Thailand - Acknowledgments and Preface
Thailand
The editor and authors are grateful to numerous individuals in the
international community, in various agencies of the United States
government, and in private organizations who gave of their time,
research materials, and special knowledge to provide data and
perspective for this study.
The authors also wish to express their appreciation to staff members
of the Federal Research Division, Library of Congress, whose high
standards and dedication helped shape this volume. These include Martha
E. Hopkins, who managed editing and book production, as well as editing
portions of the text, Marilyn L. Majeska, who edited parts of the
manuscript and the accompanying figures and tables, and editorial
assistants Barbara Edgerton and Izella Watson. David P. Cabitto and
Kimberly A. Lord prepared the book's graphics, Susan M. Lender reviewed
the maps, and Arvies J. Staton contributed to the charts on military
rank and insignia.
The following individuals are gratefully acknowledged as well: Ruth
Nieland, Vincent Ercolano, and Mary Ann Saour for editing various
chapters; Catherine Schwartzstein for the final prepublication editorial
review; Shirley Kessell of Communicators Connection for preparing the
index; and Malinda B. Neale of the Printing and Processing Section,
Library of Congress, for phototypesetting, under the direction of Peggy
Pixley. Special thanks go to Teresa E. Kamp, who designed the
illustrations for the cover of the volume and the title pages of the
chapters. The inclusion of photographs in this book was made possible by
the generosity of various individuals and public and private agencies.
Finally, the editor and authors wish to thank Federal Research
Division staff members Mervin J. Shello and Ly H. Burnham for sharing
their expertise in telecommunications and demography; Tracy M. Henry for
her assistance in word processing; Meridel M. Jackson for her economic
insights and computer expertise; and Russell R. Ross, Robert L. Worden,
and Richard F. Nyrop for reviewing all parts of the book.
The Area Handbook for Thailand, first published in 1971, was
revised in 1981 as Thailand: A Country Study. This volume, a
revision of the 1981 edition, recounts developments in Thailand during
the 1980s, a period of relative political stability and respectable
economic growth. Recently Thailand's attention has focused increasingly
on regional concerns as, in concert with other members of the
Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN), it has attempted to deal
with the problem of the Vietnamese occupation of Cambodia.
Like its predecessors, this study is an attempt to present an
objective and concise account of the dominant social, economic,
political, and national security concerns of contemporary Thailand, as
well as to provide a historical framework for this overview. The 1981
edition, which this volume replaces, was prepared by a team composed of
Robert Rinehart, Irving Kaplan, Donald P. Whitaker, Rinn-Sup Shinn, and
Harold D. Nelson and led by Frederica M. Bunge.
The current Thailand: A Country Study results from the
combined efforts of a multidisciplinary team. The authors obtained
information from a variety of sources, including scholarly studies,
official reports of government and international organizations, and
foreign and domestic newspapers and periodicals. Full references
to these and other sources used by the authors are listed in the
Bibliography.
The authors have tried to limit the use of foreign and technical
terms, which are defined when they first appear in the study. Readers
are also referred to the Glossary at the back of the book. In general,
Thai personal names conform to the system of romanization followed by
the Library of Congress. Certain exceptions have been made, including
names of the monarchs of the Chakkri Dynasty and those of certain other
persons more familiar to Western readers in variant forms. Some
religious and social terms are given in Thai; others are in Sanskrit,
following usage in Webster's Third New International Dictionary
(unabridged edition), or in Pali, the language of Theravada Buddhist
scriptures. Contemporary place-names used in this study are those
approved by the United States Board on Geographic Names. All
measurements are given in the metric system.
Thailand
Thailand - History
Thailand
LITTLE IS KNOWN of the earliest inhabitants of what is now Thailand,
but 5,000-year-old archaeological sites in the northeastern part of the
country are believed to contain the oldest evidence of rice cultivation
and bronze casting in Asia and perhaps in the world. In early historical
times, a succession of tribal groups controlled what is now Thailand.
The Mon and Khmer peoples established powerful kingdoms that included
large areas of the country. They absorbed from contact with South Asian
peoples religious, social, political, and cultural ideas and
institutions that later influenced the development of Thailand's culture
and national identity.
