit for the family allowance was
raised to eighteen in 1990 for children still in school.
In 1990 Bulgarian demographers recorded a negative growth rate
(negative 35 births per 1,000 population) for the first time. At that
point, the number of live births per woman was 1.81. Demographers
reported that the figure must increase to 2.1 to maintain the country's
natural rate of population replacement. Mortality figures in Bulgaria
were also much higher than those of the developed European countries.
The most alarming demographic trend of the late 1980s, however, was
substantially greater emigration totals. The 1989 Turkish exodus caused
by the Zhivkov assimilation campaigns had a severe impact on the
Bulgarian labor force. Then, in 1990, economic reform brought harsh
living conditions that stimulated a wave of emigration by ethnic
Bulgarians. As of March 1991, some 460,000 Bulgarians had emigrated,
bringing the total number of Bulgarians living abroad to about 3
million. The majority of the �migr� population remained in nearby
countries (1.2 million in Yugoslavia, 800,000 in other Balkan countries,
and 500,000 in the Soviet Union). Smaller numbers went as far as the
United States (100,000 to 120,000), Canada (100,000), Argentina
(18,000), and Australia (15,000).
Throughout its history, the Balkan Peninsula was a homeland for many
diverse ethnic groups that were able to preserve their national
identities despite being shifted among the jurisdictions of powerful
empires. In modern Bulgaria, the opposite has been true: the largest
minority ethnic group, the Turks, remained in territory that their
Ottoman ancestors had occupied. After the fall of the Zhivkov
government, Bulgaria moderated its minority policy substantially to
improve delicate relationships with neighboring countries such as Turkey
and Yugoslavia.
Government Minority Policy
The 1893 census listed the following nationalities and religious
groups in order of prevalence: Eastern Rite Orthodox Bulgarians, Turks,
Romanians, Greeks, Gypsies, Jews, Muslim Bulgarians, Catholic
Bulgarians, Tatars, Gagauzi (a Turkishspeaking people of the Eastern
Orthodox faith), Armenians, Protestant Bulgarians, Vlachs (a
Romanian-speaking people in southwest Bulgaria), and foreigners of
various nationalities, mainly Russians and Germans.
Migrations and boundary changes after the two world wars reduced the
list somewhat; few Greeks and Romanians remained in Bulgaria by 1990.
However, Bulgaria's communist leaders often tried to deny the existence
of minority groups by manipulating or suppressing census data or by
forcibly assimilating "undesirable" groups. In 1985, at the
height of the last anti-Turkish assimilation campaign, a leading
Bulgarian Communist Party official declared Bulgaria "a one-nation
state" and affirmed that "the Bulgarian nation has no parts of
other peoples and nations."
After the fall of Todor Zhivkov in 1989, all the minorities in
Bulgaria progressed somewhat toward self-determination and freedom of
expression. New minority organizations and political parties sprang up,
and minority groups began publishing their own newspapers and magazines.
Non-Bulgarian nationalities regained the right--curtailed in the Zhivkov
era--to use their original names, speak their language in public, and
wear their national dress. In 1991 significant controversy remained,
however, as to how far the rights of minorities should extend.
Legislators making policy on such issues as approval of non-Bulgarian
names and Turkish-language schools faced mass protests by nationalist
Bulgarians, who successfully delayed liberalization of government policy
on those issues.
Bulgarians
Bulgarians have been recognized as a separate ethnic group on the
Balkan Peninsula since the time of Tsar Boris I (852-89), under whom the
Bulgars were converted to Christianity. Early historians began
mentioning them as a group then; however, it is not clear whether such
references were to the earliest Bulgarians, who were Asiatic and
migrated to the Balkan Peninsula from the Ural Mountains of present-day
Russia, or to the Slavs that preceded them in what is now Bulgaria. By
the end of the ninth century, the Slavs and the Bulgarians shared a
common language and a common religion, and the two cultures essentially
merged under the name "Bulgarian".
Acceptance of the Eastern Orthodox church as the state religion of
the First Bulgarian Empire in A.D. 864 shaped the Bulgarian national
identity for many centuries thereafter. The Bulgarian language, which
was the first written Slavic language, replaced Greek as the official
language of both church and state once the Cyrillic alphabet came into
existence in the ninth century. National literature flourished under the
First Bulgarian Empire, and the church remained the repository of
language and national feeling during subsequent centuries of occupation
by the Byzantine and Ottoman empires.
Ottoman rule was the most formidable test of Bulgarian ethnic
identity. The Ottoman Turks forced many of their Christian subjects to
convert to Islam, and the Turks differentiated their subjects only by
religion, not by nationality. The latter policy meant that the empire
usually considered the Bulgarians as Greeks because of their common
Orthodox religion. Turkish recognition of the Greek Orthodox Church gave
the Greeks the power to replace Bulgarian clergy and liturgy with Greek,
further threatening Bulgarian national identity. Under the Ottomans,
some Bulgarians who had converted to Islam lost their national
consciousness and language entirely. Others (the Pomaks) converted but
managed to retain their old language and customs.
During the Ottoman occupation, the monasteries played an important
role in preserving national consciousness among educated Bulgarians.
Later, during the National Revival period of the nineteenth century,
primary schools and reading rooms (chitalishta) were
established to foster Bulgarian culture and literacy in cities
throughout Bulgaria. The vast majority of uneducated peasants, however,
preserved their customs in the less accessible regions in the mountains.
Traditional folk songs and legends flourished there and became richer
and more widely known than the literature created by educated
Bulgarians.
Bulgarian is classified as a South Slavic language, together with
Serbo-Croatian, Slovenian, and Macedonian. One of the oldest written
languages in Europe, Bulgarian influenced all the other Slavic
languages, especially Russian, in early medieval times. In turn the
Bulgarian language was enriched by borrowings from other civilizations
with which it came into contact. Besides 2,000 words from the
pre-Cyrillic Old Slavonic language, Bulgarians borrowed religious terms
and words used in daily life from the Greeks; vocabulary relating to
political, economic, and day-to-day life from Turkish; and many Russian
words to replace their Turkish equivalents as Ottoman influence waned
during the National Revival period. In the postwar era, many West
European words began to appear in Bulgarian, especially in technological
fields.
Turks
Because of their status as former occupiers, the Turks have had a
stormy relationship with Bulgaria since the beginning of its
independence. In 1878 Turks outnumbered Bulgarians in Bulgaria, but they
began emigrating to Turkey immediately after independence was
established. The movement continued, with some interruptions, through
the late 1980s. Between 1923 and 1949, 219,700 Turks left Bulgaria. Then
a wave of 155,000 emigrants either were "expelled" (according
to Turkish sources) or were "allowed to leave" (according to
Bulgarian sources) between 1949 and 1951. The number would have been far
greater had Turkey not closed its borders twice during those years. In
1968 an agreement reopened the BulgarianTurkish border to close
relatives of persons who had left from 1944 to 1951. The agreement
remained in effect from 1968 to 1978.
The biggest wave of Turkish emigration occurred in 1989, however,
when 310,000 Turks left Bulgaria as a result of the Zhivkov regime's
assimilation campaign. That program, which began in 1984, forced all
Turks and other Muslims in Bulgaria to adopt Bulgarian (Christian or
traditional Slavic) names and renounce all Muslim customs. Bulgaria no
longer recognized the Turks as a national minority, explaining that all
the Muslims in Bulgaria were descended from Bulgarians who had been
forced into the Islamic faith by the Ottoman Turks. The Muslims would
therefore "voluntarily" take new names as part of the
"rebirth process" by which they would reclaim their Bulgarian
identities. During the height of the assimilation campaign, the Turkish
government claimed that 1.5 million Turks resided in Bulgaria, while the
Bulgarians claimed there were none. (In 1986 Amnesty International
estimated that 900,000 ethnic Turks were living in Bulgaria.)
The motivation of the 1984 assimilation campaign was unclear;
however, many experts believed that the disproportion between the birth
rates of the Turks and the Bulgarians was a major factor. The birth rate
for Turks was about 2 percent at the time of the campaign, while the
Bulgarian rate was barely above zero. The upcoming 1985 census would
have revealed this disparity, which could have been construed as a
failure of Zhivkov government policy. On the other hand, although most
Turks worked in lowprestige jobs such as agriculture and construction,
they provided critical labor to many segments of the Bulgarian economy.
The emigration affected the harvest season of 1989, when Bulgarians from
all walks of life were recruited as agricultural laborers to replace the
missing Turks. The shortage was especially acute in tobacco, one of
Bulgaria's most profitable exports, and wheat.
During the name-changing phase of the campaign, Turkish towns and
villages were surrounded by army units. Citizens were issued new
identity cards with Bulgarian names. Failure to present a new card meant
forfeiture of salary, pension payments, and bank withdrawals. Birth or
marriage certificates would be issued only in Bulgarian names.
Traditional Turkish costumes were banned; homes were searched and all
signs of Turkish identity removed. Mosques were closed. According to
estimates, 500 to 1,500 people were killed when they resisted
assimilation measures, and thousands of others went to labor camps or
were forcibly resettled.
Before Zhivkov's assimilation campaign, official policy toward use of
the Turkish language had varied. Before 1958, instruction in Turkish was
available at all educational levels, and university students were
trained to teach courses in Turkish in the Turkish schools. After 1958,
Turkish-language majors were taught in Bulgarian only, and the Turkish
schools were merged with Bulgarian ones. By 1972, all Turkish-language
courses were prohibited, even at the elementary level. Assimilation
meant that Turks could no longer teach at all, and the Turkish language
was forbidden, even at home. Fines were levied for speaking Turkish in
public.
After the fall of Zhivkov in 1989, the National Assembly attempted to
restore cultural rights to the Turkish population. In 1991 a new law
gave anyone affected by the name-changing campaign three years to
officially restore original names and the names of children born after
the name change. The Slavic endings -ov, -ova, -ev, or -eva could now be
removed if they did not go with one's original name, reversing the
effect of a 1950s campaign to add Slavic endings to all non-Slavic
names. The law was important not only for Turks, but also for the
minority Gypsies and Pomaks who had been forced to change their names in
1965 and 1972 respectively. In January 1991, Turkish-language lessons
were reintroduced for four hours per week in parts of the country with a
substantial Turkish population, such as the former Kurdzhali and Razgrad
districts.
Macedonians
Beginning with the withdrawal of the Ottoman occupation, the region
known as Macedonia was divided among two or more European states. The
entire region was never included in a single political unit. In 1990
Macedonia included all of the Yugoslav republic of Macedonia, the Pirin
region of southwest Bulgaria, the part of northern Greece bordering the
Aegean Sea and including Thessaloniki, and a very small part of eastern
Albania. The Macedonian language, in which no written documents are
known to have existed before 1790, had three main dialects. One dialect
was closest to Serbian, one most resembled Bulgarian, and a third, more
distinctive group became the basis for the official language.
The region's location in the middle of the Balkans and its lack of
defined ethnic character made the dispute over the existence and
location of a separate Macedonian nationality and control over its
territory one of the most intractable Balkan issues of the late
nineteenth and twentieth centuries. In general Bulgaria and Greece
asserted that the Macedonians within their jurisdiction were ethnically
indistinguishable from the majority population. Yugoslavia saw the
Macedonians of all jurisdictions as a distinct ethnic group. But,
beginning with independence in 1878, Bulgarians also claimed various
segments of non-Bulgarian territory based on the ethnic Slavic
commonality of the Bulgarians and the Macedonians. Residual claims on
Macedonian territory were a primary reason for Bulgaria's decision to
side with Germany during both world wars. In the division of territory
after World War I, most of Macedonia became part of the Kingdom of the
Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes (later the Kingdom of Yugoslavia), and was
renamed "South Serbia." After World War II, Yugoslavia
strengthened its hold by making Macedonia a separate republic and
recognizing the Macedonians as a distinct nationality.
The Bulgarian position maintained that leading patriots such as Gotse
Delchev and Iane Sandanski (who had fought for Macedonian independence
from the Turks) and cultural figures such as the Miladinov brothers (who
promoted education and the Slavic vernacular during the National Revival
period) were products of Bulgarian culture and considered themselves
Bulgarians, not Macedonians. In 1990 many people in the Pirin region
identified themselves as Bulgarian, but some opposition Macedonian
organizations such as Ilinden (named after the 1903
IlindenPreobrazhensko uprising for Macedonian independence on St.
Elijah's Day) sought recognition by the Bulgarian government as a
minority separate from the Bulgarians. This position was based on the
assertion that Macedonians were a separate nationality with a distinct
language and history.
No reliable data showed how many people in Bulgaria, or in all of
Macedonia, considered themselves Macedonian or spoke a Macedonian
dialect in 1990. Those who considered the Slavs in Macedonia as
Bulgarians cited statistics for the whole region at the time it was
first divided after World War I. At that time, 1,239,903 Bulgarians, or
59 percent of the population, were listed. The Bulgarians were a
majority in both Yugoslav (Vardar) Macedonia (759,468 people) and in
Bulgarian (Pirin) Macedonia (226,700 people). Later Bulgarian censuses,
however, showed sharply varying numbers of Macedonians according to what
political agenda was to be supported by a given census. The 1946 census,
for example, identified over 250,000 Macedonians, reportedly to back
President Georgi Dimitrov's short-lived plan for federation with
Yugoslavia. Then, between the censuses of 1956 and 1965, the number of
Macedonians dropped from 187,789 to 9,632. After that time, the
Bulgarian census ceased identifying citizens by nationality.
Gypsies
Although Gypsies are known to have lived in Bulgaria since the
fourteenth century, most of the Gypsy population arrived in the past few
centuries. The last known group was forced to settle in 1958, having
remained nomadic until that time. The Gypsy population was divided into
three groups. According to the 1965 census, the last that enumerated
Bulgarians by nationality, 42.5 percent were Orthodox and spoke
Bulgarian; 34.2 percent were Orthodox and spoke Romanian or Romany, the
Gypsy language; and 22.8 percent were Muslim, spoke Turkish, and
considered themselves ethnic Turks. Estimates in 1990 put the Gypsy
population at about 450,000, some 10 percent of whom lived in the
southeastern city of Sliven.
The Gypsies had a long history as one of Bulgaria's most
disadvantaged and maligned nationalities. They were the focus of
official name-changing campaigns in every postwar decade between 1950
and 1990. Despite their numbers, Gypsies did not contribute much to
Bulgarian society because only about 40 percent of them attained the
educational and cultural level of the average Bulgarian. The other 60
percent lived in extremely disadvantaged conditions, isolated from the
mainstream of society by the Gypsy tradition of preserving ethnic
customs and by Bulgarian government policy. Government programs to
improve the lot of the Gypsies usually meant construction of new,
separate Gypsy neighborhoods rather than integration into Bulgarian
society. Housing in Gypsy neighborhoods was always poor and overcrowded.
In 1959 when a new neighborhood was built in Sofia, 800 people moved
into 252 apartments. Each apartment had one and one-half rooms and no
kitchen or inside plumbing. By 1990 about 3,000 people lived in these
same apartments.
The education of Gypsies who spoke Romany was inhibited because the
language has no alphabet or written literature. Gypsy children were
exposed to Bulgarian only in school, hampering completion of studies for
many. The illiteracy rate among Gypsies was believed to be still quite
high in 1990, although no statistics were available. According to the
only known literacy figures for nationalities, given in the 1926 census,
8.2 percent of Gypsies were literate compared with 54.4 percent of
Bulgarians overall. The Gypsy community exerted little pressure on
students to finish school; many dropped out before reaching legal
working age, increasing the tendency to marry and begin having children
early.
In 1990 about 70 percent of Gypsy workers were unskilled and worked
as general laborers, custodians, street cleaners, dishwashers, or in
other minimum-wage occupations. About 20 percent of Gypsies worked at
skilled jobs. The small Gypsy intelligentsia, which included musicians,
scholars, professionals in various fields, and political figures, tried
to influence their countrymen to gain more education and job skills.
Pressure also was exerted for elimination of separate Gypsy
neighborhoods and official replacement of the derogatory Bulgarian word tsiganin
with rom, the Romany word for Gypsy.
Other Minorities
Because of official suppression of nationality statistics, little
information was available on less numerous minorities in Bulgaria
between 1965 and 1990. Most of the Tatar population (6,430 in 1965) had
migrated from the Crimea to the cities of the Dobruja area in the
nineteenth century. The Greek minority (8,241 in 1965) comprised
political �migr�s from Greece and the remainder of a population in
southern Bulgaria that had been largely forced out of Bulgaria by
government oppression and violence between the world wars. The Armenian
population (20,282 in 1965) was mostly added between 1896 and 1924
during the massive emigration of Armenians from the Ottoman Empire. The
Armenians were concentrated in the cities, especially Sofia and Plovdiv.
In 1946 some 44,209 Jews remained in Bulgaria, which had conducted no
large-scale persecution despite its wartime alliance with Nazi Germany.
But the 1950s saw massive emigration of Jews to Israel, leaving only
5,108 in Bulgaria by the time of the 1965 census.
Bulgaria - RELIGION
The Bulgarian Orthodox Church, which played a crucial role in
preserving Bulgarian culture during the Ottoman occupation, remained
central to the sense of Bulgarian nationhood even under the postwar
communist regimes. In spite of the official status of Orthodoxy,
Bulgaria also had a tradition of tolerance toward other Christian
religions. Tolerance of Islam, however, remained problematic under all
forms of government because of that religion's historical identification
with the occupation and subjugation of Bulgaria.
Eastern Orthodoxy
In 1991 most Bulgarians were at least nominally members of the
Bulgarian Orthodox Church, an independent national church like the
Russian Orthodox Church and the other national branches of Eastern
Orthodoxy. Because of its national character and its status as the
national church in every independent Bulgarian state until the advent of
communism, the church was considered an inseparable element of Bulgarian
national consciousness. Baptism, before 1944 an indispensable rite
establishing individual identity, retained this vital role for many even
after the communists took power. The power of this tradition caused the
communist state to introduce a naming ritual called "civil
baptism" (grazhdansko krushtvane).
Although communist regimes could not eliminate all influence, they
did undermine church authority significantly. First, the communists
ruled that the church only had authority on church matters and could not
take part in political life. Second, although the constitution made the
church separate from the state, the clergy's salaries and the fees
needed to maintain the churches were paid by the state. This meant that
the clergy had to prove its loyalty to the state. From 1949 until 1989,
religion in Bulgaria was mainly controlled by the Law on Religious
Organizations, which enumerated the limitations on the constitution's
basic separation of church and state.
The number of Orthodox priests declined from 3,312 in 1947 to 1,700
in 1985. Priests associated with the prewar regime were accused of
engaging in illegal or antisocialist activities, supporting the
opposition, and propagandizing against the state. Upon taking control of
all church property, the state had the choice of maintaining churches or
closing them down. Thus, for example, Rila Monastery, the largest
monastery in Bulgaria, became a national museum in 1961.
In 1987 the Orthodox Church had 3,720 churches and chapels, 120
monasteries, 981 regular and 738 retired priests, 135 monks, and 170
nuns. The church was administered by a Holy Synod. Under communist rule,
the synod had the authority to publish limited quantities of religious
material such as magazines, newspapers, and church calendars. A new
translation of the Bible was published in 1982, but in such small
quantities that the size of the printing could not be determined. By
1988 the 1982 edition was being resold at ten times the original price.
After the fall of Zhivkov, the Orthodox Church and other churches in
Bulgaria experienced a revival. Church rituals such as baptisms and
church weddings attracted renewed interest, and traditional church
holidays were observed more widely. Christmas 1990, the first Christmas
under the new regime, was widely celebrated and greatly promoted in the
mass media. By contrast, Christmas had received little public attention
during the postwar years. The government returned some church property,
including the Rila Monastery, and religious education and Bible study
increased in the early post-Zhivkov years. The Orthodox seminary in
Sofia returned to its original home in 1990 and attracted over 100 male
and female students in its first year of operation. The Konstantin
Preslavski Higher Pedagogical Institute added a new theology department
to train theology, art, and music teachers as well as priests. The Holy
Synod planned to publish 300,000 Orthodox Bibles in 1992.
Islam
The Muslim population of Bulgaria, including Turks, Pomaks, Gypsies,
and Tatars, lived mainly in northeastern Bulgaria and in the Rhodope
Mountains. Most were Sunni Muslims because Sunni Islam had been more
widely promoted by the Ottoman Turks when they ruled Bulgaria. Shia
sects such as the Kuzulbashi and the Bektashi also were present,
however. About 80,000 Shia Muslims lived mainly in the Razgrad, Sliven
and Tutrakan (northeast of Ruse) regions. They were mainly descendants
of Bulgarians who converted to Islam to avoid Ottoman persecution but
chose a Shia sect because of its greater tolerance toward different
national and religious customs. For example, Kuzulbashi Bulgarians could
maintain the Orthodox customs of communion, confession, and honoring
saints. This integration of Orthodox customs into Islam gave rise to a
type of syncretism found only in Bulgaria.
As of 1987, Muslims in Bulgaria had 1,267 mosques served by 533 khodzhai,
or religious community leaders. The Muslim hierarchy was headed by one
chief mufti and eight regional muftis, interpreters of Muslim law, all
of whom served five-year terms. The largest mosque in Bulgaria was the
Tumbul Mosque in Shumen, built in 1744.
Bulgarian Muslims were subject to particular persecution in the later
years of the Zhivkov regime. This was partly because the Orthodox Church
traditionally considered them foreigners, even if they were ethnically
Bulgarian. The Bulgarian communist regimes declared traditional Muslim
beliefs to be diametrically opposed to communist and Bulgarian beliefs.
This justified repression of Muslim beliefs and consolidation of Muslim
into the larger society as part of the class and ideological struggle.
Like the practitioners of the other faiths, Muslims in Bulgaria
enjoyed greater religious freedom after the fall of the Zhivkov regime.
New mosques were built in many cities and villages; one village built a
new church and a new mosque side by side. Some villages organized Quran
(also seen as Koran) study courses for young people (study of the Quran
had been completely forbidden under Zhivkov). Muslims also began
publishing their own newspaper, Miusiulmani, in both Bulgarian
and Turkish.
Roman Catholicism
Roman Catholic missionaries first tried to convert the Bulgarians
during the reign of Boris I. They were unsuccessful, and Boris I led the
Bulgarians in their conversion to Orthodoxy. In 1204 the Bulgarian Tsar
Kaloian (1197-1207) formed a short-lived union between the Roman
Catholic Church and the Bulgarian Orthodox Church as a political tactic
to balance the religious power of the Byzantine Empire. The union ended
when Rome declared war on Bulgaria and the Bulgarian patriarchate was
reestablished in 1235. The Catholic Church had no influence in the
Bulgarian Empire after that date.
Nonetheless, Catholic missionaries renewed their interest in Bulgaria
during the sixteenth century, when they were aided by merchants from
Dubrovnik on the Adriatic. In the next century, Vatican missionaries
converted most of the Paulicians, the remainder of a once-numerous
heretical Christian sect, to Catholicism. Many believed that conversion
would bring aid from Western Europe in liberating Bulgaria from the
Ottoman Empire. By 1700, however, the Ottomans began persecuting
Catholics and preventing their Orthodox subjects from converting.
After Bulgaria became independent, the Catholic Church again tried to
increase its influence by opening schools, colleges, and hospitals
throughout the country, and by offering scholarships to students who
wished to study abroad. Prince Ferdinand of SaxeCoburg -Gotha, first
ruler of independent Bulgaria, was himself Catholic and supported the
Vatican in these efforts. The papal nuncio Angelo Roncalli, who later
became Pope John XXIII, played a leading role in establishing Catholic
institutions in Bulgaria and in establishing diplomatic relations
between Bulgaria and the Vatican in 1925.
The communist era was a time of great persecution for Catholics,
nominally because Catholicism was considered the religion of fascism.
Bulgarian communists also deemed Catholicism a foreign influence
because, unlike Orthodoxy, it had no ties to Russia. The logic was that
anything anti-Russian must also be antiBulgarian . Under the communist
regimes, Catholic priests were charged with following Vatican orders to
conduct antisocialist activities and help opposition parties. In 1949
foreign priests were forbidden to preach in Bulgaria, and the papal
nuncio was forbidden to return to Bulgaria. Relations between the
Vatican and Bulgaria were severed at that time. During the
"Catholic trials" of 1951-52, sixty priests were convicted of
working for Western intelligence agencies and collecting political,
economic, and military intelligence for the West. Four priests were
executed on the basis of these charges. In the early 1950s, the property
of Catholic parishes was confiscated, all Catholic schools, colleges,
and clubs were closed, and the Catholic Church was deprived of its legal
status. Only nominal official toleration of Catholic worship remained.
In 1991 about 44,000 Roman Catholics remained in Bulgaria, mostly in
Ruse, Sofia, and Plovdiv. Another 18,000 Uniate Catholics were
concentrated in Sofia. (Uniate Catholics recognize the pope as their
spiritual leader, but practice the Eastern Orthodox rite.) Bulgaria
reestablished relations with the Vatican in 1990, and the Bulgarian
government invited the pope to visit Bulgaria. Uniate Catholics began
assisting Western-rite Catholics in conducting masses in Bulgarian,
making the liturgy more accessible, and prompting predictions that the
two branches would unite. Relations had not been established between the
Bulgarian Orthodox Church and the Roman Catholic Church in 1991,
however, and Catholics blamed official Orthodox intolerance for the
continued rift.
Protestantism
Protestantism was introduced in Bulgaria by missionaries from the
United States in 1857-58, amid the National Revival period. The two main
denominations, the Methodists and Congregationalists, divided their
areas of influence. The former predominated in northern Bulgaria and the
latter in the south. In 1875 the Protestant denominations united in the
Bulgarian Evangelical Philanthropic Society, which later became the
Union of Evangelical Churches in Bulgaria. Besides setting up churches,
the Protestants established schools, clinics, and youth clubs, and they
distributed copies of the Bible and their own religious publications in
Bulgarian. The Union of Evangelical Churches produced the first
translation of the entire Bible into Bulgarian in 1871 and founded the
nondenominational Robert College in Constantinople, where many Bulgarian
leaders of the post-independence era were educated. After independence
in 1878, the Protestants gained influence because they used the
vernacular in services and in religious literature.
The communist regimes subjected Protestants to even greater
persecution than the Catholics. In 1946 church funding was cut off by a
law curbing foreign currency transactions. Because many ministers had
been educated in the West before World War II, they were suspected
automatically of supporting the opposition parties. In 1949 thirty-one
Protestant clergymen were charged with working for American intelligence
and running a spy ring in Bulgaria. All church property was confiscated,
and the churches' legal status was revoked. Most of the mainstream
Protestant denominations maintained the right to worship nominally
guaranteed by the constitution of 1947.
According to estimates in 1991, the 5,000 to 6,000 Bulgarian
Pentecostals made that sect the largest Protestant group. The
Pentecostal movement was brought to Bulgaria in 1921 by Russian �migr�s.
The movement later spread to Varna, Sliven, Sofia, and Pleven. It gained
popularity in Bulgaria after freedom of religion was declared in 1944,
and the fall of Zhivkov brought another surge of interest. In 1991 the
Pentecostal Church had thirty-six clergy in forty-three parishes, with
sufficient concentration in Ruse to petition the government to establish
a Bible institute there.
In 1991 the Adventist Church had 3,500 Bulgarian members, twothirds
of them young people. The Adventist movement began in the Dobruja region
of Bulgaria at the turn of the century and then spread to Tutrakan,
Ruse, Sofia, and Plovdiv. It gained momentum in Bulgaria after 1944.
Under the communist regimes, mainstream Adventists maintained the right
to worship. Some twenty parishes with forty pastors remained active
through that era, although a breakaway reformed group was banned because
of its pacifist beliefs. Some Adventists were imprisoned for refusal of
military service.
Judaism
The Bulgarian communist regimes officially considered Jews a
nationality rather than a religious group. For that reason, and because
nearly 90 percent of the country's Jewish population emigrated to Israel
after World War II, the Jewish society that remained in Bulgaria was
mainly secular. Under the Zhivkov regime, synagogues rarely were open in
Sofia, Samokov, and Vidin. In 1990 the Jewish population was estimated
at about 71,000. At that time, only two rabbis were active, although
several synagogues reportedly were reopened under the new regime. Most
of the Jews in Bulgaria were Sephardic, descended from Spanish Jews who
spoke Hebrew or Ladino (a Judeo-Spanish dialect). A much smaller number
were Ashkenazi, with Yiddish-speaking ancestors. However, very few Jews
in postcommunist Bulgaria remembered their ancestral languages, and
frequent mixed marriages further diluted feelings of Jewish identity.
The Jews of Bulgaria assimilated easily into Bulgarian society, partly
because they traditionally lived in cities and worked as tradesmen or
financiers.
The fate of the Bulgarian Jews during World War II was a source of
Bulgarian pride. The approximately 50,000 Jews then living in Bulgaria
had long been well integrated into the fabric of Bulgarian city life.
Because of this integration, neither society in general nor Tsar Boris
III was inclined to follow the anti-Jewish policies of Bulgaria's Nazi
ally. Boris tried to appease the Nazis by passing comparatively benign
anti-Jewish laws, which nevertheless were protested widely, especially
by the Bulgarian Orthodox Church. Twice in 1943, Boris personally
blocked orders to deport Bulgarian Jews, sending them instead to
so-called labor camps inside Bulgaria. Many Jews also received transit
visas to Palestine at this time.
Bulgaria - SOCIETY
Most manifestations of traditional Bulgarian familial and societal
relations disappeared in the initial postwar wave of modernization, but
some traditions proved surprisingly persistent and survived into the
1990s, especially in parts of western and southwestern Bulgaria.
Although postwar communist regimes nominally emphasized emancipation of
women, strong elements of paternalism and emphasis on traditional female
roles remained in Bulgarian society. By 1990 economic forces had
eliminated traditional extended families and limited the number of
children, especially in urban areas. Some evidence of resurging
traditional relationships was seen in the immediate post-Zhivkov years.
Traditional Society
Traditional Bulgarian society had three classes: the peasants (almost
everyone in the villages), the chorbadzhii (a small wealthy
class that owned large tracts of land and hired peasants to work them),
and the esnafi (skilled tradespeople in towns, who later became
the bourgeoisie). Most references to traditional Bulgarian society
described village or peasant society, because until the communist era
the great majority of Bulgarians were peasants.
The most important institution of traditional Bulgarian society was
the zadruga, an extended family composed of ten to twenty small
families, related by blood, who lived and worked together, owned
property jointly, and recognized the authority of a single patriarch.
The extended family most often included four generations of men, the
wives whom those men brought into the household through marriage, and
the children produced through those marriages. Once a girl married, she
would leave the zadruga of her parents for that of her husband.
No member of the zadruga had any personal property other than
clothes or the women's dowries.
Traditional Bulgarian society was strongly patriarchal. The zadruga
leader, called the "old man" or the "lord of the
house," had absolute power over his family and was treated with the
utmost respect. He was considered the wisest because he had lived the
longest. His duties included managing the purchase and sale of all
household property; division of labor among zadruga members;
and settling personal disputes. Older men within the household could
offer advice, but the "old man" had the final word. Obligatory
signs of familial respect included rising whenever he appeared and
eating only after he had begun and before he had finished his meal. The
"old man's" wife (or the senior woman if he were widowed) had
similar authority over traditional women's activities such as tending
the garden, observing holiday rituals, and sewing. The senior woman
commanded similar respect from zadruga members, but she was
never allowed to interfere in functions designated for men.
When a zadruga broke up (normally because it became too
large for easy management), property was divided equally among its
members. Before the twentieth century, many villages were formed as
outgrowths of an enlarged zadruga. The largest of the extended
family organizations in Bulgaria began breaking up in the 1840s. At that
time, the Ottoman Empire instituted new inheritance laws that did not
take zadruga property patterns into account. A second stage of
fragmentation occurred as the expectation of automatic integration into
the extended family gradually weakened in younger generations: sons
began leaving the zadruga at the death of the "old
man," and newly arrived wives failed to adjust to the traditional
system. As a result of such pressures, smaller households began to
proliferate in the nineteenth century.
The zadruga breakup accelerated after Bulgaria gained its
independence and began instituting Western-style laws that gave women
equal inheritance rights, although in many parts of Bulgaria women did
not begin demanding their legal inheritance until well into the
twentieth century. The disintegration of large family holdings gradually
led to the impoverishment of the peasants as land ownership became more
fragmented and scattered with each generation. The durability of the
extended family was reflected in the 1934 census, however, which still
listed a category of household size as "thirty-one and over."
Furthermore, even after extended families broke up, many peasants
continued to work cooperatively.
The familial system sometimes extended to include godparents and
adopted brothers and sisters--unrelated individuals enjoying the same
status as close relatives. Godparenthood included another set of
traditional relationships that knit village society together. Godparents
kept close ties with their godchildren throughout their lives, and the
godparent/godchild relationship could be transferred from generation to
generation. Godparents were treated with the utmost respect and had an
important role in all important events in a godchild's life, beginning
with baptism. The familial relationship was so strong that a taboo
developed against the marriage of children related to the same family
only through godparenthood.
After the decline of the zadruga, the patriarchal system
continued to flourish in the smaller families, where husbands gained
ownership of family property and all the patriarchal status the old men
once had. The status of wives remained distinctly secondary. Upon
marriage a woman still severed all ties with her family if her husband's
family lived in another village. Thus, couples always looked forward to
the birth of sons rather than daughters because sons always would remain
family members. Men traditionally married between the ages of twenty and
twenty-two; women, between eighteen and twenty. In areas where daughters
were needed as laborers at home, marriage might be postponed until age
twenty-five. Arranged marriages, common until the communist era,
persisted in the most traditional villages until the 1960s.
Only in the twentieth century did men begin to consult their wives in
family decisions. Until that time, wives were expected to give blind
obedience to their husbands. A woman who dared question or interfere in
a man's work was universally condemned. Women waited for a man to pass
rather than crossing his path, and wives often walked with heavy loads
while their husbands rode on horseback. The wife was responsible for all
work inside the house and for helping her husband in the field as well.
Children typically began to share in household work at the age of
five or six. At that age, girls began to do household work, and by age
twelve they had usually mastered most of the traditional household
skills. By age twelve or thirteen, boys were expected to do the same
field work as adults. Alternatively, boys might begin learning a trade
such as tailoring or blacksmithing at six or seven. As the size of
farmland parcels diminished and field labor became less critical, more
families sent children away from home to learn trades. Village boys
apprenticed in cities sometimes became accustomed to city life and did
not return to the village.
Family Life and Modern Society
Throughout the era of postwar communist modernization, family life
remained one of the most important values in Bulgarian society. In a
1977 sociological survey, 95 percent of women responded that "one
can live a full life only if one has a family." From the beginning
of the twentieth century until the 1970s, the marriage rate in Bulgaria
was stable at close to 10 percent per year. The rate was slightly higher
just after the two world wars. The rate fell beginning in 1980, however,
reaching 7 percent in 1989. Slightly more couples married in the cities
than in the villages, a natural development considering the ageing of
the village population. Most women married between the ages of eighteen
and twenty-five, most men between twenty and twenty-five. Village men
and less educated city men typically married before they were twenty.
The first men to marry often were those who had completed their military
service, did not plan further education, and could support themselves
financially. Those who continued their education often delayed marriage
until their late twenties. In choosing their spouses, the less educated
and those from more traditional regions of Bulgaria sought qualities
most highly valued in traditional society: love of hard work, modesty,
and good character. Among the educated classes, values such as personal
respect, commonality of interests, and education were more often
predominant in the choice of a spouse.
Until 1944 divorce was quite rare in Bulgaria, and great stigma was
attached to all individuals who had divorced. After 1944 the divorce
rate rose steadily until 1983, when it reached 16.3 percent. Between
1983 and 1986, however, the rate fell to 11.2 percent. In the 1980s, the
divorce rate in the cities was more than twice that in the villages, in
part because the village population was older. The divorce rate was
especially high for couples married five years or less; that group
accounted for 44 percent of all divorces. In 1991 the rate was
increasing, however, for those married longer than five years.
Concerned about Bulgaria's low birth rate, the government issued new
restrictions on divorce in its 1985 Family Code. The fee to apply for a
divorce was more than three months' average salary, and every
application for a divorce required an investigation. The grounds most
often listed in a divorce application were infidelity, habitual
drunkenness, and incompatibility.
In 1991 the average Bulgarian family included four people. Families
of two to five people were common, whereas families of six or more were
rare. In the larger families, moreover, the additional members usually
included one or two of the couple's parents. In 1980 extended families
spanning three or even four generations made up 17 percent of all
households, indicating the persistence of the extended family tradition.
Although the tradition was more prevalent in the villages of western and
southern Bulgaria than in the cities, many urban newlyweds lived with
their parents because they could not afford or obtain separate
apartments.
Socialist Bulgaria greatly emphasized the emancipation of women. The
1971 constitution expressly stated that "all citizens of the
People's Republic of Bulgaria are equal before the law, and no
privileges or limitations of rights based on national, religious, sex,
race, or educational differences are permitted" and that
"women and men in the People's Republic of Bulgaria have the same
rights." Bulgaria's Family Code also affirmed equal rights for men
and women.
In 1988 Bulgaria's work force included an almost equal number of men
(50.1 percent) and women (49.9 percent). By 1984 nearly 70 percent of
working women surveyed said that they could not imagine life without
their professional work, even if they did not need the pay. Only 9
percent of the women preferred being housewives. However, most men
surveyed in 1988 cited economics as the reason for their wives to work,
asserting that the wives should give up their work if they were needed
at home.
Household chores remained primarily the responsibility of women,
including most working wives. In 1990 the average working woman spent
eight and one-half hours at her job and over four and one-half hours
doing housework: cooking, washing dishes, washing clothes, ironing,
mending, and tending the children. In many households, such tasks were
still considered "women's work," to which husbands contributed
little.
In their social planning, Bulgarian legislators usually viewed their
country's women mainly as mothers, not as workers. Besides the laws
passed in an effort to increase the country's birth rate, legislators
passed laws giving certain privileges to women in the workplace, often
keeping their reproductive capability in mind. Women were prohibited by
law from doing heavy work or work which would adversely affect their
health or their capacities as mothers. The list of prohibited jobs
changed constantly, and women sought such jobs because they generally
offered better pay and benefits. Depending on the type of work, women
could retire after fifteen or twenty years, or after reaching age
forty-five, fifty, or fiftyfive . Women who had raised five or more
children could retire after fifteen years of work, regardless of their
age or type of work. Men were generally offered retirement after working
twenty-five years or reaching age fifty, fifty-five, or sixty. Some jobs
were restricted to women unless no women were available. Without
exception these were low-skill, low-paying jobs such as archivist,
elevator operator, ticket seller, coat checker, and bookkeeper. Other
jobs, such as secretary, stenographer, librarian, cashier, and cleaning
person were considered "appropriate for women." Men in the
workplace often expressed resentment of women in positions of authority.
Social Groups and Their Work
Postwar Bulgarian society was divided into three social groups,
according to type of work. Workers held jobs in the
"productive" manufacturing sector of the economy. Employees
worked in "non-productive" service and education jobs. The
third group was made up of agricultural workers. The
intelligentsia, usually considered a subsector of the employee category,
held professional or creative positions requiring specific
qualifications. In 1987 nonagricultural workers made up 63 percent of
the population; employees made up 18 percent, and agricultural workers
made up 19 percent. The intelligentsia made up 13.5 percent of the total
population in 1985. Both the nonagricultural worker and the employee
category grew about 15 percent between the censuses of 1975 and 1985,
but the number of agricultural workers dropped steadily through the
1970s and 1980s. Of all people in the work force in 1990, only 21.7
percent were rated as highly qualified. Sociologists warned that figure
would have to more than double if Bulgaria were to become economically
competitive with the West.
Most of those registered as workers had jobs in industry. Between
1975 and 1985, the number of workers in the machinebuilding ,
spare-parts and metal-processing industries increased. Other industries,
such as the food industry, the lumber industry, and the fuel industry,
lost workers. Most workers were comparatively young, with little
education and few work qualifications. In 1990 some 66.8 percent of
industrial workers had a basic education or less. However, young workers
were valued because they were considered most capable of adapting to new
technology--a critical requirement for upgrading Bulgaria's outdated
industrial infrastructure.
In the 1980s, employment grew in the trade, supply, construction, and
transportation sectors. But the sectors requiring primarily intellectual
work grew the fastest: research and research services, education, and
administration. After growing by 90 percent between 1965 and 1985,
administration included 26 percent of all employees and was the largest
division of this category. The housing sector was the only component of
the employee category that lost jobs between 1975 and 1990.
The number of agricultural workers decreased markedly from 50 percent
of all workers in 1965 to 20 percent in 1985. As agricultural production
intensified, many agricultural workers were transferred to
nonagricultural jobs. In the late 1980s, however, a shortage of
agricultural workers occurred because so many people had left the
villages. For this reason, labor-intensive farm activities such as
harvesting required recruitment of brigades from schools and
nonagricultural enterprises. Many of the remaining farm workers could
not adapt to new technology. This lack of adaptation inhibited the
modernization and mechanization of agricultural processes.
The democratization that followed the Zhivkov regime raised the
problem of unemployment, unknown in Bulgaria after 1944. As of April
1991, some 124,000 Bulgarians were unemployed, with no sign of
improvement in the midst of economic restructuring, enterprise
shutdowns, and scarcity of raw materials. The highest unemployment rates
occurred in Plovdiv and Sofia. Most unemployed persons were under age
thirty, and over 60 percent were women. Job vacancies continued to
decline in 1991, with most remaining opportunities in low-skilled jobs
or hard physical labor. Persons with the highest level of education,
such as engineers, economists, and teachers, were least likely to find
suitable positions. In 1990 the lack of skilled professional positions
spurred a "brain drain" emigration that further threatened
Bulgaria's ability to compete on technologically oriented world markets.
In the meantime, the country's economy had lost its protected position
as a member of the defunct Comecon, putting more pressure on the
domestic labor force.
Because the national welfare system could only accommodate those who
lost their jobs because of enterprise shutdown, in 1990 the Bulgarian
government began seeking ways to create more jobs. It considered
rewarding businesses that added shifts or offered parttime or seasonal
work, and it encouraged development of small business. One proposed
solution, replacing working pensioners with young unemployed workers,
was unworkable because enterprises found it less expensive to continue
hiring pensioners.
Bulgaria - SOCIAL SERVICES
Until the 1920s, peasants relied on traditional medicine and went to
a doctor or hospital only as a last resort. Traditional healers believed
that many illnesses were caused by evil spirits (baiane) and
could therefore be treated with magic, with chants against the spirits,
with prayers, or by using medicinal herbs. The knowledge of healing
herbs was highly valued in village society. For healing one could also
drink, wash, or bathe in water from mineral springs, some of which were
considered holy. Even in postcommunist Bulgaria, some resorted to herbal
medicine or to persons with reputed extrasensory healing powers.
Herbalists and "extrasenses" resurged in popularity in
Bulgaria after the overthrow of Zhivkov. Because of the skepticism of
conventional doctors, little research was done on the validity of
traditional herbal medicine, but in 1991 doctors began to consider
rating skilled herbalists as qualified specialists.
Beginning in 1944, Bulgaria made significant progress in increasing
life expectancy and decreasing infant mortality rates. In 1986
Bulgaria's life expectancy was 68.1 years for men and 74.4 years for
women. In 1939 the mortality rate for children under one year had been
138.9 per 1,000; by 1986 it was 18.2 per 1,000, and in 1990 it was 14
per 1,000, the lowest rate in Eastern Europe. The proportion of
long-lived people in Bulgaria was quite large; a 1988 study cited a
figure of 52 centenarians per 1 million inhabitants, most of whom lived
in the Smolyan, Kurdzhali, and Blagoevgrad regions.
The steady demographic aging of the Bulgarian population was a
concern, however. In the 1980s, the number of children in the population
decreased by over 100,000. The prenatal mortality rate for 1989 was 11
per 1,000, twice that in West European countries. In 1989 the mortality
rate for children of ages one to fourteen was twice as great as in
Western Europe. The mortality rate for village children was more than
twice the rate for city children. However, in 1990 some Bulgarian cities
had mortality rates as low as 8.9 per 1,000, which compared favorably
with the rates in Western Europe.
Poor conditions in maternity wards and shortages of baby needs
worried new and prospective mothers. Hospital staff shortages meant that
doctors and nurses were overworked and babies received scant attention.
Expensive neonatal equipment was not available in every hospital, and
transferral to better-equipped facilities was rare. In 1990 the standard
minimum weight to ensure survival at birth was 1,000 grams, compared
with the World Health Organization standard of 500 grams.
The number of medical doctors, nurses, and dentists in Bulgaria
increased during the 1980s. Bulgaria had 27,750 doctors in 1988, almost
6,000 more than in 1980. This meant one doctor for every 323 Bulgarians.
Some 257 hospitals were operating in 1990, with 105 beds per 1,000
people.
Like other aspects of society, health services underwent significant
reform after 1989. In 1990 health officials declared that the socialist
system of polyclinics in sectors serving 3,000 to 4,000 people did not
satisfy the public's need for more complex diagnostic services. They
claimed the system was too centralized and bureaucratic, provided too
few incentives for health personnel, and lacked sufficient modern
equipment and supplies. Thereafter, new emphasis was placed on allowing
free choice of a family doctor and providing more general practitioners
to treat families on an ongoing basis. Beginning in 1990, Bulgaria began
accepting donations of money and medicine from Western countries. During
the reform period, even common medicines such as aspirin were sometimes
in short supply. Prices for medicines skyrocketed. Shortages of
antibiotics, analgesics, dressings, sutures, and disinfectants were
chronic.
In November 1989, the Council of Ministers decreed that doctors could
be self-employed during their time off from their assigned clinics.
Doctors could work for pay either in health facilities or in patients'
homes, but with significant restrictions: when acting privately, they
could not certify a patient's health or disability, issue prescriptions
for free medicine, perform outpatient surgery or abortions, conduct
intensive diagnostic tests, use anesthetics, or serve patients with
infectious or venereal diseases. In 1990 the National Assembly extended
the right of private practice to all qualified medical specialists, and
private health establishments and pharmacies were legalized.
Church-sponsored facilities were included in this provision. The 1990
law did not provide for a health insurance system, however, and
establishment of such a system was not a high legislative priority for
the early 1990s.
In 1991 the government created a National Health Council to be
financed by 2.5 billion leva from the state budget plus funds from
donors and payments for medical services. The goal of the new council
was to create a more autonomous health system. Also in 1991, the
Ministry of Health set up a Supreme Medical Council and a Pharmaceutics
Council to advise on proposed private health centers, pharmacies, and
laboratories and to regulate the supply and distribution of medicine.
In 1988 the top three causes of death in Bulgaria were cardiovascular
illnesses, cancer, and respiratory illnesses. An expert estimated that
88 percent of all deaths were caused by "socially significant
diseases" that resulted from an unhealthy lifestyle and were thus
preventable. Strokes, the most prevalent cause of death, killed a higher
percentage of the population in Bulgaria than anywhere else in the
world. In 1985 nearly 58,000 Bulgarians suffered strokes, and nearly
24,000 of them died. The mortality rate for strokes was especially high
in northern Bulgaria, where it sometimes exceeded 300 fatalities per
100,000 persons. In villages the rate was three times as high as in the
cities. Doctors cited unhealthy eating habits, smoking, alcohol abuse,
and stress as lifestyle causes of the high stroke rate.
In 1990 about 35 percent of Bulgarian women and 25 percent of men
were overweight. Sugar provided an average of 22 percent of the calories
in Bulgarian diets, twice as much as the standard for balanced
nutrition. Another 35 percent of average calories came from animal fat,
also twice as much as the recommended amount. That percentage was likely
much higher in the villages, where many animal products were made at
home. Modernization of the food supply generally led to increased
consumption of carbohydrates and fats. In contrast, the traditional
Bulgarian diet emphasized dairy products, beans, vegetables, and fruits.
Large quantities of bread were always a key element of the Bulgarian
diet. Average salt consumption was also very high. In 1990 the average
Bulgarian consumed 14.5 kilograms of bread, 4.4 kilograms of meat, 12.6
kilograms of milk and milk products, 15 eggs, and 15 kilograms of fruits
and vegetables per month.
In the 1980s, Bulgaria ranked tenth in the world in per capita
tobacco consumption. Tobacco consumption was growing, especially among
young people. Each Bulgarian consumed 7.34 liters of alcohol per month,
not including huge amounts of homemade alcoholic beverages. Between 1962
and 1982, recorded alcohol consumption increased 1.6 times.
In 1990 an estimated 35 percent of the population risked serious
health problems because of environmental pollution. In the most polluted areas, the sickness rate increased by
as much as twenty times in the 1980s. By 1990, pollution was rated the
fastest-growing cause of "socially significant diseases,"
particularly for respiratory and digestive disorders. Doctors in the
smelting center of Srednogorie found that the incidence of cancer, high
blood pressure, and dental disorders had increased significantly in the
1980s.
Pollution had an especially adverse effect on the immune systems of
children. In the first few years of the Giurgiu plant's operation, the
number of deformed children born across the Danube in Ruse increased 144
percent. From 1985 to 1990, this number increased from 27.5 to 39.7 per
1,000. Miscarriages, stillbirths, and premature, low-weight births
doubled during that period. The infant mortality rate in Srednogorie was
three times the national average in 1990. Excessive lead in the soil and
water at Kurdzhali had caused a great increase in skin and infectious
diseases in children there. In 1990 environmental authorities named the
village of Dolno Ezerovo, near Burgas, the "sickest village in
Bulgaria" because over 60 percent of its children suffered from
severe respiratory illnesses and allergies.
In 1987 Bulgarian health authorities instituted limited mandatory
testing for human immunodeficiency virus (HIV), which causes acquired
immune deficiency syndrome (AIDS). All prospective marriage partners,
all pregnant women, and all transportation workers arriving from outside
Bulgaria were required to be tested. Hemophiliacs, Bulgarian navy
sailors who had traveled abroad after 1982, and students and workers
visiting vacation resorts also fell under this rule. As of October 1989,
some 2.5 million people in Bulgaria, including about 66,000 foreigners,
had been tested for HIV, and 81 Bulgarians were diagnosed as HIV
positive. According to government figures, six of that number had
contracted AIDS. Foreigners diagnosed as HIV positive were ordered to
leave the country. Bulgaria estimated it would spend over US$4 million
to treat AIDS and HIV-positive patients in 1991.
Bulgaria - Education
Before the National Revival of the mid-nineteenth century, education
usually took the form of memorization of the liturgy and other religious
material. Supporters of the National Revival movement were instrumental
in establishing and supporting Bulgarian schools in the cities--first
for boys, and later for girls as well. These activists also introduced
the chitalishta. Often located next to a school, the chitalishta
served as community cultural centers as well as reading rooms. The first
schools, which began opening in the early nineteenth century, often did
not go beyond a basic education; students wishing to continue their
education had to go abroad.
The educational system established after Bulgaria gained its
independence retained the same basic structure through 1989. The 1878
Temporary Law on National Schools established free compulsory education
in primary school for both sexes. The schools were designed to teach
reading, writing, and basic arithmetic. In practice, not everyone
received that education, but the law gave the villages an incentive to
open new schools. By the turn of the century, one-third of all Bulgarian
villages had primary schools. In the early days, the immediate demand
for a large number of teachers meant that many new teachers had little
more education than their students. Later reforms specified a seven-year
standard education with a curriculum based on a West European model.
Some peasants, especially uneducated ones, withdrew their children from
school because they believed the classes were unrelated to peasant life.
This led to the offering of textbooks and prizes as an incentive for
students from poorer families.
Communist rule in Bulgaria brought forth a new approach to education
as a means of indoctrinating Marxist theory and communist values.
Literacy was promoted so that the communist-controlled press could be
disseminated throughout society. New classes for both adults and
children aimed at providing as many as possible with a high-school
education and abolishing illiteracy. Schools switched their focus from
liberal arts to technical training and introduced a curriculum modeled
on that of the Soviet Union. Russian language study was introduced for
all, from kindergartners to adults who had already completed their
education. Copies of Pravda, the primary newspaper of the
Communist Party of the Soviet Union, were distributed even in isolated
villages. After the overthrow of Zhivkov, however, English became the
most studied foreign language in Bulgaria, and the study of Russian
declined dramatically.
In 1979 Zhivkov introduced a sweeping educational reform, claiming
that Marxist teachings on educating youth were still not being applied
completely. Zhivkov therefore created Unified Secondary Polytechnical
Schools (Edinna sredna politekhnicheska uchilishta, ESPU), in
which all students would receive the same general education. The system
united previously separate specialized middle schools in a single,
twelve-grade program heavily emphasizing technical subjects. In 1981 a
national program introduced computers to most of the ESPUs. The change
produced a chaotic situation in which teaching plans and programs had to
be completely overhauled and new textbooks issued to reflect the new
educational emphasis. This project proved unworkable, and by 1985 new
specialized schools again were being established.
The fall of Zhivkov resulted in a complete restructuring of the
country's educational system. In retrospect Bulgarian educators
recognized that the socialist way of educating was not only
bureaucratic, boring, and impersonal. It also led to disregard for the
rights of the individual, intolerance of the opinions of others, and
aggressive behavior. The centralized system with its regional
hierarchies was therefore scrapped in favor of a system of educational
councils in which every 400 teachers could elect a delegate to the
National Council of Teachers. The first goal of the new organization was
to depoliticize the schools in cooperation with the Ministry of Public
Education.
In 1991 the Bulgarian educational system consisted of three types of
schools: state, municipal, and private (including religious). The grade
levels were primary (first to fourth grade), basic (fifth to seventh
grade), and secondary (eighth to twelfth grade). Children began first
grade at age six or seven and were required to attended school until age
sixteen. Parents also had the option of enrolling their children in
kindergarten at age five. Secondary school students had the choice of
studying for three years at professional-vocational schools or for four
years at technical schools or general high schools. Religious schools
operated only on the high-school level. Specialized high schools taught
foreign languages, mathematics, and music; admittance to them was by
special entrance exams. Special programs for gifted and talented
children began as early as the fifth grade. Special schools also
operated for handicapped children. Children suffering from chronic
illnesses could receive their schooling in a hospital or sanatorium.
Prior to the postcommunist reform era, about 25,000 students dropped
out every year before reaching their sixteenth birthday; another 25,000
failed to advance to the next grade. Under the new system, parents could
be fined 500 to 1,000 leva if their children failed to attend school;
fines also were levied for pupils retained in grade for an extra year.
Public opinion on the educational reform focused mainly on
depolitization. By the 1990-91 school year, new textbooks had been
introduced in many subjects, but many of them were not completely free
of socialist rhetoric. A first-grade mathematics textbook published in
1990 contained the following exercise: "Count how many words there
are in this sentence: 'I am grateful to the Party, for it leads my
country to beautiful, radiant life and vigilantly protects us from
war.'" A newly published music book contained songs about the
party, a communist youth organization, and Lenin. Many teachers likewise
continued to espouse the communist rhetoric in which their profession
had been long and firmly indoctrinated. In late 1990, about 50,000 Sofia
University students demonstrated against poor education and against
continued requirements to attend courses in Marxism. Their protest
caused the university to eliminate compulsory political indoctrination
courses. The 1991 Law on Public Education declared that "no
political activity is allowed in the system of public education."
Depolitization was expected to be a slow process because of the
extent to which the schools had been politicized before 1990. At the end
of 1990, over 90 percent of all teachers were still members of the
Bulgarian Socialist (formerly Communist) Party. For this reason, the Law
on Public Education prohibited teachers from becoming members of
political parties for a period of three years, beginning in 1991.
Because the Zhivkov regime had tinkered often with Bulgaria's
educational system, longtime teachers had developed a cynicism toward
reform of any type. This attitude hampered the removal of the old
socialist structures from the educational system.
Some students married and began families while they were still in
school, and two-student families were not uncommon. Such families often
depended on help from parents because of their low income and because of
a shortage of student family housing. By 1990 most Bulgarian students
worked in their free time, unlike their predecessors in the 1970s and
early 1980s.
Reform also reached higher education. In 1990 a new law on academic
freedom emphasized the concept of an intellectual market in which
universities, teachers, and students must maintain high performance
levels to stay competitive. The law gave every institution of higher
learning the right to manage its teaching and research activities
without government interference. This right included control over
curriculum, number of students, standards for student admissions and
teacher hirings, training and organization of faculty, and the level of
contact with other institutions of higher learning in Bulgaria and
abroad. Students received the right to choose their own professors. The
higher education law was criticized for withholding students' rights and
because the legislature had failed to consult students in the law's
formulation.
In 1991 experts evaluated the state university system as weak in
critically needed technical fields of study. The availability of
interested students was also questioned. In the 1990-91 school year, no
graduate students with enterprise scholarships majored in subjects such
as computer systems, artificial intelligence systems, or ecology and
environmental protection. Graduate programs in critical nontechnical
fields such as management economics, marketing, production management,
and finance also had no students.
After the overthrow of Zhivkov, France and Germany made early
commitments to help Bulgaria carry out educational reforms. In 1991 the
United States began planning a new American college in Blagoevgrad,
where students would be taught in English using American educational
methods. The first 200 students were to include 160 Bulgarians, 20
students from neighboring European countries, and 20 Americans majoring
in Balkan studies. The University of Maine was to supply the teachers.
Plans called for business and economics to be the major areas of
concentration. Affordability was a potential barrier to participation in
this plan by Bulgarian students; the cost was low by American standards,
but far above the average Bulgarian's price range. And the tuition-free
Bulgarian university system was expected to lure many qualified students
from the new university. Nevertheless, Western education assistance was
an important symbolic step in moving the social institutions of Bulgaria
into the European mainstream, from which they had been isolated for
forty-five years.
Bulgaria - The Economy
Because of a low birth rate, labor shortages began to appear in
Bulgaria in the 1980s. Then in 1989, deportation of 310,000 ethnic Turks
created critical shortages in certain economic sectors. The dislocation
caused by the large-scale economic reform that began in 1990 introduced
high rates of unemployment and social insecurity to a system that
nominally had no unemployment under the central planning regime. A
period of protracted readjustment of labor to enterprise needs was
expected in 1991.
Factors of Availability
The total labor force in Bulgaria was 4.078 million in 1988. Of that
total, 35.9 percent were classified as industrial workers, 19 percent as
agricultural workers, and 18.9 percent as service workers. In 1985 some
56 percent of the population was of working age (16 to 59 years old for
men and 16 to 54 for women); 22.9 percent were under working age, and
21.1 percent were over working age. These figures indicate that the
population had aged demographically since 1946, when 30 percent of the
population was under the working age and only 12 percent were over.
Small growth rates and occasional declines of the Bulgarian labor force
increasingly inhibited economic growth in the 1980s. The meager growth
in the labor force was due primarily to a birthrate that began declining
before World War II.
Declining population growth did not affect Bulgarian economic
planning and performance for a number of years. In the 1950s and 1960s,
the expanding labor requirements of industrial growth were accommodated
by a steady influx of peasant labor from the countryside and by the
nationalization of artisan shops in 1951. This migration slowed,
however, and complaints of an industrial labor shortage were common by
the late 1960s. The situation was exacerbated in 1974 when the
government reduced the work week from 48 to 42.5 hours. By the early
1980s, Bulgaria's urban working-age population had begun to decline in
absolute terms. Then in May 1989, ethnic strife caused thousands of
ethnic Turks to leave Bulgaria for Turkey. In August Turkish authorities
finally closed the border, but only after 310,000 ethnic Turks had left
the country, taking with them a substantial chunk of the Bulgarian work
force. In addition, a significant "brain drain" threatened in
1990 when large numbers of young, highly educated Bulgarians applied to
leave the country. In the first four months of 1990, at a time when the
country desperately needed its professional class to restructure society
and the economy, 550,000 such applications were received.
Labor statistics reflect a distinct change of economic priorities
from agriculture to industry under communist regimes. From 1948 to 1988,
the shares of labor in industry and agriculture shifted dramatically.
Industry's share rose from 7.9 to 38 percent, while agriculture's share
fell from 82.1 to 19.3 percent. Among other sectors, in 1988
construction, transportation and communications, and trade respectively
accounted for 8.3, 6.7, and 8.7 percent of employment.
Labor and Economic Reform
Under communist rule, unemployment officially was nonexistent. Like
many other Soviet-style economies, however, the Bulgarian system
included much underemployment and hoarding of surplus workers,
particularly in industry. While in power, the BCP set wage and work
norms. Average annual earnings rose from 2,185 leva in 1980 to 2,953
leva in 1988. Earnings were highest in the research, state
administration, construction, transport, and finance sectors, in that
order. Agriculture and forestry were among the lowest paid sectors.
After the overthrow of Zhivkov, reasonable use of industrial capacity
was expected to maintain a tight labor market for the foreseeable future
because the labor force had ceased to grow. Women already accounted for
approximately 50 percent of the labor force in 1988; therefore, little
additional growth was expected from that part of the population.
Similarly, little growth was expected from among voluntarily employed
pensioners and invalids. However, the tight labor supply was not the
most pressing concern of the first post-Zhivkov economic planners. The
economic transformation from centralized planning to a market economy
meant increased influence by market factors on wage and unemployment
rates in the future. This transformation also made high unemployment
likely as state enterprises closed and generation of goods and services
shifted to an expanded private sector. But this intermediate dislocation
was thought necessary to achieve correlation between wages and
productivity.
Unemployment, which stood at 72,000 at the beginning of 1991, was
expected to jump to at least 250,000 by the end of that year because of
the planned transition to a market structure. In 1990 the interim
government of Petur Mladenov created a national labor exchange to assist
in placing unemployed workers. Unemployment assistance remained a state
responsibility, but the state had very little money for this purpose in
1991. Plans called for eventual contribution by private employers to a
designated unemployment fund.
Bulgaria - The Economy - ECONOMIC STRUCTURE
Until late 1989, Bulgaria had a command economy based on centralized
planning rather than on market forces. In such a system, crucial
economic decisions such as allocation of output, rates of expansion of
various sectors, values of goods and services, and the exchange rate of
the national currency were made administratively, not by the market.
Bulgaria's faithful adherence to the Soviet model of economic planning
included rapid industrialization, large-scale investments, and other
resource allocation to heavy industry at the expense of light industry
and agriculture, higher rates of spending for capital investment than
for consumption purchases, and forced nationalization of industry and
collectivization of agriculture.
The Centrally Planned Economy
Proponents of centrally planned economies (CPEs) maintained that the
advantages of such systems far outweighed the disadvantages. They
believed that in many respects economic competition wasted society's
resources. In other words, what Marx called the "anarchy of the
market" led producers and consumers to expend resources in
activities that became unnecessary when they worked in harmony rather
than in competition. Planning could give priority to social goals over
economic ones. Should the government decide that the development of
health professionals was important to society, for example, it could
earmark funds for that purpose. Proponents of CPEs also claimed that
they could insulate their economies from the ups and downs of the
business cycle, a phenomenon which Western economies never have been
able to avoid. Theoretically, CPEs were designed to be immune to
economic (and social) losses such as reduced output and unemployment
associated with economic downturns. (As their national economies became
more interrelated with international markets, however, CPE proponents
admitted the difficulty of isolating themselves from swings in world
economic conditions.) Another theoretical advantage was that economic
decisions could be based on long-range goals because the financial
losses of any individual enterprise or industry could be offset by
profits in other areas of the economy. And, since the organization of
the entire industrial and agricultural base was determined
administratively, economies of scale could easily be incorporated into
the planning process.
Western economists were generally critical of the CPE, however. Their
criticisms had two essential components. First, central economic
planners often were unable to plan an economy efficiently; and second,
even when they could plan well, they were unable to achieve the goals
they planned. These general assertions proved true regarding specific
aspects of Bulgaria's command economy, and they had ramifications for
efforts to reorganize that economy in the 1990s.
The CPE induced enterprises to seek low production targets,
concealing productive capacity and never overfulfilling the plan by too
much, lest higher targets be set in the next plan. The result was
underutilized resources. Plans tended to stress quantity over quality.
Simply requiring a particular level of output was insufficient if that
output were of such poor quality that no one bought it, or if there were
no need for such a product in the beginning. The consumer had no
effective control over the producer when quality was low, and the
artificial price structure prevented price signals from alerting
producers to consumer preferences. Also, because enterprises were judged
on their fulfillment of the plan, producers geared production levels for
satisfying the plan, not consumers.
The CPE could induce technical progress from above, but it could not
stimulate it from below. The plan discouraged enterprise innovation,
because innovation meant interrupting current production, hence
jeopardizing plan fulfillment. The system also encouraged waste and
hoarding of fixed and working capital, and the wage system failed to
encourage workers to work harder or managers to economize on labor.
Under Zhivkov Bulgaria attempted to deal with these problems by a series
of reforms in both industry and agriculture. These reforms included
alternately centralizing and decentralizing economic management; adding
and deleting economic ministries and committees; revising the economic
indicators for plan fulfillment; and encouraging or discouraging
elements of private enterprise. Despite such experimentation, however,
Bulgaria remained faithful to the general Soviet model for over four
decades. In the years after the end of communist rule, the CPE remained
the predominant structural element in the Bulgarian economy, especially
in large enterprise management.
The Planning System
Prior to 1990, the planning hierarchy in Bulgaria included several
levels. The ultimate economic authority was the BCP. The party
determined general economic policies, identified economic reforms and
their structure, and monitored economic activity. Planning and control
were the responsibility of the Council of Ministers, which was roughly
equivalent to a Western cabinet. The most important planning committee
within the Council of Ministers was the State Planning Committee (SPC).
Within the Council of Ministers were specialized economic ministries,
such as the Ministry of Finance and the Ministry of Foreign Trade, and
various governmental committees and commissions. The composition and
authority of the ministries underwent frequent change. In 1986, for
example, six ministries with economic powers were eliminated and five
cabinet-level "voluntary associations" were formed. The
aftermath of these changes, however, showed few new power relationships.
In the later Zhivkov years, the prime responsibilities of ministry-level
agencies included forecasting development of their industries, assessing
development bottlenecks, and generally overseeing state development
policy. However, the ministries were not to participate actively in
planning. That was a function of the associations.
The associations, also known as trusts, were an intermediary
organization between the ministries and the lowest level of the planning
hierarchy, the enterprise. The association integrated production,
research and development, design, construction, and foreign trade
functions. Unlike associations in the Soviet Union, which were merely an
intermediary link in the chain of economic command, Bulgarian
associations retained several essential decision-making prerogatives and
were in direct contact with centers of economic power such as the SPC,
the Ministry of Finance, and the Bulgarian National Bank (BNB). At the
bottom of the economic hierarchy, enterprises were distinct economic
entities that operated under an independent accounting system. They were
expected to earn a planned amount of profit, a portion of which went to
the state as a profits tax.
In the Bulgarian command economy, almost all economic activity was
directed toward plan fulfillment. Economic directives were outlined
extensively in the plans, which were not merely guidelines but binding,
legal documents. The best known of these was the FiveYear Plan, although
planning was done for longer and shorter periods as well. Most important
for the day-to-day operations of enterprises were the annual and monthly
plans.
One of the most important tasks of central planning was what was
referred to as material balances--planning for correspondence
between supply and demand of goods. At the draft plan stage, this
required that supply (planned output, available stocks, and planned
imports) equal demand (domestic demand and exports) for every industry.
When demand exceeded supply, planners could increase planned output,
increase imports, or reduce domestic demand. The SPC usually favored the
last alternative. This manipulation limited the flow of inputs to
low-priority industrial branches, which most often made consumer items,
resulting in shortages of those goods.
The party began the planning process by providing priorities and
output targets for critical commodities to the SPC, which reconciled
them with required inputs. A draft plan then was created by a process of
negotiation and information exchange up and down the planning hierarchy.
After negotiating with the SPC on targets and resources and formulating
specific guidelines, the associations then negotiated with their
individual enterprises to establish final figures. The output targets
then went back to the SPC for a final negotiation with the associations.
The final version of the plan was submitted to the Council of
Ministers for approval or modification, after which the approved targets
were sent down the hierarchy to the individual firms. Thus enterprises
were informed of their binding norms for a planning period, including
volume and mix of output, procurement limits, level of state investment,
foreign currency earnings, foreign currency limits for imports, and wage
rates. An important element of the plan fulfillment stage was
manipulation of resources by ministries and the SPC to ensure
fulfillment of priority targets and minimize bottlenecks. Occasionally,
reforms allowed enterprises rather than higher echelons to make many of
these decisions. For most of the communist era, however, this was not
the case.
Bulgaria - The Economy - ECONOMIC POLICY AND PERFORMANCE
Bulgarian postwar economic development can be divided into four
phases: the revolutionary period (1944 through 1948); the development of
socialism (1949 through 1960); the age of intermittent reform (1961
through 1989); and the transformation to a market economy (beginning in
1990).
Postwar Economic Policy
After the BCP came to power in 1944, the transition to socialism
began slowly. Before World War II, the Bulgarian economy had been
agrarian and decentralized, so the industrial base was relatively
undeveloped. Following the Soviet model, the BCP first sought control
over as many facets of the economy as possible. Thus, restructuring
included collectivizing agriculture, confiscating private enterprises,
nationalizing industry, and enacting various fiscal and monetary
measures.
In the 1940s, the BCP viewed the agricultural sector as a major
obstacle to the transformation of the economy. Although collectivization
proceeded slowly at first, state power in the agricultural markets was
quickly established by nationalizing internal and foreign commodity
trade. To accomplish this, the BCP used the wartime organizations that
had overseen distribution of major crops.
Industry continued to decentralize from 1944 until 1947. In those
years, the majority of labor leaving the military and the farms entered
small factories and unmechanized artisan shops. These small enterprises
were quite the opposite of the modern, largescale industry that the BCP
was committed to creating. Small enterprises also competed with state
enterprises for scarce raw materials and skilled labor. Labor discipline
also was a major problem during this phase; unexcused absences, sporadic
strikes, and high labor turnover plagued the new state enterprises. In
September 1947, a decision to accelerate the nationalization of industry
was taken at a meeting of the Communist Information Bureau (Cominform).
As a result, in December 1947 trained groups of party members entered
all the approximately 6,100 remaining private enterprises, seized their
capital, and announced their immediate nationalization. This act
effectively erased Bulgaria's small class of private industrial
entrepreneurs. Also in 1947, government monopolies were established over
all items of retail trade. By the end of 1948, 85 percent of the means
of production were run by the state.
Although Bulgaria had few private banks when the BCP came to power,
by December 1947 those few were merged with the BNB. The BCP also
enacted a series of fiscal and monetary measures to gain control over
Bulgaria's financial resources by the end of 1947. Monetary reform froze
all bank accounts over 20,000 leva, and a tax was imposed on the
remaining accounts. These actions reduced the money supply by
two-thirds. The new policy also levied high taxes on private income and
high profits to absorb any potential new deposits.
This first phase of postwar economic development included a tentative
Two-Year Plan (1947-48) that foreshadowed later policies. Aimed
principally at speedy recovery from wartime stress, the program began
large-scale industrialization and electrification; it sought to raise
industrial production by 67 percent and agricultural production by 34
percent over prewar levels. In the event, the first plan
disproportionately allocated funds away from agriculture and encountered
severe organizational and technical problems, mistakes by inexperienced
management, and shortages of energy and production equipment--problems
that would continue in ensuing development phases.
The First Five-Year Plans
The next phase of Bulgarian postwar economic development included the
First Five-Year Plan. This plan made an important contribution to the
pattern of Bulgaria's socialist economic development by creating the
institutional apparatus for long-term industrial planning. Already in
1945, the wartime Directorate for Civilian Mobilization had been
replaced by a Supreme Economic Council that extended the previous
organization's authority over resource allocation. Now the state's
existing economic ministries were subdivided into one ministry for each
branch of production. By January 1948, a separate and politically
powerful State Production Committee (SPC) was established. By October
1948, representatives of the new SPC and the existing Main Directorate
for Statistics had set out the criteria for calculating plan
fulfillment.
The announced targets for the First Five-Year Plan (1949-53)
confirmed the economic priorities indicated by the previous TwoYear
Plan. Agriculture was to receive 17 percent of new investment and
industry 47 percent. Gross industrial output was to grow by 119 percent,
primarily because of a 220 percent increase in heavy industry. Light
industry and agriculture were to raise output by 75 and 59 percent,
respectively. The rapid collectivization and mechanization of
agriculture was expected to achieve the last target while freeing labor
for industry, construction, and transportation. Because about 25 percent
of the country's national income was invested in the economic
infrastructure, the standard of living remained low.
In 1952 the plan was declared fulfilled a year ahead of schedule, but
statistics on the period were too incomplete and contradictory to
evaluate its actual results. Substantial bottlenecks existed in material
inputs and outputs. Agriculture received less investment than planned
(only 13 percent), and showed no growth through the period. The effect
of low agricultural output rippled through other sectors of the economy,
hindering production in related industries. Substantial material and
technical aid came from the Soviet Union, but with a steep price:
Bulgaria was expected to sell products to the Soviet market at
below-market prices, and the arrogance of Soviet economic advisers
caused serious resentment.
Continuing problems with excessive labor turnover forced the regime
to cut back the targets for heavy industry in the Second Five-Year Plan
(1953-57), and average annual industrial growth fell from 20.7 to 12.7
percent during that period. This was the first of several dramatic
swings that characterized Bulgarian economic development throughout the
postwar period. The average annual growth rate of agriculture increased
from negative 0.9 percent to 4.9 percent in the Second Five-Year Plan,
but the same indicator for the overall NMP dropped from 8.4 to 7.8
percent. The industrial share of the NMP exceeded that of agriculture
for the first time in this period.
Two important economic events occurred at the Seventh Party Congress
of the BCP, which met in mid-1958. The party declared that Bulgaria was
the first country besides the Soviet Union to achieve full
collectivization of agriculture (estimates put the figure at 92 percent
at this time), and it announced the goals for the Third Five-Year Plan.
That plan, which began in 1958, set relatively moderate initial quotas
that included substantially more production of consumer goods. In 1959,
however, a BCP decision to make a "Great Leap Forward"
(borrowed by the press from Mao Zedong's concurrent program for the
Chinese economy) drastically raised quotas: by 1965 industrial output
was to be three to four times the 1957 level, and by 1961 agriculture
was to produce three times as much as it had in 1957. To achieve the
latter goal, agriculture was again reorganized. Amalgamation of
collective farms cut their number by 70 percent, after which average
farm acreage was second only to the Soviet Union among countries in
Eastern Europe. The grandiose Zhivkov Theses, as the quota program came
to be known, were tempered noticeably by 1961, when the economy's
inability to achieve such growth was obvious to all.
Meanwhile, throughout the late 1950s urban unemployment had been a
major problem. The new collectivization drive brought another wave of
peasant migration to urban centers. Compounding this problem was a
cutback in Soviet imports of industrial inputs, which created some
excess capacity in heavy industry. Thus, the intensified
industrialization of the Third Five-Year Plan also aimed at absorbing
surplus labor.
Trade relations with the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe also played
a large role in the investment priorities of the Third FiveYear Plan.
Food processing and agriculture were earmarked for greatest growth,
because these sectors, together with chemical fertilizers and small
electric equipment, were now areas of Bulgarian responsibility in the
plans of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (Comecon) for
greater East European trade. After a reduction in 1955, Bulgaria faced
greatly increased export obligations to the USSR, Czechoslovakia, and
the German Democratic Republic (East Germany) in the late 1950s. The
latter two could provide badly needed industrial machinery in return,
and the USSR provided vital raw materials and energy.
The party leadership initially resolved to fulfill the third plan,
like the first, within three or four years; although none of its goals
were reached, the party declared fulfillment in 1960, and Zhivkov
survived the popular disillusionment and economic upheaval caused by his
totally unrealistic theses. At that point, the twelve years of the
second phase of Bulgarian postwar economic development had wrought major
structural changes in the Bulgarian economy. Industry's share of the NMP
increased from 23 percent to 48 percent as agriculture's share fell from
59 percent to 27 percent. By 1960 the value produced by heavy industry
matched that of light industry, although food processing for export also
grew rapidly. Throughout the second phase, budget expenditures consisted
primarily of reinvestment in sectors given initial priority. Meanwhile,
the completion of collectivization had shifted 678,000 peasants, about
20 percent of the active labor force, into industrial jobs. The average
annual increase in industrial employment peaked at 11.5 percent between
1955 and 1960.
The Era of Experimentation and Reform
The first full five-year plans proved the Bulgarian system's capacity
for extensive growth in selected branches of industry, based on massive
infusions of labor and capital. In the first postwar decades, that
system was much more successful in reaching goals than were the command
economies in the other East European countries, largely because Bulgaria
had started with a much more primitive industrial infrastructure. By the
early 1960s, however, changes to the system were obviously needed to
achieve sustained growth in all branches of production, including
agriculture. Specific incentives to reform were shortages of labor and
energy and the growing importance of foreign trade in the
"thaw" years of the mid-1960s. Consequently, in 1962 the
Fourth Five-Year Plan began an era of economic reform that brought a
series of new approaches to the old goal of intensive growth.
Industrial Decentralization
In industry the "New System of Management" was introduced
in 1964 and lasted until 1968. This approach intended to streamline
economic units and make enterprise managers more responsible for
performance. In June 1964, about fifty industrial enterprises, mostly
producers of textiles and other consumer goods, were placed under the
new system. Wages, bonuses, and investment funds were tied to enterprise
profits, up to 70 percent of which could be retained. Outside investment
funds were to come primarily from bank credit rather than the state
budget. In 1965 state subsidies still accounted for 63 percent of
enterprise investment funds, however, while 30 percent came from
retained enterprise earnings and only 7 percent from bank credits. By
1970 budget subsidies accounted for only 27 percent of investment funds,
while bank credits jumped to 39 percent, and retained enterprise
earnings reached 34 percent. The number of compulsory targets for the
Fourth Five-Year Plan was cut to four: physical output, investment
funds, input utilization, and foreign trade targets. The pilot
enterprises did very well, earning profits that were double the norm. By
1967 two-thirds of industrial production came from firms under the new
system, which by that time had embraced areas outside consumer
production.
Another distinctive feature of the Bulgarian economy during the 1960s
was the high level of net capital investment (total investment minus
depreciation). The average of 12 percent from 1960 to 1970 was the
highest in all of Eastern Europe. As in the past, investment in heavy
industry received the lion's share--over 80 percent of total industrial
investment. Capital accumulation (net investment plus net inventories)
averaged 29 percent from 1960 to 1970, also a very high level.
Industrial Recentralization
Before the end of the 1960s, however, Bulgarian economic planning
moved back toward the conventional CPE approach. Many Western analysts
attributed the Bulgarian retreat from the reforms of the 1960s to
tension caused by the Soviet invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968.
International events may well have played a role, but the timing of the
retreat and the invasion suggest another component: dissatisfaction
among the BCP elite with the results and ideological implications of the
reform. For example, in July 1968, one month before the invasion of
Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria's unorthodox, three-tiered pricing system was
eliminated. The party leadership had never accepted the concept of free
and flexible pricing for some products, which was an important Bulgarian
departure from centralized planning in the 1960s. Resistance to reform
was further encouraged by a series of cases in which major enterprise
directors used newly decentralized financial resources to line their own
pockets.
Despite the general retreat from reform, two important measures
remained intact, one each in agriculture and industry. The first
involved new operating procedures introduced on the larger collective
farms in the early 1960s. To better exploit the new equipment introduced
during the consolidation of the late 1950s, farms were assigned more
agronomists and labor was specialized by establishing fixed brigades.
Production target negotiations between the Ministry of State Planning
and the agricultural collectives also were simplified.
The industrial reform that survived retrenchment in 1968 gave
associations, not ministries, responsibility to supervise the new system
of supply contracts between enterprises. This system continued to grow,
with prices determined on the basis of enterprise bargaining rather than
ministerial fiat. Interenterprise allocations clearly functioned more
efficiently with this arrangement.
Larger Economic Units
Just as most reforms were being rescinded, the BCP began the last
phase of postwar agricultural restructuring. Prompted by the labor
shortage, the new streamlining of collective farms that began in 1969
introduced the so-called agricultural-industrial complex
(agrompromishlen kompleks--APK). The new structure was to industrialize
agricultural production, boost the value-added component in Bulgarian
exports by processing more agricultural goods, and raise the food supply
to cities without diverting labor back from industry. In the late 1960s,
relatively poor agricultural performance under the existing structure
had prevented those goals from being reached.
The idea of combining existing enterprises into a smaller, presumably
more manageable number of units spread quickly from agriculture to
industry. By the end of the 1970s, the number of associations into which
industrial enterprises were grouped was reduced by half. The sixty-four
new, larger associations were granted the authority to make decisions
for their enterprises about new investments, bank credits, and budget
subsidies. Within an association, the larger enterprises (called
subsidiaries) still could sign their own supply contracts and maintain
their own bank accounts, but they ceased to be legal entities. Smaller
enterprises (called subdivisions) became fully dependent on their
association.
The main advantage of this streamlined organization was seen as
economy of scale through increased specialization and a simplified flow
of information. Associations also were assumed to be better able to make
investment decisions and oversee material and labor distribution than
either a small number of ministries or a large number of enterprises.
The new structure would link specific industrial enterprises with
scientific institutes in the same way as the agricultural complexes had
linked them.
These reforms proved disappointing. Reformed planning techniques
continued to leave unused industrial capacity, and quality control
failed to improve. Both Western and domestic customers remained
dissatisfied with the quality of many Bulgarian manufactures. New
planning indicators that set norms for cost reduction actually reduced
quality in a number of cases. Individual members of institutes could not
convey their ideas to associations or ministries, where decisions to
import or to invest in new technology were made. Thus the new framework
only accentuated the dangers of socialist monopoly. Party meetings and
the press criticized monopolistic abuses resulting from irrational
decisions at the top and poor implementation of rational policies at the
enterprise level. By the end of the 1970s, a new set of reforms was
prescribed.
The New Economic Model
Initiated in 1981, the next program of reforms was designated the New
Economic Madel (NEM). This program involved both agricultural complexes
and industrial enterprises. Goals of the NEM included updating the
technical infrastructure of Bulgarian industry and improving the quality
of Bulgarian exports to raise hard-currency income. Centralized planning
now was relegated to setting gross profits and overseeing the national
scientific program. In 1978-79 and 1982-83, the NEM's principal
instruments were financial incentives and accounting regulations aimed
at all levels of management, but especially at the smallest unit of
labor, the brigade. Brigades, each containing thirty to fifty workers,
now would set labor and material input levels and dispose of finished
products. In an effort to remedy the chronic distribution problems of
the central economy, higher economic institutions became financially
accountable for damage inflicted by their decisions on subordinate
levels.
Several important initiatives were launched in 1978. The longstanding
limits on enterprise investment were lifted. In their place, a new
investment plan was based on the enterprises' contractual obligations
and credits with the BNB. The bank monitored the cash balance of
enterprise contracts with customers and suppliers, granting credits only
when required. Three separate reinvestment funds received first claim on
the net income of the enterprise. Although budgetary subsidies were not
eliminated, the NEM directives assigned responsibility for financial
losses to all levels of enterprises. Self-financing became the watchword
for all economic organizations.
Another major change eliminated the automatic first claim of salaries
and wages on gross enterprise income. This meant that wages could rise
only after an increase in labor productivity, and then only by 50
percent of that increase. Moreover, management salaries could be cut by
as much as 20 percent if the complex or enterprise failed to meet its
norms for production and productivity. The formula for sanctions against
management salaries changed several times. Finally, binding performance
criteria were limited to five financial indicators for agricultural
complexes and industrial associations, and to four for individual
enterprises. Profit criteria were set only for the complexes or
associations. Complexes or associations were given explicit freedom to
sign their own contracts with suppliers and customers at home and
abroad.
The BNB was granted some flexibility in restricting its terms of
lending and in charging interest rates above the nominal 2 percent.
These measures were designed to bestow greater rewards for efficiency
and to reduce the number of unfinished or unprofitable new projects. The
latter accounted for 57 percent of all Bulgarian investment as late as
1976. A provision for joint ventures with foreign firms met little
enthusiasm from abroad.
The Last Round of Zhivkov Reforms
By 1982 economists and the party leadership admitted that the NEM had
not led to the anticipated upturn in overall productivity and
efficiency. Even upwardly skewed official statistics indicated that
aggregate economic growth had dropped to its lowest postwar level. Under
the NEM, enterprises could still get approval from state pricing
authorities for price increases with marginal or nonexistent quality
improvement--an important factor in evaluating official figures.
The differences between the Western concept of gross national product
(GNP) and NMP make performance comparisons problematic. However, a
Western economist who calculated growth rates for the Bulgarian economy
according to the conventional GNP standard used in market economies
determined the official Bulgarian growth rates between 1961 and 1980.
The calculated rate for 1981-2 was 2.9 percent.
The Bulgarian response to declining growth rates under NEM was to
initiate a second set of NEM reforms. Measures in 1982 and 1983
concentrated almost exclusively on financial incentives and prices. Net
income was identified as the major basis for judging plan fulfillment.
The only other targets were tax payments, domestic and imported input
limits, and minimum export levels. The emphasis on self-supporting net
income was extended downward to the brigade and upward to the
associations. Guarantees of a minimum wage were removed for workers and
all levels of management. Ministers themselves now were subject to
salary reductions if their industrial association failed to meet the
streamlined list of targets. Ministry access to budgetary subsidies for
new investment was drastically cut and limited to a fixed term. Most
investment capital outside net income had to be procured from the BNB.
The bank's increasingly independent guidelines included the
authorization to hold regional competitions for investment funds.
Interest rates remained low however, ranging between 2.5 and 8 percent.
All these reforms did little to invigorate economic growth. In the
Eighth Five-Year Plan (1981-5), the NMP growth rate dropped to 3.7
percent, its lowest postwar level. Officially, industry grew at a rate
of 7 percent and construction at 5.4 percent, but agriculture declined
by 3.9 percent per year.
In 1985 Mikhail S. Gorbachev visited Bulgaria and reportedly
pressured Zhivkov to make the country more competitive economically.
This led to a Bulgarian version of the Soviet perestroika
program. New Regulations on Economic Activity took effect in January
1987. These directives, intended to stimulate "socialist
competition," allowed enterprises to retain a much greater share of
their profits and also required them to compete for investment capital
from newly formed commercial banks. In June 1987, in response to
widespread dissatisfaction and confusion over the measures, a decree on
collective and individual labor activities made it possible for state
economic organizations to lease small trading and catering facilities to
private individuals by offering contracts at public auctions. The
auctions were an abject failure, however, because of high taxes, high
rents, restricted access to capital, uncertain supplies, the short
duration of the contracts, and legal insecurity. The idea was quietly
abandoned.
Finally, in January 1989, the party issued Decree Number 56. This
decree established "firms" as the primary unit of economic
management. Theoretically, four types of firm could be created:
joint-stock firms, firms with limited responsibility, firms with
unlimited responsibility, and citizens' firms. The differences among the
first three types of firms were small. But citizens' firms offered the
potential of individual, collective, and associative ownership
arrangements. In a fundamental departure from the socialist prohibition
of private citizens hiring labor, as many as ten people could now be
hired permanently, and an unlimited number could be hired on temporary
contracts. A wave of reorganizations produced new, larger firms,
depriving numerous enterprises of their self-management status.
Nonetheless, hundreds of private and cooperative firms were authorized
by Decree Number 56.
Other elements of the decree allowed firms to issue shares and bonds
and pay dividends, with a number of restrictions. Other clauses sought
to encourage foreign investment in the country. State-owned enterprises
that were transformed into joint-stock firms now could have foreign
shareholders. Although tax incentives and legal guarantees were provided
for joint ventures, little foreign investment was stimulated. In 1989
and 1990, only 117 joint ventures were consummated, totaling US$10
million in Western capital. In all probability, low labor costs were not
enough to attract foreign investment given remaining organizational
disadvantages, poor infrastructure, low political credibility, the
nonconvertability of the lev, and close economic ties to the Soviet
Union.
This last round of reforms by the Zhivkov regime confused rather than
improved economic performance. Statistics on growth for 1986-88
indicated a 5.5 percent annual rate, up from the 3.7 percent rate
achieved during the previous five-year plan. However, these statistics
were internally inconsistent and widely disputed in the press. Expert
observers speculated that they were the minimum growth the regime could
tolerate given the 6 percent target rate in the five-year plan.
Ultimately, the reforms failed to radically change the economic
conditions in the country. Public discontent increased and finally,
emboldened by revolutions throughout Eastern Europe, a popular revolt
ousted Todor Zhivkov in November 1989. By early 1990, the first attempts
were being made to establish a market-based economy.
Bulgaria - The Economy - ECONOMIC SECTORS
In 1988 Bulgaria produced approximately 43 billion kilowatt hours of
electricity (in contrast to 384 billion for France and 83.5 billion for
Yugoslavia). At that point, planners expected power consumption to
increase by about 3.5 percent per year through the year 2000. The 1988
Program for Energy Development through 1995 and in Perspective until
2005 set general long-term goals for the Bulgarian power industry,
including more effective integration of machine building and
construction industries into power projects, improved balance between
supply and demand of energy, and more effective use of low-quality coal
and local hydroelectric plants. In 1988 Bulgaria and the Soviet Union
signed a bilateral agreement for scientific and technical cooperation in
thermoelectric, hydroelectric, and nuclear power generation. That year
59 percent of Bulgaria's electricity came from thermoelectric plants
(primarily coal-powered); 35 percent came from nuclear reactors, the
remainder from hydroelectric stations. Total generating capacity in 1988
was 11,300 megawatts (in contrast to 103,400 for France, 20,000 for
Yugoslavia).
Conventional Power Generation
Besides the pollution caused by burning domestic coal, about 1,500
megawatts of Bulgaria's thermoelectric generation capacity was idle in
the late 1980s because of inefficient fuel delivery or equipment
breakdown. About half the capacity of local heat and power plants,
relied upon to supplement major electrical plants and provide heat for
industries and homes, was unavailable for the same reasons.
In the early 1990s, Bulgarian energy planners faced serious dilemmas.
At the Maritsa-iztok-1, Maritsa-iztok-2 and Dimo Dichev thermoelectric
plants, located in the Maritsa-iztok coal fields, long-term plans called
for gradual replacement of old generating equipment in existing
stations. But most such projects were far behind schedule in 1990. The
1990 decision not to complete the Belene Nuclear Power Plant meant
increased reliance on Maritsaiztok coal for heat and power generation.
In 1990 that spurce provided 70 percent of the country's coal, and its
three power stations contributed about 25 percent of total power
generation.
The Maritsa-iztok Industrial-Power Complex (with its machine building
and repair enterprises one of the largest industrial centers in
Bulgaria, employing 22,000 people in 1991) had been in operation since
1951; by 1991 the quality of its coal and the reliability of its
infrastructure were steadily declining. But at that crisis point in the
national economy, funds were unavailable for capital investment,
especially to buy expensive foreign technology. At the same time, industry authorities
acknowledged burning high-sulfur coal and strip mining at Maritsa-iztok
as a severe environmental problem whose amelioration would cost at least
a billion leva, mostly hard currency.
Hydroelectric power generation was concentrated in southwestern
Bulgaria, but few Bulgarian rivers offered large-scale hydroelectric
potential. The major hydroelectric project in the Ninth Five-Year Plan
(1986-90) was completion of the Chaira station, which would add 864
megawatts of generating capacity. Development of local hydroelectric
stations on small streams was a planning priority for the 1990s.
Nuclear Power
Nuclear power provided Bulgaria a way of easing its dependence on
imported fuels, although the Soviet Union and Czechoslovakia provided
the expertise and equipment on which Bulgaria built its nuclear power
industry. Lacking hard currency to buy enough oil, and reaching the
toleration limit for pollution by coal-burning plants, Bulgaria
increasingly made nuclear power the center of its energy policy in the
1980s. In 1974 the first nuclear power plant was opened at Kozloduy
north of Sofia on the Danube River. After completing the original
four-reactor complex in 1982, Kozloduy added a fifth unit in late 1987.
This was the first 1,000-megawatt reactor in Eastern Europe outside the
Soviet Union. A sixth unit was installed in 1989. At that point,
Bulgaria ranked third in the world in per capita nuclear power
generation, and the extent of its reliance on a sole nuclear power plant
was unsurpassed in the world.
The Bulgarian nuclear power industry was beset with major problems
from the beginning. The Kozloduy station had a history of technical
difficulties and accidents, many of which were related to the low
quality or poor design of Soviet and Czechoslovak equipment. The fifth
reactor, a constant source of trouble, was out of commission for several
months in 1991 because of extensive turbine damage. This setback put the
entire country on a brownout schedule that shut off electricity two out
of every four hours.
The Chernobyl' disaster in 1986 made nuclear safety a sensitive
political issue in Bulgaria, and by the late 1980s public opinion, now a
much more significant factor for policy makers, had turned strongly
against the nuclear industry. A second nuclear power complex was started
at Belene, to add six 1,000-megawatt reactors by the end of the Tenth
Five-Year Plan. But construction was halted in 1989 by public opposition
and disclosure that both Kozloduy and Belene were located in
earthquake-prone regions. Long-term plans for nuclear heat generation
also were shelved at that time. In 1991 the government's Commission on
Nuclear Power Supply reported that the supply system was poorly
organized and managed, and that managers relied on expensive foreign
technical help instead of available domestic engineers. The commission
also reported that, once Soviet specialists left, a shortage of
qualified personnel delayed activation of the sixth reactor at Kozloduy
(considered a top priority once Belene was rejected), and that most
monitoring instruments in the first four Kozloduy reactors were out of
operation.
In mid-1991 the International Atomic Energy Agency (IAEA) declared
the Kozloduy reactors unsafe. Two reactors were shut down. Meanwhile,
the planned activation of the two newest reactors at Kozloduy raised the
problem of nuclear waste disposal in 1991, because the Soviet Union
began charging hard currency to reprocess waste from East European
reactors, formerly one of its functions under Comecon. In 1991 Bulgaria
requested European Economic Community (EEC) aid to build its first
permanent domestic repository for nuclear waste.
The Bulgarian power transmission network was supplemented in 1988
when a high-capacity transmission line from the South Ukraine Nuclear
Power Station in the Soviet Union reached the northeastern port city of
Varna. But like Soviet fuels, imported Soviet electricity required hard
currency in 1991, mitigating the advantages of the old CEMA agreement.
Bulgaria - Industry
From 1956 through 1988, industrial production rose an average of 8.9
percent per year according to official figures, but the actual rates
declined steadily during the thirty-three year period. The annual
average rate of industrial growth for the periods 1956- 60, 1961-70,
1971-80, and 1981-8 was 15.5, 11.6, 7.5, and 4.4 percent, respectively.
By the late 1980s, Bulgarian industry had completely exhausted the
advantages it had used in earlier decades to post impressive growth
statistics.
Industrial Policy
The cost of Bulgaria's industrial growth was substantial. Besides
environmental problems, the commitment to heavy industry came at the
expense of light industry--especially food processing and textiles--and
agriculture. These were sectors in which prewar Bulgaria had relatively
high production potential. But de-emphasis held the official annual NMP
growth figures for light industry and agriculture to 7.5 and 2.8
percent, respectively, between 1956 and 1988.
In the postwar command economy, the chief beneficiaries of this
emphasis were the chemical, electronics, and machinery industries. Their
respective share of total industrial production rose from 1.9, 0, and
2.4 percent in 1939 to 8.8, 14.4, and 15 percent in 1988. Similar
statistics indicate big drops in production shares for the food
processing and textiles industries--from 51.2 to 23.3 percent, and from
19.8 to 5.1 percent, respectively, in the same period.
Besides the unchanging commitment to heavy industry, two other major
trends appeared in postwar industrial policy. The first was steady and
substantial support for a basic ferrous metals industry, regardless of
cost, in order to reduce dependence on imports. The second was an effort
to produce machinery competitive in international markets, with special
emphasis on electrical equipment.
A result of the first policy was the Kremikovtsi Metallurgical
Complex. In 1954 Soviet-supported geological surveys indicated major new
deposits of higher quality iron ore that would support a second complex
to supplement the existing V.I. Lenin Ferrous Metals Combine at Pernik.
Although the deposits were actually found to be inadequate, the
extremely expensive Kremikovtsi plant finally opened in 1963 and used
Soviet iron ore to produce over half of the national production of steel
and iron through 1978.
The Kremikovtsi complex brought numerous problems. By the mid1970s ,
over 75 percent of its ore and coking coal was imported. Costs were
inflated by premium wages paid to maintain the labor force and by delays
in construction and delivery. Production at Kremikovtsi consistently
failed to meet planned targets, and less than three-quarters of plant
capacity was used. The enterprise never showed a profit; in 1989 it lost
99.5 million leva despite receiving 600 million leva in state subsidies.
Using 15 percent of the country's total energy output, Kremikovtsi
generated only 1 percent of national income in the late 1980s.
The strategy of heavy equipment production for export fared better
than did metallurgy in the 1970s and 1980s. In fact, the most
competitive Bulgarian industries were those most committed to export
markets. The machine building and electronics industries averaged 16
percent growth between 1960 and 1980 while their combined share of
export value jumped from 13 to 55 percent from 1960 to 1982. The primary
exports in these sectors were forklift trucks and electrical hoisting
gear produced by the Balkancar enterprise. Computer equipment and
chemicals also showed improved export performance.
Bulgaria's postwar industrialization was clearly positive in some
sectors. Two notable examples were the construction of electric power
plants in the 1950s, which made possible the nationwide spread of
industry, and the development of an electrical equipment industry that
produced exportable products. Nonetheless, as the 1980s drew to a close,
it became increasingly clear that even the most competitive sectors had
serious problems that the BCP's halfway reforms could not solve. After
the initial postwar climb, four decades of socialist central planning
had left the industrial sector in a very poor state.
Industrial Centers
Bulgarian heavy industries, mostly machine building, chemicals, and
electronics, were concentrated in relatively few production centers.
Important machine tool plants were the Bolshevik Tool Plant at Gabrovo,
the Nikola Vaptsarov Combine at Pleven, and the Radomir Heavy Equipment
Plant in southwest Bulgaria. The Electronic Materials Processing and
Equipment Scientific-Production Combine was a combined scientific and
industrial center at Sofia. Electronic instrument production centers
were located at the Plovdiv Power Electronics Plant, the Shabla
Electromechanical Plant on the northeast coast, the Stara Zagora
Industrial Robot Plant, the Pravets Instrument Plant in the southwest,
and the Petkov Instrument Plant at Turgovishte. Major chemical and
petrochemical producers were the Industrial Petrochemical Plant at
Pleven (specializing in vehicle lubricants and oils), the Burgas
Petrochemical Combine (plastics), the Vratsa Industrial Chemical Combine
(chemical fertilizers), and four chemical plants at Dimitrovgrad.
Bulgaria also built large numbers of ships, many for Soviet customers,
at its Ruse and Varna shipyards on the Black Sea. The Shumen Vehicle
Plant assembled LIAZ-Madara heavy trucks in a three-way arrangement with
the Liberac Auto Plant of Czechoslovakia and the Soviet Union.
Obstacles to Industrial Growth
In 1989 the domestic market still featured little or no competition.
Over 80 percent of exports went to Comecon countries, and 75 percent of
that total went to the Soviet Union. This situation insulated the
computers, industrial robots, microprocessors, and other high-technology
exports of Bulgarian industry from the market competition that would
require backing by substantial investment in research and development.
Bulgaria thus developed a practice of expending a small proportion of
its national income on applied science, even compared with other East
European states.
Falling productivity was a major problem in a number of key
industries. Many of these industries were inherently uncompetitive, and
attempts to raise productivity through large-scale production
concentrated industrial and research facilities into enormous
enterprises that further reduced industrial flexibility. Unprofitability
made Bulgarian industry dependent on a system of widespread state
subsidies. It was reported at the BCP Central Committee plenum in
December 1989 that a quarter of all state companies had received state
support during the year, totaling 7 billion leva--almost a quarter of
the national income. Machine building, one of Bulgaria's key export
industries, became a problem area for the economy in the 1980s. Because
it was the chief consumer of the overpriced, low-quality output of the
metallurgical industry, the machine industry eventually became
unprofitable as well. In 1990 Balkancar, the country's biggest company,
one of its most successful exporters, and another major customer of the
metallurgy enterprises, lost money for the first time.
A critical economic policy decision in the late 1980s was Zhivkov's
special emphasis on several energy-intensive industries, despite the
inadequacy of domestic energy supply. In the early 1990s, the new regime
faced a choice of dismantling many of those enterprises, finding less
expensive energy sources to keep them running, or acquiring enough hard
currency to upgrade their technological level and make them less
energy-intensive. To further complicate industrial policy, beginning in
1991 the Soviet Union began charging market prices in hard currency for
its oil and gas.
Finally, emergence of a significant, fast-growing environmental
movement cast the tradeoff of environmental quality for economic growth
in starkly negative terms. Barring substantial technical aid (most
likely from the West) to reduce industrial waste, public demand for
environmentally sound economic policy stood as a formidable obstacle to
industrial expansion.
Bulgaria - Agriculture
Prior to World War II, agriculture was the leading sector in the
Bulgarian economy. In 1939 agriculture contributed 65 percent of NMP,
and four out of every five Bulgarians were employed in agriculture. The
importance and organization of Bulgarian agriculture changed drastically
after the war, however. By 1958 the BCP had collectivized a high
percentage of Bulgarian farms; in the next three decades the state used
various forms of organization to improve productivity, but none
succeeded. Meanwhile, private plots remained productive and often
alleviated agricultural shortages during the Zhivkov era.
Early Collectivization Campaigns
When the BCP came to power, Bulgarian agriculture consisted primarily
of 1.1 million peasant smallholdings. The party saw consolidation of
these holdings as its most immediate agricultural objective. It
dismantled the agricultural bank that had been a primary source of
investment for the agriculture and food processing sectors before World
War II.
The first attempts at voluntary collectivization yielded modest
results, partly because open coercion was impossible until a peace
treaty was signed with the Allies. The labor-cooperative farm
(trudovo-kooperativno zemedelsko stopanstvo--TKZS) received official
approval in 1945. It closely resembled Soviet cooperatives in
organization, although members were guaranteed a share of profits and
membership was (nominally) completely voluntary. By 1947 only 3.8
percent of arable land had been collectivized. After the communists won
the first postwar election and the peace was concluded in 1947, pressure
on private landholders increased. Although most small farmers had joined
collectives, by 1949 only 12 percent of arable land was under state
control--mainly because the collectivization program alienated many
peasants. But between 1950 and 1953, the Stalinist regime of Vulko
Chervenkov used threats, violence, and supply discrimination to produce
the fastest pace of collectivization in Eastern Europe. Sixty-one
percent of arable land had been collectivized by 1952. The process was
declared complete in 1958 when 92 percent of arable land belonged to the
collective farms. This ended the first phase of Bulgarian postwar
agricultural restructuring.
Farm Consolidation in the 1960s
At this stage, Bulgarian collectives were much smaller than the
Soviet organizations on which they were modeled. To fulfill the
ambitious goals contained in the Zhivkov Theses (January 1959) for the
Third Five-Year Plan (1958-60), further consolidation was deemed
necessary. This process reduced the number of collectives from 3,450 to
932, and the average size of a collective grew from 1,000 to 4,500
hectares.
In the late 1960s, an agricultural labor shortage combined with
fascination for China's agrarian amalgamation to prompt further
consolidation of collective farms into APKs. By the end of 1971, all of
Bulgaria's 744 collectives and 56 state farms had been merged into 161
complexes, most of which were designated APK's. These units averaged
24,000 hectares and 6,500 members. The consolidation continued until
there were only 143 complexes in 1977. Several complexes were larger
than 100,000 hectares, and twenty-five were between 36,000 and 100,000
hectares. In the short term, they were to achieve horizontal integration
by specializing in three or fewer crops and one type of livestock. In
the longer term, they would be the basis for linking agriculture with
manufacturing and commerce. On the political level, this consolidation
was to be a symbolic merger of the agricultural and urban workers, who
had remained quite distinct parts of the Bulgarian population since the
nineteenth century in defiance of the theory of the unified socialist
society.
The new organizations never met the higher agricultural quotas of the
late 1970s, however. For some products, yield did not keep pace with
investment. Overall growth in agriculture continued to fall after the
creation of the APKs. And the goal of freeing farm workers to take
industrial jobs was not reached. On the contrary, the annual reduction
in agricultural employment dropped from 4 to 2 percent while farm labor
productivity declined. As a result, agriculture's share of gross
investment in fixed capital fell to 18 percent by 1976, a level last
seen in the mid-1950s. In 1978 this failure triggered a new policy
emphasizing smaller complexes. Reduced agricultural quotas in the Eighth
Five-Year Plan (1981-85) were an admission that too much had been
expected from the constant tinkering process.
Reform in the 1980s
By 1982 the total of old and new APKs reached 296, the average size
was halved to 16,000 hectares, and the management hierarchy was
simplified. Most importantly, the number of annual indicators of plan
fulfillment was reduced from fourteen to four. The new, simpler approach
also allowed greater freedom for APKs to negotiate prices on surplus
production and to purchase their own supplies.
In the last Zhivkov years, the communist regime attempted other
agricultural reforms, including autonomy for the collectives. At that
point, the only funds the state received from agriculture were 60
percent of foreign currency from exports. Even then, government delivery
prices remained so low that state foodstuff monopolies received only the
absolute minimum supply. In 1989 the exodus of 310,000 ethnic Turks,
many of whom had cultivated personal plots, also hurt agricultural
output.
Despite these handicaps, the United States Department of Agriculture
estimated that within Eastern Europe Bulgaria was second only to Hungary
in agricultural trade surpluses through 1987. After that time, however,
agricultural output dropped so far that the country could no longer feed
its own people. In 1990 the first rationing and shortages since World
War II were the most obvious indications of this situation. Because of
domestic shortages, export of several agricultural products was banned
in 1990.
Agricultural Products
Two long-term policies strongly determined priorities in Bulgarian
agricultural production after 1960. First, livestock was promoted at the
expense of crop cultivation, mainly to meet export demand. Between 1970
and 1988, the share of livestock in agricultural production rose from
35.3 to 55.6 percent. As a result, less land was available for crops in
that period. Pig and poultry production increased the most, but large
numbers of sheep also were raised. The second policy was a shift away
from industrial crops (primarily tobacco and cotton), toward production
of fruit (most notably apples), vegetables (most notably tomatoes), and
grapes. Bulgaria remained an important exporter of tobacco, however,
averaging 65 percent of East European exports of that crop in the 1980s.
Grain production concentrated on wheat, corn, and barley, crops which
are vulnerable to weather conditions. Poor harvests in 1985 and 1986 led
to grain imports of 1.8 and 1.5 million tons, respectively. Sugar beets,
potatoes, sunflower seeds, and soybeans also were important crops at the
end of the 1980s. In 1990 Bulgaria was the world's largest exporter of
attar of roses, used in making perfume.
The Role of Private Plots
After 1970 the only consistent contribution to agricultural
production growth was family farming on private plots leased from the
agricultural complexes. These plots could not be bought or sold or
worked by hired labor, but their yield belonged to the tenant. In 1971
special measures were instituted to increase the number and the
availability of personal plots. Beginning in 1974, peasant households
were permitted to lease additional plots and given free access to
fertilizer, fodder seed, and equipment belonging to their agricultural
complexes. To encourage this practice, the government extended loans and
waived income taxes. More importantly, delivery prices increased for
agricultural products. In the mid-1970s, a reduced work week for urban
workers and relaxed requirements for plot leasing encouraged weekend
cultivation of personal plots by the nonagricultural population. Plot
size limits were removed in 1977.
By 1982 personal plots accounted for 25 percent of Bulgaria's
agricultural output and farm worker income. In 1988 personal plots
accounted for large shares of basic agricultural goods: corn, 43.5
percent; tomatoes, 36.8 percent; potatoes, 61.5 percent; apples, 24.8
percent; grapes, 43.2 percent; meat, 40.8 percent; milk, 25.2 percent;
eggs, 49.4 percent; and honey, 86 percent. The sales from plots to town
markets meant that despite low overall agricultural growth rates in the
1980s, the urban food supply actually improved in many areas during the
early and mid-1980s.
Post-Zhivkov Agricultural Reform
In 1991 privatization of agriculture was a top priority of the
government of Prime Minister Dimitur Popov. That spring the National
Assembly passed a new Arable Land Law, revising the conditions for
ownership and use of agricultural land. The law allowed every Bulgarian
citizen to own as much as thirty hectares of land, or twenty in areas of
intensive cultivation. Use of this land was at the complete discretion
of the owner. Conditions were stated for voluntary formation of
cooperatives by private landowners and resale of their land. With some
limitations, landowners whose property had been incorporated into state
farms were to receive "comparable" plots elsewhere or other
appropriate compensation. The state or municipality retained title to
land not in private hands. Another provision described redistribution of
land seized by the state from cooperatives and individuals during
Zhivkov's several agricultural consolidations. A National Land Council
under the Council of Ministers was to oversee land distribution and
arbitrate disputes, aided by a system of municipal land commissions.
As elsewhere in the Bulgarian economy, agricultural reform
encountered stout resistance from entrenched local Zhivkovite officials.
Pre-collectivization land ownership records were destroyed, and farmers
were threatened or bribed to remain in collectives rather than seeking
private farms. Although the Arable Land Law was widely hailed as an
equitable and useful economic reform, its association with the Bulgarian
Socialist Party (BSP, formerly the BCP) majority brought criticism from
the opposition Union of Democratic Forces (UDF). Some farmers
circumvented the law simply by seizing land. The government, meanwhile,
announced that no state land would be redistributed before the 1991
harvest.
In early 1991, staples such as sugar and olive oil were unavailable
in many areas; livestock feed rations had been cut by more than half; a
grain shortfall of 1.7 million tons was expected; meat, withheld from
markets until new government prices were announced, was very scarce and
expensive in cities; and fertilizers for the year's crops were in very
short supply. Western firms expressed interest in joint agricultural
ventures in Bulgaria, but hesitated because of uncertainty about
political and legal conditions for such projects. A new round of
government pricefixing in February 1991 substantially raised food prices
but did restore supplies of some items.
Bulgaria - BANKING AND FINANCE
Under the Zhivkov regime, Bulgaria followed the customary communist
pattern of a single state-run bank performing all banking and investment
functions. Investment policy was the province of state planning
agencies, with substantial input from the BCP and the national bank.
Post-Zhivkov reform aimed at privatizing and compartmentalizing the
banking system, a goal that would likely require years of gradual
reform.
Currency and Exchange
The national currency of Bulgaria is the lev, which is divided into
100 stotinki (sing. stotinka). Throughout the communist era, the lev
could be used only in domestic transactions because it was not
convertible into foreign currency. Bulgarian nationals were prohibited
from owning foreign currency, and the law prohibited citizens and
foreigners from entering or leaving the country with leva. Like domestic
prices, the value of the lev was administratively determined. This led
to frequent overvaluing of the lev in terms of hard currencies and black
market rates well below official exchange rates. Besides official rates,
which were based on a gold parity developed after World War II, a
commercial rate was used for business transactions and statistical
purposes, and a tourist rate determined the amount received by
foreigners in Bulgaria for their domestic currencies. None of these
arbitrary rates reflected the relationship of domestic and foreign
prices. Trade with Western countries was conducted in hard currency,
while the transferable ruble, an accounting device with no convertible
value, was primarily used to clear commercial accounts within Comecon.
In 1990 the lev was devalued several times, finally settling at rates of
about 0.76 stotinki to the United States dollar (official), 3 leva to
the dollar (commercial), and 7 leva to the dollar (tourist). The black
market rate fluctuated considerably, but ended 1990 at approximately 11
leva to the dollar. In mid-1991 the Bulgarian National Bank (BNB) issued
conversion tables for the lev into major world currencies. The official
value at that time was 18 leva to the United States dollar.
Banking System
As the chief financial instrument of economic policy making, the BNB
assumed virtually all of the financial functions in the country under
the centrally planned economy. Only the granting of foreign trade and
consumer credits were separate functions, performed respectively by the
Bulgarian Foreign Trade Bank and the State Savings Bank--both of which
were subordinate to the BNB. The BNB worked with the Ministry of Finance
to finance capital investments in the economy. The BNB also monitored
the economic organizations that received investment funds to ensure
their use for accomplishing plan targets. As enterprises became more
selffinancing in the 1970s, a greater share of their investment capital
was composed of bank credits granted by the BNB. Between 1965 and 1975,
the BNB share of investment funds jumped from 7 percent to 54 percent;
the trend then moderated as enterprises began to rely more on retained
earnings to finance investments.
Like industry and agriculture, banking under the BCP experimented
occasionally with decentralization but remained quite centralized until
shortly before the overthrow of Zhivkov. A 1987 reform nominally split
Bulgarian banking into a two-tiered system. The function of the BNB was
restricted to money supply, although it also retained significant
supervisory power. The reform also created several specialized banks
including the Agricultural and Cooperative Bank, the Biochemical Bank,
the Construction Bank, the Electronics Bank, the Transportation Bank,
and the Transport, Agricultural, and Building Equipment Bank--each
responsible for an industrial sector.
Post-Zhivkov banking reform began hesitantly but grew more
comprehensive in 1991. In a controversial policy decision, the
government first increased interest rates from 4.5 to 8 percent in 1990,
then let them float freely beginning in 1991. Although the first private
commercial bank was established in May 1990, a new National Bank Bill
was not passed until June 1991. That law provided for a two-tier bank
system independent of direct government control but accountable to the
National Assembly. The first tier of the new system was to be the
Central Bank, the second a separate system of commercial banks and
lending institutions serving private citizens and enterprises.
Three-month bank credits would be available to cabinet ministries. The
BNB was to issue monthly balance statements and report semiannually to
the National Assembly.
Investment Policy
In choosing among alternative investment projects, Bulgarian planners
in the Zhivkov era faced greater difficulties than investment decision
makers in Western economies. True relative costs of labor and materials
were masked by state assignment of prices, meaning that funding
allocations among projects often were arbitrary. In most cases,
investments were not based on efficiency criteria, but rather on plan
goals. Artificially low interest rates also discouraged enterprises from
efficient investment fund allocation.
The state budget also guided party economic policy under the old
regime. Until the reforms of the 1970s, the budget was the primary
source of funds for enterprise investment. Budget revenues were
originally derived mainly from the turnover tax, a retail sales tax that
was also used to regulate demand for various products. Beginning in the
mid-1960s, budget revenues were derived progressively less from the
turnover tax and more from taxes on net enterprise income.
Prices
Investments in inefficient operations and subsidies on consumer items
often led to budget deficits. Often the state simply printed more money
to cover its obligations. Eventually this led to circulation of excess
currency compared with consumer goods and services available at
prevailing prices. Because prices were administratively set, shortages
and long lines occurred more often than inflation under the CPE. But
party-directed general price increases such as the average 15 percent
rise in 1979 usually were quite steep.
In the post-Zhivkov era, economic planners saw marketdetermined
prices for most goods and services as their long-term goal. In 1990 the
prices of 40 percent of goods and 60 percent of services were freed from
administrative control. In the second half of 1990, price liberalization
raised consumer prices an average of over 50 percent. In February 1991,
price controls were removed from all goods and services except fuels,
heat, and electricity. Immediately after this step, average food prices
were nearly six times their 1989 level; housing was up 3.7 times,
clothing three times more expensive. These levels, established by an
independent trade union study, were above the level triggering new talks
on compensation payments. (For the second consecutive year, a government
indexation program was established to reimburse a share (estimated at an
average 65 percent) of the higher cost of living caused by the new price
policy in the first half of 1991.) In a two-month period of early 1991,
consumption dropped by over 50 percent, but total consumer spending
still increased by 11.5 percent.
Bulgaria - FOREIGN TRADE
Membership in Comecon tied Bulgarian trade policy closely to the
Soviet economic sphere following World War II. By 1991, however, trade
policy was on the verge of significant diversification. With the trade
protection of Comecon no longer available, Bulgaria aggressively sought
new markets in the West while seeking to retain the most advantageous
commercial relations with its former Comecon partners.
Postwar Trade Policy
The adoption of the Soviet economic model had direct and indirect
impact on Bulgarian international trade after World War II. Among direct
results was the decision to reduce dependency on prewar Western trade
partners. This meant strong promotion of import substitution policies to
bolster domestic production of goods previously imported. In 1960
Bulgaria's total foreign trade (exports plus imports) was 31 percent of
NMP, quite low for a country with a small internal market and few
natural resources. By the 1980s, however, this figure had risen to over
90 percent. Before World War II, Germany was well-established as
Bulgaria's top trading partner. Postwar economic policy diverted trade
from Central Europe to Eastern Europe, and primarily to the Soviet
Union. The new domestic economic priorities dictated a revised foreign
trade structure. The policy of promoting heavy industry, for example,
required huge imports of machinery and raw materials. Beginning in the
mid-1950s, imports of machinery accounted for approximately half the
value of total imports, while fuels, metals, and minerals made up more
than a quarter of this value. Lower postwar investment in agriculture
eventually lessened the share of foodstuffs in total exports.
The state monopoly of foreign trade also changed the way decisions
were reached on international allocation of goods. Trade decisions were
reached administratively by planning authorities or negotiated with
other members of Comecon. Overall control of foreign trade was shared
among the Ministry of Foreign Trade, the Ministry of Finance, and the
Bulgarian Foreign Trade Bank.
Import and export operations were conducted by foreign trade
enterprises, most of which were affiliated with one or more associations
but retained a legal identity outside the associations. Although reform
measures by the Zhivkov regime gave associations some profit incentives
in international trade, the producing enterprises themselves were
completely isolated from the foreign customer. This meant that world
quality standards had no influence on Bulgarian producers.
Bulgaria in Comecon
The most important event in postwar Bulgarian international economic
relations occurred in 1949 when it became a founding member of Comecon.
Comecon was an attempt by the socialist economies to simplify the
planning process by synchronizing the five-year plans of member
countries and (more importantly), by achieving what Marxists called an
international division of labor. Countries within Comecon would
specialize in the products they made most efficiently and export the
surplus. Products that a country could not produce efficiently would be
available from one or more of its Comecon partners. This design was
intended to eliminate some redundancies inherent in the Soviet economic
model where each country produced goods of all categories. Although the
concept achieved isolated successes such as Bulgarian forklift trucks,
broad growth was blocked by the uniform socialist preoccupation with
heavy industry and the lack of a single convertible currency. The
currency issue in particular made intra-Comecon trade a cumbersome
process requiring negotiation of annual bilateral trade agreements for
all member nations.
In the 1980s, exports to the Soviet Union consisted primarily of
machinery, electronic components, and agricultural goods. These included
forklift trucks, electric engines, telephones, tobacco, fresh fruits and
vegetables, and wine. Imports from the Soviet Union were mainly energy
and raw materials, including oil, natural gas, iron ore, ferrous metals,
and cotton. In 1988 Bulgaria still relied almost entirely on Soviet oil
and natural gas. East Germany and Czechoslovakia were the next most
important Comecon trading partners, accounting for 5.2 and 4.6 percent
of exports, respectively, and 5.9 and 5.4 percent of imports,
respectively. Exchanges of goods between Bulgaria and these countries
emphasized both exports and imports of machinery and the export of
agricultural products.
In the initial years of Bulgaria's Comecon membership, the country
benefited from energy prices below world levels, especially for oil, in
two ways. The cost of developing otherwise inefficient industries was
lower, and reexport of crude and refined oil for hard currency bought
Western technology to upgrade the industrial infrastructure. Comecon
members paid for their imports through bilateral clearing agreements,
with no exchange of hard currency. In the initial stages of Comecon,
Bulgaria exported mainly food, the price of which was lower in Comecon
than on the world market. Later, however, Bulgaria paid for imported
Soviet raw materials largely with machinery that was priced higher than
on the world market.
Beginning in 1974, Soviet energy exports were based on a floating
five-year average of world prices that rarely matched market prices at a
given time. Even when Comecon prices were above the world level,
Bulgaria benefited from the lack of currency exchange in the Comecon
system. But dependence on Comecon trade, especially Soviet energy
exports, damaged Bulgaria tremendously when economic reform swept
through the Soviet sphere in 1989 and 1990. Of Bulgarian exports, 62.5
percent still went to the Soviet Union in 1988, and 53.5 percent of
imports came from that country. The new trade system established after
reforms required trade accounts to be cleared in hard currency at
current world prices as of January 1, 1991. (Bilateral protocols for
this procedure had not been signed by that time, however; Bulgaria still
owed Hungary 87 million transferable rubles in 1991.)
After the political reforms in Eastern Europe, the Soviet Union
announced cutbacks in energy exports to Eastern Europe. This caused
energy and raw materials shortages. In 1990 Bulgarian industry was
forced to curtail production sharply; meanwhile, consumers endured
severe shortages of gasoline as fuel prices doubled. A new set of export
and import regulations adopted in mid-1991 removed import taxes from 200
types of raw materials and consumer goods in critically short supply.
The same regulations set export price minimums to eliminate pricing
below world market levels; export of crude oil, metals, grains, and
textile raw materials was banned.
Trade with the West and the Third World
After 1960 Bulgaria's trade with the West increased, partly because
Bulgaria needed Western machinery to supplement the outdated, overpriced
manufacturing equipment supplied by Comecon. Between 1960 and 1975, the
Western share of Bulgarian imports went from 13.6 percent to 23.6
percent. In the same period, however, exports dropped from 12.4 to 9.3
percent, creating an external debt problem with the West. Increased
exports to Third World nations did little to help Bulgaria reduce this
trade deficit because most Third World trade was not in convertible
currencies.
Throughout the 1970s, Bulgarian trade balances alternated between
solvency and high deficits. Although the trade deficit was eliminated in
1975, many short-term debts to West European banks remained. By 1976
Bulgarian debt was 13 percent of estimated GNP-- the highest ratio in
Eastern Europe at the time. Bulgaria greatly diminished this debt by
reexporting Soviet oil to Western buyers in the late 1970s.
From that point, Bulgaria maintained trade surpluses in hard currency
until 1985, when emergency imports of grain and coal created a deficit
of US$200 million. A series of poor harvests, high machinery imports in
the investment push of the Ninth FiveYear Plan (1986-90), and sharply
dropping oil prices deprived Bulgaria of hard currency and created a
major new trade deficit. Libya and Iraq, the main Third World customers
with which a surplus had been accumulated, also reduced their purchase
of Bulgarian goods at this time.
The resulting trade deficits were financed by credits from Western
banks. After the overthrow of Zhivkov, the government announced that the
gross hard currency debt had reached US$10.6 billion by the end of 1989.
Net indebtedness was somewhat lower at US$7.7 billion, but much of the
hard currency export credits that Bulgaria granted were to Libya and
Iraq, who were likely to default on many of their deals. Bulgaria had
arranged for Iraq to repay these loans with oil, but in 1991 the trade
embargo and ensuing Persian Gulf War negated that agreement. In March
1990, the incoming Bulgarian government announced unilateral suspension
of principal payments on outstanding debt, and later interest payments
were suspended as well. Western lines of credit immediately were frozen
and Bulgarian hard currency holdings dropped to the minimal level of
US$200 million in May 1990.
Bulgaria's main Western trading partners were the Federal Republic of
Germany (West Germany) before German unification in 1990, Switzerland,
and Italy. Exports to these countries were relatively minor, accounting
for between 1 and 0.7 percent of total exports. Imports from West
Germany were 4.9 percent of the total, while Switzerland accounted for
1.4 percent of imports, and Italy 1.1 percent. Trade with the developed,
Western economies resembled trade between an undeveloped country and an
industrialized one. Bulgaria imported mostly machinery from those
countries and sold them raw and semifinished materials and agricultural
products.
The most important Third World trading partners, Iraq and Libya,
purchased 2.8 and 2.3 percent of Bulgarian exports, respectively. These
exports consisted mainly of major construction projects and agricultural
goods. The overthrow of the Zhivkov regime revived talk of establishing
a Black Sea Trading Zone that also would include Turkey and Greece and
perhaps Romania. In establishing its new trade policy in 1991, Bulgaria
faced a choice of expanding its traditional commercial ties with Germany
and Germany's partners in the EEC or cultivating new ties with closer
markets such as Turkey. In 1991 Turkey offered to invest US$13 billion
in Bulgaria's economy. An independent Union for Cooperation between
Bulgaria and Turkey was founded to foster direct cooperation between
enterprises of the two countries, and transportation links were
solidified by ministerial agreements in 1991. Talks with the EEC early
in 1991 yielded assurance of shortterm EEC financial support through the
PHARE program (Economic Reconstruction Aid for Poland and Hungary) and
closer future ties, assuming that Bulgaria continued to make progress in
its political and economic reform programs.
New Trade Conditions, 1990
The end of central planning opened the Bulgarian economy to world
competition and began a wrenching transition for which it was
ill-equipped in finance, industrial diversity, agricultural
infrastructure, and available natural resources. The transition was made
doubly difficult because the long years of privileged access to energy
had fostered inefficient energy use in the Bulgarian economy.
Under the new economic conditions, imports would be purchased only in
hard currency; although Western firms and governments offered some
credits and aid in 1991, Western investors preferred Poland, Hungary,
and Czechoslovakia to Bulgaria. Those countries were more familiar to
Westerners, and they had had relatively advanced market economies before
World War II. For these reasons, in the early 1990s they received the
lion's share of a rather meager Western investment in Eastern Europe.
Bulgaria - Government and Politics
ON NOVEMBER 10, 1989, after thirty-five years as undisputed leader,
Todor Zhivkov resigned his positions as head of the Bulgarian Communist
Party (BCP) and head of state of Bulgaria. This act, forced by political
opposition and turmoil, was the symbolic watershed between two very
different eras in Bulgarian governance. One year after Zhivkov's
resignation, Bulgaria had at least some of the primary building blocks
for a democratic state: a freely elected parliament, a coalition
cabinet, independent newspapers, and vigorous, independent trade unions.
Beginning with Soviet occupation of Nazi-allied Bulgaria in September
1944, the political culture of that country had been totally dominated
by a monolithic communist party. In the following three years, that
party took advantage of the presence of Soviet troops, decades-long
disorder in the Bulgarian political system, and its own high visibility
as an anti-Nazi resistance force to complete a rapid communization
process.
Postwar communist rule in Bulgaria can be divided into three periods
with varying political characteristics. The first period, 1944 through
1947, saw the consolidation of communist power. The Fatherland Front,
which began in 1942 as a small illegal antifascist coalition, led a coup
that coincided with the 1944 Soviet invasion and installed communists
for the first time in crucial government positions. In the next three
years, the BCP gradually eliminated disorganized blocks of political
opposition, cut Bulgaria off from foreign influences except that of the
Soviet Bloc, and confiscated most private economic resources. By the end
of 1947, the last effective political opposition had been eliminated and
Soviet troops had left Bulgaria. Longtime communist leader Georgi
Dimitrov was prime minister of a Bulgarian government that ruled
according to a new constitution modeled after that of the Soviet Union.
Although that constitution left the political institutions of prewar
Bulgaria nominally intact, the consolidation period set the pattern for
a very different set of political relationships. Actual political power
was concentrated entirely in the national BCP. From 1947 until 1989,
nominations and elections to judicial, legislative, and executive posts
required party approval. During that time, a nominal second party
existed, but party nominees were elected without opposition at all
levels of government. The National Assembly (Narodno Subranie) met only
to rubber-stamp proposals from the party or the executive branch.
The second phase of the communist period, from 1948 through 1953,
strengthened Bulgaria's traditionally close ties with the Soviet Union
and established a pattern of imitating the Soviet Union in all major
aspects of foreign and domestic policy. The first Bulgarian Five-Year
Plan began in 1949, by which time most means of production were in state
hands. In 1949 Dimitrov was succeeded by Vulko Chervenkov, a prot�g�
of Soviet leader Joseph V. Stalin. Chervenkov imitated his patron's cult
of personality by assuming total control of the BCP and the government
and enforcing complete conformity to party policy through 1954.
Chervenkov intensified the sovietization that began under Dimitrov; the
only vestiges of political diversity at this point were a few national
party leaders who survived Chervenkov's purges.
In 1953 the death of Stalin brought a strong reaction in Soviet
politics against the cult of personality and in favor of collective
leadership. Accordingly, in 1954 Todor Zhivkov replaced Chervenkov as
first secretary of the BCP. In the next eight years, Zhivkov gradually
consolidated his position as supreme leader. In doing so, he maintained
the totalitarian state machinery of his predecessors but showed
flexibility and resiliency--especially in maintaining power at home
while following the winding path of Soviet policy to which Bulgaria
remained scrupulously loyal. In spite of dramatic international changes
and crises between 1954 and 1989, the Zhivkov era was the longest period
of stable rule by a single administration in the history of the modern
Bulgarian state.
In the 1980s, however, the Zhivkov regime was overtaken by the wave
of political liberation that swept all of Eastern Europe, and by the
lethargy and corruption of an administration totally without opposition
for nearly thirty years. Immediately after Zhivkov's fall, Bulgaria
returned to its precommunist political culture, a shifting mosaic of
major and minor parties and coalitions. The National Assembly was
resurrected as the vehicle for democratic representation, and the first
free parliamentary election was held in 1990. Unlike the communist
parties of other East European nations, the BCP (which changed its name
in 1990 to the Bulgarian Socialist Party, BSP) was based on a domestic
political movement that predated the 1917 Russian Revolution. Partly for
this reason, the BSP was able to win the first free elections that
followed overthrow of the old regime. But internal fragmentation,
economic crisis, and the party's connection with the wrongs of the
Zhivkov era diminished the BSP's popular support as the 1990s began.
Meanwhile, based on very brief experimentation with true
parliamentary democracy before World War II, and imitating its East
European neighbors, Bulgaria had decisively rejected repressive
one-party rule and professed allegiance to democracy. But formation of
democratic institutions on the ruins of the early 1900s proved a
formidable task in the early years of the postcommunist era. Coalition
government, the main device of political stability in the precommunist
era, functioned unevenly in solving the massive problems of the early
1990s, and the remaining power centers of the old regime hindered
reform.
<>THE PREWAR
POLITICAL CONTEXT
During World War II, the BCP actively opposed Bulgaria's Axis
alliance by forming partisan terrorist and sabotage groups. In 1942 the
broad Fatherland Front coalition was formed as the communists attempted
to involve legal opposition groups in exerting antiwar pressure on the
government. The coalition's activities brought severe government
reprisals. By 1944 partisan units also were being formed in the
Bulgarian army.
The Red Army invasion of September 1944 found a temporary Bulgarian
government desperately trying to avoid accommodation with the communist
left or the pro-German right, but under intense diplomatic and military
pressure from both Germany and the Soviet Union. Boris had died in 1943
and by 1944 severe wartime shortages (partly caused by peasants hoarding
food supplies) eroded support for the government.
When Soviet troops entered Bulgaria, the Fatherland Front engineered
a bloodless coup displacing the government of Prime Minister Konstantin
Muraviev. In 1946 the first Fatherland Front government divided
ministries among the BCP, Zveno, the Bulgarian Agrarian National Union
(BANU), and the Bulgarian Social Democratic Party (BSDP). Within a year,
the BCP had used that power base to purge the government of all key
opposition figures and dominate the Fatherland Front. In 1946 a national
referendum rejected the monarchy in favor of a people's republic,
leading to the immediate exile of Simeon II, nine-year-old son of Boris
III. The following month, the communists easily won a national election
for representatives to a subranie to write a new constitution
over the objections of BANU, which sought a return to the Turnovo
Constitution. In early 1947, the conclusion of peace between Bulgaria
and the Allies eliminated the Allied Control Commission, through which
Britain had maintained some influence on domestic Bulgarian politics. By
that time, the only remaining obstacle to total BCP domination was
Nikola Petkov's BANU, in a coalition with other noncommunist parties.
The power struggle ended abruptly in mid-1947, when the Fatherland Front
arrested and executed Petkov as a Western agent. This event paved the
way for unanimous adoption of a new constitution in December 1947. The
new document was closely modeled on the 1936 Soviet constitution.
The parliamentary election of fall 1946 gave the BCP 275 of 465 seats
and made Georgi Dimitrov prime minister. The communists gained control
of all significant ministries, beginning the last stage of consolidating
communist dictatorship. The ensuing regimes of Dimitrov and Chervenkov
defined Bulgaria as a highly conventional communist state and isolated
it from nearly all noncommunist commercial and cultural influences.
The State under Dimitrov
In the 1946 elections, noncommunist parties in the Fatherland Front
lost influence far out of proportion to the numerical election results.
The most salient new feature of the Dimitrov Constitution was that it
rejected the separation of powers among government branches in favor of
a "unity of state power," lodged in a presidium wielding
legislative, judicial, and executive powers and chosen by the National
Assembly with party approval. As before, the National Assembly was a
unicameral legislature; elections were to be held every four years, and
members could be recalled at any time. The assembly would meet in
regular sessions twice a year, or by special order of the
Presidium--making the full assembly little more than a rubber-stamp
body. The Presidium met continuously and exercised all constitutional
powers of the National Assembly when the assembly was not in session.
The Presidium's powers included controlling the selection of the Council
of Ministers, amending the constitution, approving the national economic
plan, declaring war, and making peace. The president of the
nineteen-member Presidium thus became one of the two most powerful men
in Bulgaria.
The Council of Ministers retained a nominal executive authority as a
cabinet, but it was overshadowed by the designation of the National
Assembly as "supreme organ of state power." In practice, the
council chairman, who by office was prime minister of the country, was
always the first secretary of the BCP. This gave the prime minister
power equal to that of the Presidium president. The judiciary, now also
chosen by the legislative branch at all levels of government, lost all
independence. Independent local political power was eliminated when
province and district jurisdictions were restructured into people's
councils. The councils elected executive committees analogous to the
national Presidium and overseen by that body. As at the national level,
local government bodies were filled primarily with party officials.
Thus, the Dimitrov Constitution achieved unprecedented centralization of
political power in Bulgaria.
Like its Soviet model, the 1947 constitution guaranteed broad
freedoms to all citizens (religion, conscience, assembly, speech, the
press, emancipation of women, and inviolability of person, domicile, and
correspondence). The Bulgarian document differed from the Soviet by
allowing private property, but only if the privilege were not used
"to the detriment of the public good." All means of production
shifted to state ownership. Universal suffrage was guaranteed, as were
welfare and employment. Guaranteed employment was restricted to socially
useful occupations, however.
Government practice soon eroded the constitutional guarantee of
religious freedom. Between 1948 and 1952, several official acts
repressed the Bulgarian religious community. In 1948 the exarch of the
Bulgarian Orthodox Church was forced into retirement for his refusal to
defend the communist state and the Soviet Union. In 1949 the Law on
Religious Organizations put all churches under state control; over the
next four years, Catholic and Protestant clergy were harrassed and
imprisoned as part of an overall policy of preventing contact with the
West. During this period, the Dimitrov government continued purging
party and nonparty officials, imitating the contemporaneous Stalinist
practice of eliminating all possible political rivals. The most notable
victim was the hardline Stalinist and long-time party leader Traicho
Kostov, convicted and executed in 1949 as a collaborator with the
fascists and Josip Broz Tito, the heretical Yugoslav communist leader.
The Chervenkov Era
The fifth party congress, held in December 1948, rightfully
celebrated the complete political dominance of socialism in Bulgaria.
When Dimitrov died in 1949, his successor, Stalin prot�g� Vulko
Chervenkov, began four years of intense party purges (disqualifying
nearly 100,000 of 460,000 Bulgarian communists). Chervenkov's
cultivation of a cult of personality earned him the nickname
"Little Stalin." The breakaway of Tito's Yugoslavia from the
Cominform (Communist Information Bureau) in 1948 caused Stalin and
Chervenkov to put additional pressure on the BCP to conform with the
Soviet line. Stalin's death in 1953 introduced new Soviet leaders who
disapproved Chervenkov's methodology, but the Bulgarian leader remained
prime minister and dominated politics until 1956. Chervenkov announced a
"new course" in 1953, police terror abated, and some political
prisoners were released. Meanwhile, Bulgarian government under the
communists followed a postwar East European pattern by creating large
numbers of bureaucratic posts, filled by party-approved functionaries,
the nomenklatura. A swollen bureaucracy had been traditional in
Bulgaria since the modern state was founded in 1878; but previously
appointments had depended on membership in the civil service elite, not
on membership in a particular party.
Bulgaria - THE ZHIVKOV ERA
Todor Zhivkov was the dominant figure in Bulgarian government for
about thirty-five years, during which time the political scene remained
remarkably stable. In the context of post-Stalinist communist
statecraft, Zhivkov was a masterful politician. In the context of
popular demands for meaningful reform, he was an anachronism whose
removal symbolized the beginning of a new approach to governance.
The Rise of Zhivkov
The Chervenkov era firmly established Bulgarian reliance on the
Communist Party of the Soviet Union (CPSU) for policy leadership and
resolution of domestic party rivalries. Just as Stalin's condemnation
had doomed Kostov, so condemnation of the cult of personality by
Stalin's successors doomed Chervenkov and prepared the way for his
successor, Todor Zhivkov. Zhivkov, who began his political career in the
party youth organization and worked his way to the party Central
Committee in 1948, became party chief when Chervenkov resigned that
position in 1954. Both the Moscow authorities who ultimately chose new
Bulgarian leaders and the BCP leaders in Sofia approved Zhivkov's
flexibility, youth (he was forty-two when selected), and lack of
powerful friends and enemies.
In 1956 Bulgarian politics again felt the influence of the Soviet
Union. When Nikita S. Khrushchev became leader of the CPSU, he began a
new phase of de-Stalinization and party reform that echoed strongly in
Bulgaria. This left Chervenkov without support outside Bulgaria. Then,
in 1956 the April Plenum of the BCP Central Committee began a broad
party liberalization policy that caused Chervenkov to resign as prime
minister. Rather than break completely with the past, however, the party
retained Chervenkov as a member of a de facto ruling triumvirate that
included Zhivkov and longtime party leader and purge participant Anton
Yugov, who became prime minister. Although party liberalization was
stalled by 1956 uprisings in Hungary and Poland, the April Plenum
identified Zhivkov as the leader of the Politburo. In doing so, it also
shifted power conclusively to the "home" branch of the BCP,
more attuned to Bulgarian issues and less to total obedience to the
Soviet line.
Zhivkov Takes Control
By the end of 1961, a new wave of Soviet anti-Stalinism gave Zhivkov
the support he needed to oust Chervenkov and Yugov. Zhivkov's political
position had deteriorated because his grandiose, failed plans for
industrialization and agricultural collectivization had evoked strong
social protests between 1959 and 1961, but he succeeded Yugov as prime
minister in 1962. Khrushchev formally endorsed Zhivkov with a state
visit to Bulgaria in 1962. Although no additional changes occurred in
the party or the government until 1971, Zhivkov began introducing a new
generation of leaders in the mid-1960s, and political repression eased
noticeably. The old guard of officials remaining from the 1944
revolution remained a powerful party element with important Soviet
connections; therefore, Zhivkov provided that group enough Politburo
positions to ensure its support. Meanwhile, Zhivkov selectively purged
officials throughout the early period to prevent development of
alternative power centers in the party. In 1964 Zhivkov earned peasant
support by appointing Georgi Traikov, chief of the nominally independent
BANU, head of state and by pardoning comrades of the executed BANU
leader Petkov.
In 1966 a strong resurgence of the conservative wing of the BCP at
the Ninth Party Congress curtailed Bulgarian diplomatic and economic
overtures to the West and to its Balkan neighbors. The new conservatism
also tightened government control over the media and the arts, and the
government resumed anti-Western propaganda to protect Bulgarian society
from bourgeois influences. As was the case in the 1956 invasion of
Hungary, Bulgarian support for the 1968 Soviet invasion of
Czechoslovakia brought tighter party control of all social
organizations, and reaffirmation of "democratic centralism"
within the party--all with the goal of reassuring the Soviet Union that
Bulgaria would not follow in the heretical footsteps of the Czechs.
The Constitution of 1971
A later echo of the events of 1968 was the drafting of a new
constitution at the Tenth Party Congress in 1971. Unlike the Dimitrov
Constitution, the new document specified the role of the BCP as
"the leading force in society and the state," and the role of
BANU as its collaborator within the Fatherland Front. The 1971
constitution also defined Bulgaria as a socialist state with membership
in the international socialist community. As before, broad citizen
rights were guaranteed but limited by the requirement that they be
exercised only in the interest of the state. Citizen obligations
included working according to one's ability to build the foundation of
the socialist state and defend the state, compulsory military service,
and paying taxes. Most of the governmental structure specified in the
Dimitrov Constitution remained, but a new body, the State Council,
replaced the Presidium as supreme organ of state power. This council
consisted of twentytwo members and a chairman who was de facto head of
state. The State Council was more powerful than the Presidium because it
could initiate as well as approve legislation, and because it exercised
some of the non-governmental supervision normally delegated to ruling
parties in East European communist states of that period. Council
members, nominally elected by the National Assembly, were members of the
BCP or other mass organizations.
In 1971 Zhivkov resigned as prime minister to become chairman of the
State Council. The National Assembly, traditional center of political
power in Bulgaria until the 1947 constitution stripped it of power,
received some new responsibilities. Permanent commissions were to
supervise the work of ministries, and legislation could now be submitted
by labor and youth groups (all of which were partycontrolled ). In
practice, however, the National Assembly still rubber-stamped
legislation and nominations for the State Council, Supreme Court, and
Council of Ministers. As a follow-up to the constitution's prescription
of private property rights, the 1973 Law on Citizens' Property virtually
abolished private ownership of means of production, confining such
ownership to "items for personal use."
The Tenth Party Congress also devised a new BCP program to coincide
with the new constitutional description of party power. The program
specified an orthodox hierarchical party structure of democratic
centralism, each level responsible to the level above. The lowest-level
party organizations were to be based in workplaces; all other levels
would be determined by territorial divisions. Loyalty to the CPSU was
reiterated. The BCP goal was described as building an advanced socialist
society lacking differentiation by property and social standing--at that
point, all of society was to be a single working class. Science and
technology were to receive special attention by the party, to improve
production that would make possible the next jump from advanced
socialism to the first stage of communism.
After a decade of political calm and only occasional purges of party
officials by Zhivkov, social unrest stirred in the mid-1970s and alarmed
the Zhivkov government. International events such as the Helsinki
Accords of 1975, the growth of Eurocommunism in the 1970s, and the 1973
oil crisis stimulated hope for liberalization and discontent with the
domestic economy. Zhivkov responded in 1977 by purging Politburo member
Boris Velchev and 38,500 party members--the largest such change since
the early 1960s. Provincial party organizations also were substantially
reorganized. In May 1978, the Bulgarian government acknowledged for the
first time that an antigovernment demonstration had occurred--
indicating that the 1977 measures had not quelled domestic discontent.
The Last Zhivkov Decade
The period between 1978 and 1988 was one of political calm. With
minor exceptions, the structure and operations of the government and the
BCP remained unchanged. But the avoidance of meaningful change, despite
cosmetic adjustments in the Zhivkov government, assumed that Bulgarian
governance was the same uncomplicated procedure it had been in the 1970s
and early 1980s--a major miscalculation.
Celebration of the 1,300th anniversary of the Bulgarian state in 1981
brought official liberalization and rehabilitation for some segments of
Bulgarian society. Bourgeois political factions that had opposed the BCP
before World War II were exonerated and described as comrades in the
fight for Bulgarian democracy. Zhivkov also raised the official status
of the Orthodox Church to codefender of the Bulgarian nationality, and
restrictions on religious observances were eased.
By the second half of the 1980s, substantial maneuvering and
speculation centered on identifying the successor to the seventyfour
-year-old Zhivkov, who was increasingly isolated from everyday
governance. Four younger politicians divided most of the key
responsibilities of government and party in 1986. Although speculation
grew that Zhivkov had become a figurehead or was preparing to resign, in
the late 1980s he was still able to divide the power of his rivals and
avoid naming a single successor.
The BCP maintained complete control over all major programs and
policies in the Bulgarian government, although the role of the party in
specific instances was not clear. In 1987, facing a budding opposition
movement and pressure from the Soviet Union, the BCP began planning for
multiple-candidate (not multiparty) regional elections to end citizen
apathy toward both government and the party. Although some reforms were
made in the nomination process, local electoral commissions retained
control over final lists of nominees.
By February 1989, at least nine independent political groups had
emerged. Spurred by the liberalized domestic policies of Mikhail S.
Gorbachev in the Soviet Union, such groups demanded similar concessions
from the Bulgarian government. Given Bulgaria's long record of mimicking
Soviet policy changes, this was a natural expectation. In fact, the 1987
BCP Central Committee plenum had endorsed officially perestroika and
glasnost, the cornerstones of the Gorbachev reform program. The plenum
also substantially reduced official state ceremonies, rituals, personal
awards, and propaganda, explaining that such formalities alienated the
people.
In the three years following the 1987 plenum, however, the Bulgarian
government and the BCP gave lip service to Soviet reforms, while quietly
taking a more hard-line approach to many issues. During this period,
reform in the BCP and the government apparatus was confined to
reshuffling ministries, departments, and personnel as a gesture of
solidarity with perestroika. At the same time, dissident groups
were harrassed, put under surveillance, and accused of unpatriotic
activities.
Issues of Dissent
In the late 1980s, official repression of the Turkish minority was
the most visible domestic issue in Bulgaria. By 1989 this policy had
brought harsh international condemnation and provided a human rights
issue for the domestic opposition. A total of 310,000 ethnic Turks were
expelled or emigrated voluntarily in 1989, and the Bulgarian economy
suffered greatly from this depletion of its work force.
In July 1989, more than a hundred well-known Bulgarian intellectuals
petitioned the National Assembly to restore rights to the ethnic Turks
suffering forced emigration. Bulgarian Turks formed the Movement for
Rights and Freedoms, advocating a wide range of government reforms
besides the Turkish issue. The regime responded by accusing Turkish
agents of fomenting ethnic strife, denying the existence of a Turkish
minority in Bulgaria, and fanning the racial animosity of Bulgarians
toward Turks.
In addition to the ethnic and political problems, in the late 1980s
Bulgaria faced the need for strenuous economic reforms to improve
efficiency, technology, and product quality. Between 1987 and 1989, the
Zhivkov regime promised expansion of trade and joint ventures with the
West, banking reform, currency convertability, and decentralized
planning. In actuality, however, the thirty-five- year-old regime lacked
the political will and energy to press drastic economic reform. The
economic stagnation that began in the early 1980s, with which Zhivkov
had become identified, continued unchallenged and became another major
cause of political discontent.
The Removal of Zhivkov
Despite the appeareance of numerous opposition groupsa in the
preceding year, the Zhivkov regime was unprepared for the successive
fall of communist regimes across Eastern Europe in late 1989. In October
an all-European environmental conference, Ecoforum, was held in Sofia
under the auspices of the Conference on Security and Cooperation in
Europe (CSCE).
This event focused world attention on Bulgaria's history of repressing
environmental activism and stimulated open demonstrations by human
rights advocates and the Bulgarian Ekoglasnost environmental group.
Although some demonstrators were beaten and detained, direct
communication with the West inspired them to greater self-expression.
This activity culminated in a mass demonstration in Sofia on November 3.
Meanwhile, in a speech to a plenum of the BCP in late October, Zhivkov
admitted that his latest restructuring program, begun in 1987 to achieve
"fundamental renewal" of society, politics, and the economy,
had been a failure. He unveiled a new, detailed program to counteract
"alienation of the people from the government and the production
process." Other party spokesmen increasingly noted recent drastic
reforms in other socialist states and pointed to Bulgaria's failure to
keep pace. Then, at the regular plenary meeting of the BCP Central
Committee in November, Prime Minister Georgi Atanasov announced
Zhivkov's resignation.
Although the resignation appeared voluntary, Western observers agreed
that top party figures, increasingly dissatisfied with Zhivkov's refusal
to recognize problems and deal with public protests, had exerted
substantial pressure on him. The leaders of the movement to remove
Zhivkov--Atanasov, Foreign Minister Petur Mladenov (who became head of
state), and Defense Minister Dobri Dzhurov--had received the advance
blessing of Moscow and the majority of the Bulgarian Politburo. Soviet
leader Gorbachev apparently approved the change because Zhivkov had not
heeded warnings that cosmetic reform was insufficient given the drastic
restructuring sought by Gorbachev. Within a month of his resignation,
Zhivkov was expelled from the BCP, accused of abuse of power, and
arrested. Mladenov became chairman of the State Council and chief of the
BCP.
Bulgaria - GOVERNANCE AFTER ZHIVKOV
The Zhivkov ouster brought rapid change in some political
institutions, little or no change in others. The official name of the
country dropped "people's" to become simply the Republic of
Bulgaria. For two years, the BCP remained entrenched as the most
powerful party, slowing reform and clinging tenaciously to economic and
political positions gained under Zhivkov. But a new constitution was
ratified in mid-1991, laying the basis for accelerated reform on all
fronts.
The Mladenov Government
The first few months of the Mladenov regime brought few of the
dramatic changes seen in Czechoslovakia or the German Democratic
Republic (East Germany) in the same period. Mladenov, who came to power
without a personal following, left much of the old government in power
and failed to separate state from party functions. Although initial
reforms came from the Politburo, Mladenov achieved popularity by
immediately legalizing political protest, giving the media unprecedented
freedom, abolishing privileges of party officials, and scheduling free
elections within six months. Article 1 of the 1971 constitution, which
established the leading role of the BCP in Bulgarian government and
society, was abolished in January 1990. Public repudiation of Zhivkov
allowed his subordinates to treat him as a scapegoat, thus protecting
themselves from blame by the proliferating opposition groups.
The Bulgarian communists avoided the immediate political rejection
suffered by their East European comrades for several reasons. Because
the BCP had begun as an indigenous Bulgarian movement in 1891,
Bulgarians did not resent it as an artificially imposed foreign
organization. In 1989 nearly one in nine Bulgarians belonged to the
party, a very high ratio that included a large part of the
intelligentsia. Early opposition groups were concentrated in Sofia and
did not have the means to reach the more conservative hinterlands,
reflecting a political dichotomy between town and country that had
existed since pre-Ottoman times. Visible reorganization and reform
occurred in the BCP shortly after Zhivkov left power; the Politburo was
abolished and some old-guard communists were purged. The BCP invited
opposition representation in the government and conducted a series of
round-table discussions with opposition leaders. In February 1990,
Mladenov resigned as party chief, removing the stigma of party
interference in government; in April, the State Council was abolished
and Mladenov was named president.
The 1990 Stalemate
The first free election of the postwar era, the national election of
June 1990, was anticipated as an indicator of Bulgaria's post-Zhivkov
political mood and as an end to the extreme uncertainty that followed
the Zhivkov era. But the election results provided no decisive answers
or conclusions. During the political maneuvering that preceded the
election, the contest for control of the National Assembly narrowed to
the BCP and the Union of Democratic Forces (UDF), a coalition of several
major and many minor parties and groups with diverse interests. The BCP
presented a reformist image, liberally blaming Zhivkov for national
problems and changing its name to the Bulgarian Socialist Party (BSP) to
stress that a new era had begun. In March an agreement with opposition
groups had made approval of legislative proposals by the round table
necessary before the BCP-dominated National Assembly could consider
passage. The round table also signed accords defining future legal
changes in the political system, including multiple parties, separation
of powers, constitutional protection of media freedom, and legalization
of private property.
The parliamentary election was followed by three months of inactivity
and drift in the summer of 1990. Although the Council of Ministers had
resigned immediately after the election, a new government was not formed
until late August. BSP party official Andrei Lukanov finally became
prime minister in an all-socialist cabinet because UDF and other
opposition parties refused to form a coalition. At the same time, the
National Assembly required several weeks to agree on compromise
candidate Zheliu Zhelev to replace Mladenov as president. The most
significant political situation was outside government institutions. The
two major parties became deadlocked over UDF demands that the BSP
acknowledge its responsibility for the economic ruin of Bulgaria, and
that the government adopt the UDF plan for radical economic reform
similar to that in Poland. Although much of the Zhivkov old guard had
been forced out in favor of middle-of-the road socialists in 1990, the
UDF demands activated strong pockets of reaction. Zhelev, a dissident
philosopher and UDF leader, spent the rest of 1990 seeking compromises
among the factions.
The Lukanov government, tied to an aging, largely conservative
constituency and full of little-known BSP figures, met few of the reform
demands. In October Lukanov presented a 100-day economic reform plan to
serve as a transition to longer-term planning in 1991. The plan borrowed
major parts of the program advocated by the UDF. The National Assembly
remained too divided on the reform issue to give Lukanov the legislative
support he needed. Meanwhile, polls showed a definite drop in popular
support for the BSP; under these circumstances, the UDF intensified
efforts to turn out the government by refusing to support any of
Lukanov's proposals.
In November Bulgaria was paralyzed by student demonstrations and
general strikes called to topple Lukanov. Lukanov's resignation ended
the opposition's refusal to form a coalition government. Zhelev, who
then commanded more political power than any other figure, proposed a
compromise candidate, Dimitur Popov, as prime minister. Popov, a judge
with no party allegiance, received a mandate to form a new cabinet and
proceed with reforms as soon as possible. After considerable
deliberation, cabinet posts were distributed among major factions, and
reform legislation began slowly moving into the National Assembly in the
first half of 1991.
Bulgaria - GOVERNMENT STRUCTURE
In the years immediately following the Zhivkov regime, the nominal
structure of the Bulgarian government remained essentially unchanged.
Actual decision making, however, moved from the elite level of the
communist leadership to a variety of political figures and institutions.
The Role of Unofficial Organizations
An important quasigovernmental institution in the early stages of
this process was the national round table. Conceived by opposition
groups shortly after Zhivkov's fall, the round table format was accepted
by the Atanasov government under threat of general strikes. In March
1990, a declaration on the role and status of the national round table,
formulated by all major political groups, gave the round table approval
rights to all major legislation proposed by the government, prior to
formal consideration by the National Assembly. In 1990 round table
discussions included key government figures and representatives of all
constituent groups of the UDS and other opposition parties and trade
unions. This forum was an effective bridge across the chaotic months
preceding the first free election. It reached key compromises on
election law, major provisions of the new constitution, and economic
reforms. Compromise measures were then forwarded to the parliament for
ratification. By mid-1990 round table proposals were dominated by the
platform of the UDF, for which that forum had become the chief input to
government policy. The national round table thus replaced the BCP as the
de facto source of legislative initiatives, in the absence of a
coalition government representing the major Bulgarian political
factions.
In late 1990, President Zhelev convened a Political Consultative
Council that was able to unite all major factions behind formation of a
coalition government in December 1990. This step ended the threat that
chaos would follow the resignation of the Lukanov government. In January
1991, the parties represented in the National Assembly signed a detailed
agreement describing political rights, the legislative agenda for 1991,
BCP (BSP) responsibility for the mistakes of the Zhivkov regime,
property rights, resolution of social conflicts, and ethnic questions.
The stated purpose of this agreement was to ease national tensions and
provide a proper working atmosphere for the immense reform program
envisioned for 1991.
The National Assembly
In the post-Zhivkov reforms, the National Assembly returned to its
prewar status as a forum for debate of legislation among representatives
of true political factions. This status had been lost completely from
1947 to 1989, when the assembly rubber-stamped legislation originating
in the BCP hierarchy.
The Assembly under Zhivkov
According to the 1971 constitution, the unicameral National Assembly
was the supreme organ of state power, acting as the national legislature
and electing all the other bodies of the national government. In
practice under the Zhivkov regime, the National Assembly met for three
short sessions each year, long enough to approve policies and
legislation formulated by the Council of Ministers and the State
Council. The National Assembly had a chairman (elected by the entire
body, until 1990 at the recommendation of the BCP Central Committee),
and four deputy vice chairs. In the intervals between sessions, the
functions of the assembly were conducted by permanent commissions whose
number and designation varied through the years. Not enumerated in the
1971 constitution, the authority of the commissions often overlapped
that of the ministerial departments. The National Assembly had the power
to dissolve itself or extend its term in emergency session.
During the Zhivkov years, new assemblies were elected every five
years to coincide with party congresses; the Central Committee of the
BCP met immediately before the first session of each new assembly to
approve candidates who were then rubber-stamped by the National Assembly
for the leadership positions of the assembly, State Council, and Council
of Ministers. The ninth National Assembly (1986-90) was rarely even
notified of policy decisions of the Zhivkov-led State Council.
Nevertheless, election of the National Assembly remained the most
important political ritual in Bulgaria throughout the communist period,
and the return to free assembly elections in 1990 recalled the direct
popular representation prescribed in the Turnovo Constitution of 1879,
still revered as a model for Bulgarian governance.
The First Freely Elected Assembly, 1990
The first significant post-Zhivkov act of the holdover (ninth)
National Assembly was passage of twenty-one measures of constitutional
reform. These measures included abolition of the article of the 1971
constitution giving the BCP sole right to govern. In April 1990, that
National Assembly dissolved itself to make way for national election of
a Grand National Assembly, charged with writing and ratifying a new
constitution; this was the first voluntary adjournment of that body
since World War II.
In accordance with the provisions under which the 1990 parliamentary
elections were held, after passing the new constitution in July 1991 the
Grand National Assembly voted to dissolve itself and continue working as
a normal parliament until election of the new body. Thus, in the second
half of 1991 work would continue on critical legislation covering issues
such as privatization, election procedures, and local government reform.
After the 1990 national elections, the National Assembly remained a
weak legislative body, but for a new reason. No longer required to
follow party orders precisely, representatives often were split quite
evenly on reform issues. The majority BSP included reform and
reactionary factions, and the 144 UDF members were a formidable
opposition group. Unlike the brief assemblies of the Zhivkov era, the
new body remained in session several days a week throughout the
remainder of 1990 through mid-1991, struggling for compromise on reform
legislation.
The State Council and the Presidency
The State Council, technically an executive committee within the
National Assembly, was created by the 1971 constitution as the primary
executive agency of the national government. Because of that role, the
chairman of the council was automatically president of the country and
thus one of the two most powerful figures in Bulgaria in the Zhivkov
years. The State Council included representatives from trade unions, the
Communist Youth League of Bulgaria (Komsomol), and other mass
organizations. The council supervised the Council of Ministers and had
the right to repeal ministry decisions--a function that clearly reduced
the Council of Ministers to secondary executive status. In addition to
its executive functions, the State Council could issue direct decrees
with full legal authority when the National Assembly was not in session,
with no provision for later approval by the full legislative body. Under
Zhivkov most members of the State Council were high officials of the
BCP. When Petur Mladenov replaced Zhivkov as chairman of the State
Council, he did not automatically become head of state. When the State
Council was abolished in April 1990, the round table named Mladenov
president of the republic, a new title for the Bulgarian head of state.
The appointment was made with the understanding that the new
constitution would set guidelines for this office. Meanwhile, Mladenov
and his successor Zheliu Zhelev retained the power to form cabinets with
the consent of the National Assembly, to represent the country abroad,
and to act as commander in chief of the armed forces.
The Council of Ministers
The constitution of 1971 substantially diminished the power of the
Council of Ministers, or cabinet, which had been an intermittent center
of executive authority in Bulgarian governments since 1878. In the last
two decades of the Zhivkov regime, the council acted as an advisory
board to the State Council and directed everyday operations of the
government bureaucracies. All members of the Council of Ministers
belonged to the BCP or BANU, and many held top party posts and
ministries simultaneously. Longtime Politburo member Stanko Todorov
headed the executive committee of the council from its creation in 1971
until 1989. Within their areas of responsibility, the ministries had
authority to form administrative organs and to overturn acts by local
government agencies. The exact makeup of the council was not prescribed
in the constitution; the National Assembly had authority to make changes
as necessary, and the council's shape and size changed often in the last
Zhivkov years.
After the elections of 1986, the Council of Ministers was reorganized
and reduced in size. In the last years of the Zhivkov regime, it
included eleven ministers, a chairman (the prime minister), a deputy
prime minister, and the chairman of the Committee on State and People's
Control. In early 1990, the new provisional council had fourteen
ministries: agriculture and forests; construction, architecture, and
public works; economy and planning; finance; foreign affairs; foreign
economic relations; industry and technology; internal affairs; internal
trade; justice; national defense; national education; public health and
social welfare; and transport. The ambassador to the Soviet Union also
had full cabinet status, as did the heads of the committees for
protection of the environment and state and people's control. Five
deputy prime ministers also sat in that cabinet, which was headed by
Zhivkov-era holdover Georgi Atanasov. The second provisional cabinet,
under Andrei Lukanov, included ministers of the environment, culture,
and science and higher education in its seventeen departments. The
ambassador to the Soviet Union was dropped, and a minister for economic
reform added.
The new status of the Council of Ministers as the power center of
Bulgarian government was signaled by the targeting of Prime Minister
Lukanov for opposition pressure in the fall of 1990. A second signal was
intense bargaining between the BSP and opposition parties for positions
in the Popov cabinet. That bargaining produced a compromise agreement
that gave the key ministries of foreign economic relations and finance
to the BSP, with national defense going to the UDF. The Ministry of the
Interior, very sensitive because of its role under Zhivkov as the
enforcer of state security, was largely reorganized and headed by a
nonpolitical figure whose two deputies represented the major parties.
The splitting of the deputy minister positions was a key compromise to
gain approval of the Popov cabinet. In all, five of the seventeen
ministers in the new cabinet were politically unaffiliated; seven
remained from the last Lukanov cabinet to soften the transition; and the
UDF filled only three posts. The multiparty conference that reached this
agreement also allowed for further adjustments in the cabinet structure
for the Popov government. As an interim head of government, Popov's main
goal was to establish minimal political and economic conditions
favorable to long-term reforms.
The Judiciary
Members of the highest national judicial body, the Supreme Court,
were elected to five-year terms by the National Assembly. Until 1990,
however, National Assembly approval really meant control by the State
Council, hence by the BCP. The national court system was divided into
criminal, civil, and military courts; the Supreme Court had jurisdiction
in both original and appellate cases, and it controlled the activities
of all lower courts. The 1971 constitution called the court system and
state prosecutor's office "weapons of the dictatorship of the
proletariat." The chief prosecutor, chief legal official of
Bulgaria, was responsible for compliance with the law by ordinary
citizens, local and national political entities and officials, and other
public organizations. The powers of this office were extended by law in
1980 in an effort to forestall public dissatisfaction with the crime
prevention system. Like the justices of the Supreme Court, the chief
prosecutor served at the approval of the State Council. Together with
the chief justice of the Supreme Court, the chief prosecutor provided
absolute BCP control of the Bulgarian judicial system until 1990. The
election of all judicial officials further guaranteed this control.
Lower courts functioned at the provincial and municipal levels;
election was by people's councils at the provincial level and directly
by citizens at the municipal level, using party-approved lists. In 1990
each of Bulgaria's provinces (including Sofia) had a province court. The
105 provincal courts tried minor offenses. Both professional judges and
lay assessors sat in the lower courts. Specialized disputes were heard
outside the regular court system. For example, international trade cases
went to the Foreign Trade Court of Arbitration of the Bulgarian Chamber
of Commerce and Industry, civil disputes among enterprises and public
organizations were heard by the State Court of Arbitration, and labor
disputes were settled by the conciliation committees of enterprises.
Criticized before and after the fall of Zhivkov, the Bulgarian
justice system changed little with the reform programs of 1990 and 1991.
The round table resolutions of early 1990 alluded only to separation of
the judicial, legislative, and executive branches to avoid concentration
of power in any single branch. However, establishment of an independent,
authoritative judiciary would be complicated by the universal view,
instilled by forty-five years of complete control by the BCP, that the
Bulgarian court system was only an extension of the state's executive
power. In a 1991 poll, only 1.7 percent of Bulgarians expressed trust in
the courts and the prosecutor's office. In 1990 the youngest judges were
over forty years old, and the most talented had left for other careers
because of the short term of office, poor pay, low professional status,
and party control. In late 1990, Judge Dimitur Lozanchev became the
first politically neutral chairman of the Supreme Court since World War
II.
Local Government
In 1987 Bulgaria consolidated its local government structure by
combining its twenty-eight districts (okruzi; sing. okrug),
into nine provinces (oblasti; sing. oblast), including
the city of Sofia. A tangible part of the Zhivkov regime's massive (and
largely theoretical) plan for economic and political restructuring, the
reorganization imitated restructuring plans in the Soviet Union. Local
government consolidation was to eliminate the complex and inefficient okrug
bureaucracies and improve the operation of "people's
self-management," the system by which people's councils nominally
managed area enterprises. The latter improvement was to result from
narrowing the primary function of the new oblast government to
the assistance of local workers' collectives. At the same time,
municipalities and townships became somewhat more autonomous because the
restructuring gave them some of the administrative power removed from
the higher level.
Although the number of districts had remained stable from 1959 until
the 1987 reform, the number and allocation of smaller urban and rural
political entities changed rapidly during that period as the population
shifted. In 1990 there were 299 political divisions smaller than the oblast
and twentynine separate urban areas. Both oblasti and smaller
constituencies were ruled by people's councils, elected for thirtymonth
terms. The local multiple-candidate elections of February 1988 were
another aspect of the restructuring program. Although local election
commissions retained considerable influence over nominations, about 26
percent of successful candidates were nonparty in 1988. At that time,
51,161 councillors and 3,953 mayors were elected.
The people's councils at all levels were run by elected executive
committees that met continuously. These committees had full executive
power to act between sessions of the people's councils, in the same way
as the State Council acted for the National Assembly in the Zhivkov-era
national government. Each council was responsible to the council at the
next higher level; financial planning was to conform to the goals of
national economic programs. Local councils had authority over the
People's Militia, or police, as well as over local services and
administration. The Popov government scheduled new local elections for
February 1991, after which time reforms were expected in the local
government system. Meanwhile, most provincial governments remained under
the control of Zhivkovite officials, intensifying the schism between the
urban and provincial political climates.
Electoral Procedures
The round table reforms of 1990 included a new election law ratified
by the National Assembly. As in other aspects of governance, prescribed
election procedures did not change greatly under the new regime, but the
intent and practice of the law did. The right to vote by direct secret
ballot remained universal for all Bulgarians over eighteen, and the
officials they elected remained thoretically responsible only to the
voters. Prescriptions for eligibility for nomination and the nomination
process changed little with the new law. The main difference was that in
practice the BCP (BSP) no longer could indiscriminately remove elected
representatives or members of people's councils, nor did it control the
nomination function nominally given to public organizations, trade
unions, youth groups, and cooperatives.
Under the election law of 1953, all candidate lists were approved by
the communist-controlled Fatherland Front. Under the 1990 law, all
parties and registered nonparty organizations could submit candidates;
individuals could be nominated for the assembly with 500 signatures of
voters from their district, and an unlimited number of candidates might
run from each district. The State Council formerly had the power to call
elections; for the 1990 Grand National Assembly election, the date was
fixed by agreement of the UDF and the BCP. The Central Election
Commission, formerly a creature of the State Council, was to supervise
the equitable implementation of election laws, overseeing the operation
of equivalent commissions at local levels. Election commissions at all
levels included members from various parties; the Central Election
Commission was headed by a professor of law with no political
connection.
The new law also revised the representational system of the National
Assembly. The new assembly continued to have 400 seats, but it would sit
for four instead of five years. A new electoral structure also was
introduced. Half the National Assembly members were elected in
multiple-seat districts, in proportion to total votes cast for each
party in the district. A 4 percent minimum was required for a party to
achieve representation. The law designated twenty-eight multiple-seat
voting districts, based on the pre-1987 okruzi. The other 200
members were elected from 200 singleseat voting districts. A runoff
election was held in each district where no candidate received 50
percent of the initial vote (this occurred in 81 of the 200 districts).
All voters in the 1990 election had one vote in each type of district.
The election was supervised by the CSCE. According to impartial
observers and the parties themselves, the election was reasonably free
of interference and coercion, considering that most of the electorate
had never faced a true political choice and the registration and voting
systems were quite complex. Party strategies were dictated by timing and
geography. The UDF, lacking time and resources to campaign in the
provinces, confined its efforts to the more congenial constituency in
Sofia and other large cities. The BSP campaigned as a reform party in
progressive Sofia, but it took advantage of the substantial residue of
Zhivkovite local officials in the provinces (many of whom were accused
of exerting pressure on their constituents to vote BSP) to gain 211
assembly seats to the UDF's 144. The UDF outpolled the BSP in Sofia,
Plovdiv, Varna, and most other Bulgarian cities.
The timing of the next national election was the topic of heated
debate in the first half of 1991 as political factions maneuvered for
advantage. After the new constitution was ratified in July 1991 and a
new election law was scheduled for August, elections were tentatively
set for October 1991. The new election law was to free the system of the
cumbersome procedure used in 1990. Controversial elements of the law
were a BSP-backed clause disallowing absentee ballots from �migr�s and
the restriction of all campaign activities to the Bulgarian language.
The 1991 law prescribed a Central Electoral Commission of twenty-five,
to be appointed by the president in consultation with major political
factions. The central commission would then appoint and oversee like
commissions at lower jurisdictions and set policy for election
administration. National elections were to be held by the proportional
system, eliminating the two-part system of 1990. Recognized parties,
coalitions of parties, individual nominees, and combinations of
individuals and parties would be eligible to run. The country was
divided into thirty-one electoral constituencies, three of which were in
Sofia.
Bulgaria - NONGOVERNMENTAL POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS
Until 1989 the BCP exerted firm control over such nongovernmental
political institutions as trade unions, youth groups, women's groups,
and the nominally oppositionist BANU. The ouster of Zhivkov, however,
brought a torrent of new and revived groups into the political arena. In
the new open political climate, the groups' fragmented constituencies
often spoke loudly for their own special interests, greatly complicating
the process of coalition-building and compromise needed to accomplish
national reform.
The Bulgarian Communist (Socialist) Party
The Bulgarian Communist Party (BCP), which renamed itself the
Bulgarian Socialist Party (BSP) several months after the fall of
Zhivkov, boasted one of the highest membership-to-population ratios (one
in nine Bulgarians) in any communist country in the late 1980s. Between
1958 and 1987, membership grew by 442,000, mainly by adding bureaucrats
and blue-collar workers in younger age groups. In 1986 women made up
32.7 percent of party membership but few women held high positions. The
proportion of worker members had grown to 44.4 percent by 1986, and the
proportion of farm members had dropped to 16.3 percent, reflecting an
even sharper drop in the overall farming population of Bulgaria. Party recruitment in the 1980s targeted individuals
already successful in public or economic life, and the proportion of
whitecollar members increased in that decade.
In 1987 the BCP was organized into 2,900 local units. Until 1990
primary party organizations were based primarily in workplaces. The next
level in the hierarchy was municipal organizations, which were overseen
by city or province and ultimately national bodies. At every level,
party and government personnel were closely interwoven, and the
principle of democratic centralism kept the lower levels strictly
subordinate to the national party. The primary organizations were
charged with recruitment and mobilization. A major concession by the
postZhivkov party was removal of party cells from all state offices, the
judiciary, educational and health agencies, as well as all
nongovernmental workplaces--a concession forced by the UDF's threat to
boycott the round table negotiations that would set a national agenda
for political reform early in 1990. That change significantly altered
the primary level of party organization.
Until 1990 the top level of party leadership was the Politburo, of
which Zhivkov was general secretary. That position had been abolished in
the 1950s in the BCP as part of de-Stalinization. It was restored in
1981, however, to recognize Zhivkov's long service and conform to Soviet
restoration under Leonid Brezhnev. Politburo members usually were
selected from the central committee and nominally elected by party
congresses, which normally met every five years. In 1986 the Thirteenth
Party Congress elected an eleven-member Politburo dominated by party
loyalists of Zhivkov's generation but supplemented by a few younger
specialists in politics and economics. Following tradition, the 1986
congress made few changes in the previous Politburo. The party
congresses were nominally the top policy-making body of the party, but,
like the National Assembly, they rubber-stamped decisions handed them by
the party elite.
The BCP hierarchy also included the Central Committee, whose members
the congress unanimously approved from candidates supplied by the party
leadership. Through a number of specialized departments, the Central
Committee performed administrative party work between sessions of
congress. After considerable size variation, the last Central Committee
included 190 members and 131 candidate members in early 1990. The third
elite group was the BCP Secretariat, a group somewhat smaller than the
Politburo (its number also varied during the Zhivkov years), entrusted
with implementing party policy.
Membership in the BCP required recommendation by three established
members; if accepted at the primary and next-highest level, a candidate
received full membership with no probationary period. Criminal or
unethical behavior caused withdrawal of membership. Without benefit of
explanation, a varying number of members also failed to receive the new
party cards issued before each party congress. Abrupt purging of cadre
and membership elements deemed potentially hostile to current programs
was a procedure that Zhivkov used with great skill to balance and weaken
opposition forces throughout his tenure in office.
The fall of Zhivkov brought immediate and dramatic changes in the
BCP, including removal of the word "communist" from its name.
The Extraordinary Fourteenth Party Congress of the BCP was held in the
winter of 1990, over a year sooner than scheduled. That congress
abolished the Central Committee and the Politburo in favor of a Supreme
Party Council headed by a presidency. To streamline party activity, the
new council had only 131 members, 59 fewer than the last Central
Committee. The Secretariat was abolished. The party emerged from the
congress with significant splits between reform and conservative
factions and a new temporary program. Only about 10 percent of previous
Central Committee members became members of the new Supreme Party
Council; several party stalwarts who had survived the Zhivkov overthrow,
including Prime Minister Atanasov, were not elected. The BCP's
constitutional guarantee of the leading role in Bulgarian society
already had been abolished. In a compromise with the UDF shortly after
the congress, party organizations were banned from workplaces and the
armed forces. The BSP had full control of the government (the UDF
refused to form a coalition both before and after the 1990 elections),
but BSP popularity and power ebbed rapidly during 1990 and 1991. By the
first anniversary of Zhivkov's resignation, party membership had
decreased to an estimated 250,000. (Membership had been reported as
984,000 at the time of the Fourteenth Party Congress.)
Bulgaria - The Union of Democratic Forces
The Union of Democratic Forces (UDF--Bulgarian Sayuz na
Demokratichnite Sili--SDS), which emerged as the chief opposition
faction to the BCP after 1989, was a motley coalition of several major
and many minor parties and groups. Some of the parties, such as BANU,
predated the communist era by several decades. Others, such as the Green
Party, were organized after the overthrow of Zhivkov. When the UDF was
founded in December 1989, it included ten organizations; by the
following spring, six more parties and movements had joined.
The basis of the UDF was the dissident groups that formed under the
faltering Zhivkov regime in the late 1980s. The all-European Ecoforum of
October 1989 allowed many such groups to meet and exchange ideas for the
first time; once Zhivkov fell, the initial contacts spawned an
organizational declaration that envisioned a loose confederation. Within
the confederation, constituent groups would continue to work for their
own specific interests. The coordinating council was to include three
members from each organization. Longtime dissident philosopher Zheliu
Zhelev was elected chairman and Petur Beron, a well-known environmental
scientist, was chosen secretary.
The diversity of membership required substantial compromise in the
UDF program. At least one issue central to each member group was
included in the program, however. The general goals of the program were:
a civil society, market economy, multiparty system, and constitutional
government. Sixteen specific steps were outlined to achieve those goals.
The main criterion for acceptance of new member organizations was
compatibility of their goals with those in the UDF program.
Shortly after the UDF was founded, a vital policy decision confronted
its leaders: the BCP-dominated government revoked the Zhivkov program of
Bulgarizing the names of all Turkish citizens. Alienating the extreme
nationalist factions that opposed compromise with the ethnic minority,
the UDF supported the government decision in its first major policy
statement.
In the first half of 1990, the stature of the UDF was enhanced by its
participation as an equal in round table discussions with the BCP (BSP)
on a range of policy issues that would set future economic and political
policy. By March 1990, the coalition's main goal was clearly stated: to
push the interim National Assembly to draft a democratic constitution
and urgent reform legislation as quickly as possible, over the
opposition of remaining BSP hardliners and noncommunist splinter groups.
All factions recognized that once this was completely accomplished, the
coalition would dissolve and members would act as independent political
parties with varying agendas.
In the parliamentary elections of June 1990, the UDF platform
advocated a wide range of drastic reforms in government structure, the
media, foreign policy, and the economy. Detailed proposals were offered
for education, the environment, and a two-phase "shock
therapy" reform leading to a free market economy. Finally, the UDF
blamed the previous communist regime for Bulgaria's current crises. The
UDF failed to gain a majority in the National Assembly because many
rural areas remained in control of Zhivkovite BSP politicians. Many
peasants had felt relatively secure under the old collective system, and
the timing of the election had forced opposition parties to concentrate
campaigns in the cities, their strongest regions. The BSP won 211 of the
400 seats.
In the year following parliamentary elections, BSP obstructionism
stymied legalization of the UDF's reform goals. On the other hand, the
UDF's refusal to participate in the Lukanov cabinet proved its popular
strength by stalemating Lukanov's economic reform program. In the
crisis-driven formation of the Popov government in December 1990, the
UDF gained strategic cabinet posts. In January 1991, the UDF and the BSP
agreed on a timetable for passage of the new constitution and other
urgent legislation, but early in 1991 parliamentary disagreements set
back the schedule. In March 1991, the UDF sponsored a protest rally
attended by more than 50,000 people in Sofia. In May legislators from
several smaller parties walked out of the National Assembly to protest
its inaction; the BANU contingent promised to do the same if the
parliament had not passed a new constitution by the end of June.
Meanwhile, however, official UDF policy continued seeking to break the
long stalemate by convincing the socialists in the National Assembly to
abandon their go-slow approach to reform.
By mid-1991 a split developed between the largest member groups (the
reconstituted BSDP, BANU, Ekoglasnost, and the Green Party) and the
smaller ones over using quotas and preferential lists in the next
election--a practice that would contradict the UDF's role as a single
national movement and give larger parties substantially more influence
in policy making. Easily the largest member organizations with about
100,000 members each, the BANU and BSDP would benefit most from such a
shift. In July 1991, voting in the National Assembly on the new
constitution clarified the split between factions viewing the UDF as a
single national movement and those seeking individual identity within a
loose confederation. The main issue was the constitutional prescription
for legislative representation by party. By summer 1991, disagreements
on ratification of the constitution had led splinter groups to form a
new Political Consultative Council to rival the UDF's existing National
Coordinating Council as a controlling agency of the UDF. This threatened
to split the UDF into two or three slates of candidates for the 1991
national elections. Thus, by mid-1991 the relative harmony of the UDF's
first year had evolved into persistent divisiveness affecting tactics,
organizational structure, and the pace of reform. In spite of
conciliatory efforts by the coordinating council, the effective united
front that had forced major concessions from the BSP in 1990 seemed less
potent in 1991.
Bulgaria - Trade Unions
The Bulgarian trade union movement was rejuvenated in the pluralist
post-Zhivkov political atmosphere after being forced to adhere totally
to BCP policy throughout the postwar period. By 1990 unions were a
powerful policy-making force, using well-organized strikes and walkouts
to emphasize their positions.
Unions under Communist Regimes
In the decade before World War II, the benign dictatorship of Tsar
Boris III abolished independent trade unions in favor of a single
government-sponsored Bulgarian Workers' Union. As Bulgaria emerged from
the war under Soviet occupation, communists abolished that union and
replaced it with a General Workers' Professional Union that included
both white- and blue-collar workers. Gradually, independent union
organizations were forced to disband or join the communist organization.
By 1947 union leaders were an important instrument in consolidation of
the party's power. When capitalism was declared illegal in 1948, the
Dimitrov government united thirteen unions under the Central Council of
Trade Unions, which endured until 1989 as the single umbrella
organization representing Bulgarian workers.
During that entire period, all workers' and professional
organizations followed faithfully the economic policies of the BCP. The
official goals of the Bulgarian trade unions were first to help
management to fulfill state economic plans, then to defend workers'
interests when they did not conflict with such fulfillment. As
institutions the unions had no policy input. In individual enterprises,
union leaders and managers developed informal advisory relationships.
The only official role of the unions was as transmitters of party
policies to the working masses. Although union and BCP membership were
theoretically separate, officials at the national and local levels often
overlapped to give the party direct control of workers. For example,
members of the districtlevel people's councils often were also union
executives.
General congresses of trade unions were held explicitly to carry out
BCP policy; congress delegate structure (2,997 attended the ninth
congress in 1982) and the holding of preliminary district congresses
mimicked BCP procedures. The many industrial reorganization plans of the
Zhivkov regime meant periodic restructuring, if not new roles, for the
unions. In the early 1980s, for example, the decentralizing reforms of
the New Economic Model (NEM) changed the labor union structure from one
divided by region to one divided by brigade, collective, and enterprise,
matching the NEM industrial structure of the time. Although this change
was controversial, it did little to improve the influence of the
Bulgarian working class on enterprise policy.
In the 1980s, union membership approached 4 million, encompassing an
estimated 98 percent of Bulgarian workers. Almost a year before the fall
of Zhivkov, the Independent Labor Federation, Podkrepa, organized as a
white-collar opposition group inspired by the Polish Solidarity
movement. In 1989 Podkrepa consistently was persecuted for its outspoken
criticism of Zhivkov's policies.
Independent Union Organizations
When the communist regime was overthrown, the central council began
restructuring the trade union system, declaring the organization
independent of the BCP and renaming its umbrella organization the
Confederation of Independent Trade Unions (CITU). In 1990 BCP
organizations were banned from work places, although the continuing
overlap of party and union officials maintained substantial communist
influence in the CITU at local levels. In the early reform years, the
CITU and Podkrepa were the two major trade union federations, although
many independent unions also emerged in this revival period for the
movement. Early in 1990, Podkrepa established its credibility by
exacting an agreement with CITU guaranteeing its members all the rights
(and the substantial privileges) accorded official trade unions under
the previous system. From the beginning, Podkrepa sought maximum
influence on government policy, repeatedly demanding radical economic
reform.
Podkrepa grew rapidly in 1990 because of its roles as a charter
member of the UDF, as a participant in the policy round tables with the
BCP, and as the organizer of strikes and demonstrations against the
communist-dominated Lukanov government. In early 1990, an estimated 300
strikes helped convince the government that talks with opposition groups
were necessary. Although Podkrepa ran no candidates in the national
elections of 1990, it vigorously supported candidates who espoused labor
views. In late 1990, another wave of strikes pushed the Lukanov
government out and led to the coalition Popov government. Although CITU
and other unions participitated, Podkrepa usually was the prime
organizer in such actions.
CITU, whose membership of 3 million dwarfed the 400,000 of Podkrepa,
remained politically passive in the early post-Zhivkov period. In
mid-1990 CITU began issuing statements critical of government
inactivity, and it mobilized 500,000 workers to participate in the
November 1990 strikes initiated by Podkrepa against the Lukanov
government.
The strikes that forced Lukanov's resignation also raised criticism
of the political role of both labor organizations late in 1990. CITU
received criticism for both its continued ties with the BSP and its
aggressive reformist stance. The Supreme Party Council of the BSP
declared a policy of noninterference in CITU affairs. Meanwhile,
Podkrepa, led by controversial, outspokenly anticommunist Konstantin
Trenchev, responded to internal and external criticism by changing from
active membership to observor status in the UDF.
The unions continued active participation in political decision
making in 1991, however. Because economic reforms brought substantial
unemployment and workplace disruption, representing worker interests was
synonymous with such involvement in this period. In January 1991, CITU
and Podkrepa signed a "social peace agreement" with the Popov
government to refrain from striking during the first phase of economic
reform in exchange for limitations on work-force cutbacks. However,
jurisdictional and policy disputes threatened to undermine the
agreement. Although both organizations continued to support the Popov
government, in March 1991 Podkrepa proposed that UDF representatives
boycott the National Assembly because it failed to pass reform measures.
As opposition to the communists declined as a uniting factor,
Bulgaria's trade unions maneuvered to shape new roles for themselves in
1991. Representing 40 percent of the population in a wide-open political
culture, they exerted tremendous influence on policy even in the first
post-Zhivkov year. The radical economic reform envisioned by Bulgarian
leaders would include entirely new relationships among the government,
enterprise management, and unions. Movement to a Western-style
free-market economy would mean conceding some worker rights taken for
granted under the command economy, but compromise with the Podkrepa-led
union movement promised to be a severe test for other political
institutions.
Bulgaria - Youth Organizations
In the post-Zhivkov era, extreme diversification of political
organizations and activities paralleled a similar liberation in the
media and the arts. Under Zhivkov Bulgaria had followed the totalitarian
formula for media control, allowing only official radio and television
stations and newspapers that were conduits for the official party line
on all subjects. Limited artistic freedom came in several
"thaw" periods (notably in the mid-1960s and the late 1970s)
that closely followed similar relaxation in the Soviet Union. The
charisma of Liudmila Zhivkova, appointed by her father to oversee
cultural affairs in 1975, notably lightened the Bulgarian cultural scene
from the late 1970s through 1981. The early 1980s was a time of
unprecedented freedom for media discussion of controversial topics; the
Law on Plebiscites (1983) was to have promoted discussion of preselected
issues of public interest, but by 1984 party reactionaries had
reasserted control. The 1984 Bulgarian Writers' Conference called for
more ideological content in literature, signaling a change that lasted
through the end of the Zhivkov regime.
The Intelligentsia
Intellectual groups developed no formal organizations comparable to
groups in other East European countries, because the small intellectual
community centered in one city (Sofia) required no such measures.
Furthermore, the Bulgarian Writers' Union already contained a large
percentage of the intelligentsia. Especially during the "thaw"
periods, factions in the union showed substantial diversity in their
approach to the role of art versus that of the state. A much smaller
Bulgarian Artist's Union and Bulgarian Journalists' Union had similar
status. A samizdat (underground publication network) did
circulate dissident writings from the Soviet Union and elsewhere. Among
official publications, Narodna kultura (People's Culture)
gained a singular reputation between 1984 and 1988 by publishing
provocative articles on politics, economics, education, and the
environment. In 1988 Zhivkov fired its editor Stefan Prodev for helping
found a dissident organization.
Zhivkov and the Intelligentsia
Until the late 1980s, Zhivkov successfully prevented unrest in the
Bulgarian intellectual community. Membership in the writers' union
brought enormous privilege and social stature, and that drew many
dissident writers such as Georgi Dzhagarov and Liubomir Levchev into the
circle of the officially approved intelligentsia. On the other hand,
entry required intellectual compromise, and refusal to compromise led to
dismissal from the union and loss of all privileges. The punishment of
dissident writers sometimes went far beyond loss of privileges. In 1978
�migr� writer Georgi Markov was murdered in London for his
anticommunist broadcasts for the British Broadcasting Corporation, and
Blaga Dimitrova was harshly denounced for her critical portrayal of
party officials in her 1982 novel Litse.
Zhivkov also softened organized opposition by restoring symbols of
the Bulgarian cultural past that had been cast aside in the postwar
campaign to consolidate Soviet-style party control. Beginning in 1967,
he appealed loudly to the people to remember "our motherland
Bulgaria." In the late 1970s, Zhivkov mended relations with the
Bulgarian Orthodox Church, and in 1981 Liudmila Zhivkova's national
celebration of Bulgaria's 1,300th anniversary raised patriotic feeling.
Zhivkov's extensive campaign of cultural restoration provided at least
some common ground between him and the Bulgarian intelligentsia.
The Ferment of 1988-90
In late 1987, dissatisfaction with government corruption, pollution,
the Turkish issue, and repeated failure of economic reform programs
began to stimulate open political dissent. By that time, a younger
generation had matured, unimpressed by communist doctrine and
disinclined to blind obedience. In November 1987, the Federation of
Clubs for Glasnost and Democracy (originally the Discussion Club for
Support of Glasnost and Perestroika) was founded by communist
intellectuals to promote openness in Bulgarian society. In early 1988,
the appearance of the Independent Association for Defense of Human
Rights in Bulgaria publicized the repression of the regime. Meanwhile,
the fragmented intellectual community had been galvanized by a single
issue: environmental degradation. In the winter of 1987-88, an
ecological exhibition in Ruse, one of the most seriously polluted
industrial centers in Bulgaria, received national media attention. The
communist regime's failure to protect its people from such dangers
became a symbol for the general aura of incompetence that surrounded
Zhivkov in the late 1980s.
In mid-1988 Zhivkov responded to the new opposition by purging two
high pro-glasnost party officials, signaling that the party
would permit glasnost only on its own terms. The BCP also tried
to preempt environmental opposition by forming the Movement for
Environmental Protection and Restoration amid promises for stiffer
environmental regulation.
In late 1988 and early 1989, many leaders of independent Bulgarian
groups were deported or harrassed. Nevertheless, by mid1989 at least
thirteen independent associations and committees had been founded for
the defense of human rights and the environment. Then in 1989, communism
was discredited by successful freedom movements in Hungary, Poland, East
Germany, and Czechoslovakia. By that time, glasnost had
stimulated political dialog in the Soviet Union, which was still the
model for Bulgarian political behavior. Under these new conditions,
government intimidation failed. Although Zhivkov sought reconciliation
with the intelligentsia by proclaiming a "new cultural
revolution" in early 1989, the unions of writers, journalists, and
artists leveled strong criticism on the environment and other issues.
When Ekoglasnost was formed that year, it made a formidable public
appeal for an accounting of economic policies that harmed the
environment.
In 1989 the Federation of Clubs backed the National Assembly petition
against Turkish assimilation by characterizing the policy as against the
best traditions of the Bulgarian nation. According to one theory, the
Zhivkov policy toward the Turks was calculated to alienate the
intelligentsia from the ethnocentric Bulgarian majority by forcing the
former to take sides with the Turks; whatever its purpose, the policy
failed amid the massive Turkish exodus of 1989. Leaders of the Movement
for Rights and Freedoms, deported for defending the Turks, were welcomed
at a session of the CSCE, severely damaging Zhivkov's image in Europe.
In the fall of 1989, dissident groups received further validation at the
CSCE Conference on the Environment in Sofia, where they held public
meetings and were received by Western delegates. The mass demonstrations
that followed convinced the BCP that the Zhivkov regime could not
survive.
Dramatic expression of public discontent continued after the Zhivkov
ouster. In mid-1990 tent-city demonstrations in Sofia continued for
several weeks, encountering no effective official resistance. Patterned
after peaceful antigovernment protests of the 1960s in the West, the
Sofia campsite of over 100 tents near the BSP headquarters building
began as a protest against communist retention of power in the national
elections of June 1990. The protest eventually included demonstrators of
many political viewpoints. Besides election fraud by the BSP, issues
targeted were the Chernobyl' coverup, corruption among former and
present BCP/BSP officials, Bulgaria's role in the invasion of
Czechoslovakia, and past actions of present government officials such as
Lukanov and Interior Minister Atanas Semerdzhiev. The tent city played
an important role in publicizing reform issues as a new national
government was being formed.
The Media and Public Issues
In the wake of Zhivkov's overthrow, fast-spreading pluralism in the
media and intellectual circles brought a din of conflicting opinion to
the public. In 1987 Bulgaria had seventeen daily newspapers, most of
which were local. By 1991 eight national newspapers were publishing, and
an expanding variety of local and weekly papers was available. Until
1990 the chief daily newspaper was Rabotnichesko delo, the
official organ of the BCP. After the fall of Zhivkov, the daily was
renamed Duma; in its new format, it began to feature more
balanced accounts of national problems, reflecting the moderate image
now cultivated by its sponsoring organization. The fragmentation of
politics in 1990 brought a newspaper boom that included a full spectrum
of political views. In 1991 the leading papers by circulation were Duma,
Demokratsiya (an independent), the trade union daily Trud,
and Zemia, aimed primarily at rural readers. The most popular
weeklies were Sturshel, featuring folk humor, and the
long-running Pogled. The weekly 168 Chasa went
furthest in rejecting traditional Bulgarian journalism in favor of
sophisticated parody and Western-style indepth features.
Universities dropped their required study of Marxist-Leninist
ideology, and student organizations emerged immediately to assert
positions on a wide variety of issues. In numerous national polls, the
public expressed dissatisfaction with government leaders, economic
policies (as both too radical and too conservative), and the BSP.
Vestiges of the traditional gap between city and village remained,
however: on the average, rural Bulgarians expressed less support for
market reform and noncommunist leaders, placed less blame on the
communists for current problems, and opposed complete rights for the
Turkish minority more strongly.
In 1990-91 the media featured major expos�s on malfeasance by the
Zhivkov regime (acknowledged by the present BSP under public pressure),
coverups of radiation exposure from the Kozloduy Nuclear Power Plant and
the Chernobyl' disaster in the Soviet Union, and the murder of Georgi
Markov (a full-scale investigation of which opened in 1990). In mid-1991
Bulgaria opened its archives to an international commission
investigating the 1981 assassination attempt on Pope John Paul II. In
spite of those developments, in 1991 government agencies and individuals
still threatened independent publications with court action for
"treasonous" statements. In a 1991 poll by the independent 168
chasa, 46 percent of respondents expressed the belief that a
campaign had been organized to control the Bulgarian media (the BSP and
party officials were most often named responsible), and 37 percent said
that freedom of the press was not in danger in Bulgaria.
The Permanent Commission for Human Rights and the National Problem
was created in 1990 as an advisory and investigatory agency of the
National Assembly. Composed of thirty-nine members of parliament, the
commission received the nominal assignment of investigating past and
present human rights violations in Bulgaria, recommending appropriate
compensation, and drafting new human rights legislation. Among the
issues addressed in the commission's first year were restoration of
government-confiscated property to churches and Turkish citizens;
verifying complaints of unfair sentencing and inhumane prison
conditions; proposing laws to replace restrictive legislation such as
the Law on Religious Beliefs and the Law on Passports; and erecting
legal barriers against state persecution for political reasons. In
January 1991, commission chairman Svetoslav Shivarov reported that all
political prisoners in Bulgaria had been freed.
The Turkish Problem
As in other parts of Eastern Europe, the repeal of single-party rule
in Bulgaria exposed the long-standing grievances of an ethnic minority.
Especially in the 1980s, the Zhivkov regime had systematically
persecuted the Turkish population, which at one time numbered 1.5
million and was estimated at 1.25 million in 1991. Mosques were closed,
Turks were forced to Slavicize their names, education in the native
language was denied, and police brutality was used to discourage
resistance. The urban intelligentsia that partcipated in the 1990 reform
movement pushed the post-Zhivkov governments toward restoring
constitutionally guaranteed human rights to the Turks. But abrogation of
Zhivkov's assimilation program soon after his fall brought massive
protests by ethnic Bulgarians, even in Sofia.
In January 1990, the Social Council of Citizens, a national body
representing all political and ethnic groups, reached a compromise that
guaranteed the Turks freedom of religion, choice of names, and unimpeded
practice of cultural traditions and use of Turkish within the community.
In turn the Bulgarian nationalists were promised that Bulgarian would
remain the official language and that no movement for autonomy or
separatism would be tolerated. Especially in areas where Turks
outnumbered Bulgarians, the latter feared progressive
"Islamification" or even invasion and annexation by Turkey--a
fear that had been fed consciously by the Zhivkov assimilation campaign
and was revived by the BSP in 1991. Because radical elements of the
Turkish population did advocate separatism, however, the nonannexation
provision of the compromise was vital.
The Bulgarian governments that followed Zhivkov tried to realize the
conditions of the compromise as quickly as possible. In the multiparty
election of 1990, the Turks won representation in the National Assembly
by twenty-three candidates of the predominantly Turkish MRF. At that
point, ethnic Bulgarians, many remaining from the Zhivkov regime, still
held nearly all top jobs in government and industry, even in the
predominantly Turkish Kurdzhali Province. Nevertheless, parts of
Bulgarian society felt threatened by the rise of the MRF. In 1990 that
faction collided with a hard-line Bulgarian group, the National
Committee for Defense of National Interests--an organization containing
many former communists instrumental in the Zhivkov assimilation program.
In November 1990, Bulgarian nationalists established the Razgrad
Bulgarian Republic in a heavily Turkish region to protest the
government's program of restoring rights to the Turks. In the first half
of 1991, intermittent violence and demonstrations were directed at both
Turks and Bulgarians in Razgrad.
These conditions forced the government to find a balance between
Turkish demands and demonstrations for full recognition of their culture
and language, and Bulgarian nationalist complaints against preferential
treatment for the ethnic minority. In 1991 the most important issue of
the controversy was restoring Turkishlanguage teaching in the schools of
Turkish ethnic districts. In 1991 the Popov government took initial
steps in this direction, but long delays brought massive Turkish
protests, especially in Kurdzhali. In mid-1991 continuing strikes and
protests on both sides of the issue had brought no new discussions of
compromise. Frustration with unmet promises encouraged Turkish
separatists in both Bulgaria and Turkey, which in turn fueled the
ethnocentric fears of the Bulgarian majority-- and the entire issue
diverted valuable energy from the national reform effort. Although most
political parties supported full minority rights, in 1991 the strength
of Bulgarian nationalist sentiment, deeply rooted in centuries of
conflict with the Ottoman Empire and not inclined to compromise,
promised to make the Turkish question the most pressing human rights
issue in Bulgaria for the foreseeable future.
Bulgaria - FOREIGN POLICY
Although the Zhivkov regime often advocated closer relations and
multilateral cooperation with Yugoslavia, Turkey, Greece, Albania, and
Romania, a number of traditional issues barred significant improvement
until the late 1980s. Bulgarian proposals to make the Balkans a zone
free of chemical and nuclear weapons, or a "zone of peace and
understanding" (advanced by Zhivkov at the behest of the Soviet
Union, and to eliminate weapons of the North Atlantic Treaty
Organization (NATO) from the region) was vetoed on several occasions.
But in 1990, Zhelev was able to remove some of the suspicion that had
barred rapprochement by the Zhivkov regime. Post-Zhivkov regimes sought
closer relations with both Greece and Turkey, partly in the hope that
NATO would grant Bulgaria membership to form a bridge between its two
mutually hostile members.
Yugoslavia
Bulgarian relations with Yugoslavia were conditioned by old issues of
Balkan politics and by strong domestic political forces at work in both
countries. Throughout the 1980s, the Yugoslav media complained loudly
that Bulgaria mistreated its Macedonian citizens by insisting that
Macedonians were ethnically Bulgarians, making separate ethnic
recognition inappropriate. The Zhivkov regime (and its successors),
fearing that inflamed nationalism in Yugoslavia would intensify demands
for Macedonian autonomy across the border in Bulgaria, largely ignored
the Yugoslav propaganda campaign on the Macedonian issue. The dispute
over Macedonia survived and prospered after communism lost its grip on
both countries. Bulgarian nationalists, stronger after Zhivkov, held
that the Slavic population of the Republic of Macedonia was ethnically
Bulgarian, a claim leading naturally to assertion of a Greater Bulgaria.
To defuse nationalist fervor on both sides, and in keeping with the
policy of improved relations with all neighbors, Zhelev officially
advocated nonintervention in the ethnic affairs of other nations.
The nonintervention strategy assumed greater importance when the
Republic of Macedonia sought independence from the Yugoslav federation
in 1991 in an effort to escape the increasing dominance of the Republic
of Serbia in the federation. That effort reinforced the protective
attitude of Macedonian nationalists in Bulgaria toward Yugoslav
Macedonia, which had been part of Serbia in the interwar period.
Serbia's use of force to prevent the breakup of the Yugoslav federation
in 1991 triggered Bulgarian fears of wider destabilization in the
Balkans if Serbian expansionism were fully revived.
In 1991 Bulgarian policy toward Yugoslavia was complicated by the
rejuvenation of Macedonian national groups in Bulgaria. The largest of
these was the Union of Macedonian Societies, a longstanding cultural and
educational society that in 1990 took the prefix IMRO (Internal
Macedonian Revolutionary Organization), which was the name of the
terrorist organization active in Bulgaria, Greece, and Serbia between
1893 and 1935. But the threat posed by such groups remained small
because the focus of Bulgarian nationalism was the Turkish issue in
1991, and because economic reform was the major concern of all factions.
In spite of claims by the Serbian press that Bulgaria was aiding Croatia
in the civil war of 1991 and that Bulgaria owed Serbia reparations from
World War II, Bulgaria followed Zhelev's policy of nonintervention as
the Yugoslav civil war continued.
Romania
In the early 1980s, Bulgarian relations with Romania featured regular
official visits by Zhivkov and Romanian President Nicolae Ceausescu and
diplomatic avoidance of differing approaches to internal control
(Romania being the more totalitarian) and the Warsaw Pact (Bulgaria
being the more loyal member). At that point, both countries concentrated
on more pressing foreign issues, and both advocated creating a Balkan
nuclear-free zone. But during the 1980s, relations were strained by the
independent foreign policy of Romania, its opposition to perestroika
in the late 1980s, and mutual accusations of environmental pollution
affecting the other country. Deteriorating personal relations between
Zhivkov and the maverick Ceausescu also may have contributed to the
decline. But, in the name of Warsaw Pact solidarity, the Zhivkov regime
subdued criticism of chemical pollution from Romanian plants across the
Danube, and it remained neutral in the Hungarian-Romanian dispute over
Romanian treatment of ethnic Hungarians in that country in the late
1980s. After the emergence of the environment as a political issue in
1989, however, accusations became more harsh on both sides. In 1991
joint commissions attempted to reach a compromise on the environmental
issue and restore the pragmatic, relatively amicable relationship of the
postwar years.
Greece
Bulgarian relations with Greece, a traditional enemy, were stable
throughout the 1970s and 1980s, in spite of major government changes in
both countries. Zhivkov made this stability a model for the overall
Balkan cooperation that was a centerpiece of his foreign policy in the
1980s. In 1986 the two countries signed a declaration of
good-neighborliness, friendship, and cooperation that was based on
mutual enmity toward Turkey and toward Yugoslav demands for recognition
of Macedonian minorities in Bulgaria and Greece. An important motivation
for friendship with Greece was to exploit NATO's Greek-Turkish split,
which was based on the claims of the two countries in Cyprus. In early
1989, Bulgaria signed a ten-year bilateral economic agreement with
Greece.
The main historical issue between Bulgaria and Greece, disposition of
their Macedonian minorities, was settled during the 1970s; after that
time, the parties adopted mutual policies of strict noninterference in
internal affairs. In mid-1991 the possibility of independence for
Yugoslav Macedonia threatened to renew tension in that area.
Post-Zhivkov Bulgarian policy toward Greece remained very conciliatory,
however; in 1991 Zhelev stressed cooperation with Greece as a foundation
for Balkan stability and reassured the Greeks that Bulgarian
rapprochement with Turkey did not threaten this relationship.
Turkey
In spite of intermittent rapprochement, Turkey was hostile to
Bulgaria through most of the 1980s because of Zhivkov's mistreatment of
Bulgarian Turks and the economic hardship caused in Turkey by mass
immigration of Turks from Bulgaria in 1989. The last rapprochement, a
protocol of friendship in early 1988, was signed by Bulgaria to defuse
international criticism of its ethnic policy. That agreement dissolved
rapidly in 1988, when Turkey saw no change in Bulgarian ethnic
assimilation; by 1989 Turkey was vowing to defend the Turkish minority,
while Bulgaria claimed that its "Turks" were all Bulgarians
converted to Islam under the Ottoman Empire.
The ouster of Zhivkov and subsequent Bulgarian commitment to
repatriate deported Turks and grant them full human rights brought a
marked change in Turkish policy. Despite delays and complaints from the
Bulgarian Turks, Turkey remained patient and positive toward all signs
of progress. The former dissident Zhelev, long a vocal critic of
assimilation, became president and met with Turkish President Turgut �zal
in September 1990. That meeting began a series of high-level economic
talks in 1990-91 that yielded Turkish loans and technical assistance to
Bulgaria and promised to bolster bilateral trade, which had shrunk by 80
to 90 percent in the mid1980s . A new treaty of friendship and
cooperation was prepared in the summer of 1991.
Despite the thaw, obstacles remained in Bulgarian-Turkish
rapprochement. The ill will caused by Zhivkov's shrill anti-Turkish
propaganda remained fresh in the early 1990s. Strident anti-Muslim and
anti-Turkish statements in the media by Bulgarian nationalist factions
kept tension high, and minor border incidents continued in 1991. And
Bulgarian friendship with Greece created a precarious balancing act that
required caution toward such moves as the Bulgarian-Turkish nonagression
pact proposed by Turkey in late 1990.
Bulgaria - The Soviet Union
Anastasoff, Christ. The Bulgarians. Hicksville, New York:
Exposition Press, 1977.
Bankowicz, Marek. "Bulgaria--The Limited Revolution." Pages 195-210
in Sten Berglund and Jan Ake Dellenbrant (eds.), The New
Democracies in Eastern Europe. Aldershot, United Kingdom:
Edward Elgar, 1991.
Bell, John D. The Bulgarian Communist Party from Blagoev to
Zhivkov. Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press,
1986.
------. Peasants in Power: Alexander Stamboliski and the
Bulgarian Agrarian National Union, 1899-1923. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1977.
Berglund, Sten, and Jan Ake Dellenbrant (eds.). The New
Democracies in Eastern Europe. Aldershot, United Kingdom:
Edward Elgar, 1991.
Bokov, Georgi (ed.). Modern Bulgaria: History, Policy, Economy,
Culture. Sofia: Sofia Press, 1981.
Bokova, Irina. "Bulgaria and Ethnic Tensions in the Balkans,"
Mediterranean Quarterly, 2, No. 1, Winter 1991, 88-
98.
Bromke, Adam, and Derry Novak, (eds.). The Communist States in
the Era of Detente, 1971-1977. Oakville, Ontario: Mosaic
Press, 1979.
Bromke, Adam, and Teresa Rakowska-Harmstone (eds.). The
Communist States in Disarray, 1965-1971. Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota, 1972.
Bukowski, Charles. "The Dilemma of Economic Reform and Political
Legitimacy in Eastern Europe," Coexistence, 23, No.
3, 1986, 227-45.
Constant, Stephen. Foxy Ferdinand: Tsar of Bulgaria. New
York: Franklin Watts, 1980.
Crampton, Richard J. A Short History of Modern Bulgaria.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.
Debove, Alain. "The Turkish Minority in Bulgaria," Nordic
Journal of Soviet and East European Studies [Oslo], 4,
No. 3, 1987, 53-63.
Dellin, L.A.D. (ed.). Bulgaria. New York: Praeger, 1957.
Devedjiev, Hristo H. Stalinization of the Bulgarian Society,
1949-1953. Philadelphia: Dorrance, 1975.
Dimitrov, Ilcho (ed.). Kratka istoriia na Bulgariia.
Sofia: Nauka i izkustvo, 1981.
Evans, Stanley G. A Short History of Bulgaria. London:
Lawrence and Wishart, 1960.
Genchev, Nikolai. The Bulgarian National Revival Period.
Sofia: Sofia Press, 1977.
Georgiev, Emil, et al. Bulgaria's Share in Human Culture.
Sofia: Sofia Press, 1968.
Groueff, Stephane. Crown of Thorns. Lanham: Madison Books,
1987.
Holden, Gerard. The Warsaw Pact: Soviet Security and Bloc
Politics. Oxford: B. Blackwell, 1989.
Hristov, Hristo. A History of Bulgaria. Sofia: Sofia
Press, 1985.
Jelavich, Barbara. The Habsburg Empire in European Affairs,
1814-1918. Chicago: Rand McNally, 1969.
------. History of the Balkans. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1983.
Jelavich, Charles. The Establishment of the Balkan National
States, 1804-1920. Seattle: University of Washington
Press, 1977.
Kaplan, Robert D. "History's Cauldron," Atlantic Monthly,
267, No. 6, June 1991, 93-96.
Kinder, Hermann, and Werner Hilgemann. The Anchor Atlas of
World History, 1. Garden City, New York: Anchor Books,
1974.
Lang, David. The Bulgarians. Boulder, Colorado: Westview
Press, 1976.
McIntyre, Robert J. Bulgaria: Politics, Economics, and
Society. London: Pinter, 1988.
Miller, Marshall Lee. Bulgaria During the Second World
War. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1975.
Mishev, Dimitur. The Bulgarians in the Past. New York:
Arno Press, 1971.
Nicoloff, Assen. The Bulgarian Resurgence. Cleveland:
1987.
Oren, Nissan. Bulgarian Communism: The Road to Power,
1934-1944. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press, 1971.
------. Revolution Administered: Agrarianism and Communism in
Bulgaria. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1973.
Parker, John. "The Macedonian Problem Solved?" South Slav
Journal [London], 6, No. 4, Autumn 1983, 12-21.
Perl, Lila. Yugoslavia, Romania, Bulgaria. Camden: Thomas
Nelson, 1970.
Rusinov, Spas. Bulgaria: A Survey. Sofia: Sofia Press,
1969.
Sch�pflin, George (ed.). The Soviet Union and Eastern
Europe. New York: Praeger, 1970.
Staar, Richard F. Communist Regimes in Eastern Europe.
Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press, 1988.
The Stateman's Year-Book: 1990-1991. (Ed., John Paxton.)
St. Martin's Press, New York: 1990.
Wolff, Robert. The Balkans in Our Time. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1956.
CITATION: Federal Research Division of the Library of Congress. The Country Studies Series. Published 1988-1999.
Please note: This text comes from the Country Studies Program, formerly the Army Area Handbook Program. The Country Studies Series presents a description and analysis of the historical setting and the social, economic, political, and national security systems and institutions of countries throughout the world.
TRY USING CTRL-F on your keyboard to find the appropriate section of text