The Tai, a people who originally lived in southwestern China,
migrated into mainland Southeast Asia over a period of many centuries.
The first mention of their existence in the region is a twelfth-century
A.D. inscription at the Khmer temple complex of Angkor Wat in Cambodia,
which refers to syam, or "dark brown" people (the
origin of the term Siam) as vassals of the Khmer monarch. In
1238 a Tai chieftain declared his independence from the Khmer and
established a kingdom at Sukhothai in the broad valley of the Mae Nam
(river) Chao Phraya, at the center of modern Thailand. Sukhothai was
succeeded in the fourteenth century by the kingdom of Ayutthaya. The
Burmese invaded Ayutthaya and in 1767 destroyed the capital, but two
national heroes, Taksin and Chakkri, soon expelled the invaders and
reunified the country under the Chakkri Dynasty.
Over the centuries Thai national identity evolved around a common
language and religion and the institution of the monarchy. Although the
inhabitants of Thailand are a mixture of Tai, Mon, Khmer, and other
ethnic groups, most speak a language of the Tai family. A Tai language
alphabet, based on Indian and Khmer scripts, developed early in the
fourteenth century. Later in the century a famous monarch, Ramathibodi,
made Theravada Buddhism the official religion of his kingdom, and
Buddhism continued into the twentieth century as a dominant factor in
the nation's social, cultural, and political life. Finally, the
monarchy, buttressed ideologically by Hindu and Buddhist mythology, was
a focus for popular loyalties for more than seven centuries. In the late
twentieth century the monarchy remained central to national unity.
During the nineteenth century, European expansionism, rather than
Thailand's traditional enemies, posed the greatest threat to the
kingdom's survival. Thai success in preserving the country's
independence (it was the only Southeast Asian country to do so) was in
part a result of the desire of Britain and France for a stable buffer
state separating their dominions in Burma, Malaya, and Indochina. More
important, however, was the willingness of Thailand's monarchs, Mongkut
(Rama IV, 1851-68) and Chulalongkorn (Rama V, 1868-1910), to negotiate
openly with the European powers and to adopt European-style reforms that
modernized the country and won it sovereign status among the world's
nations. Thailand (then known as Siam) paid a high price for its
independence, however: loss of suzerainty over Cambodia and Laos to
France and cession of the northern states of the Malay Peninsula to
Britain. By 1910 the area under Thai control was a fraction of what it
had been a century earlier.
In the early decades of the twentieth century, Thailand's political
system, armed forces, schools, and economy underwent drastic changes.
Many Thai studied overseas, and a small, Western-educated elite with
less traditional ideas emerged. In 1932 a bloodless coup d'etat by
military officers and civil servants ended the absolute monarchy and
inaugurated Thailand's constitutional era. Progress toward a stable,
democratic political system since that time, however, has been erratic.
Politics has been dominated by rival military-bureaucratic cliques
headed by powerful generals. These cliques have initiated repeated coups
d'etat and have imposed prolonged periods of martial law. Parliamentary
institutions, as defined by Thailand's fourteen constitutions between
1932 and 1987, and competition among civilian politicians have generally
been facades for military governments.
History Contents
<"3.htm">EARLY HISTORY
<"4.htm">The Mon and the Khmer
<"5.htm">The Tai People:
Origins and Migrations
<"6.htm">Sukhothai
<"7.htm">THE AYUTTHAYA ERA,
1350-1767
<"8.htm">Thai Kingship
<"9.htm">Social and Political
Development
<"10.htm">Economic Development
<"11.htm">Contacts with the
West
<"12.htm">Ayutthaya: The Final
Phase
<"13.htm">THE BANGKOK PERIOD,
1767-1932
<"14.htm">The Chakkri Dynasty
<"15.htm">Mongkut's Opening to
the West
<"16.htm">Chulalongkorn's
Reforms
<"17.htm">The Crisis of 1893
<"18.htm">BEGINNING OF THE
CONSTITUTIONAL ERA
<"19.htm">1932 Coup
<"20.htm">Phibun and the
Nationalist Regime
<"21.htm">World War II
<"22.htm">Pridi and the
Civilian Regime, 1944-47
<"23.htm">RETURN OF PHIBUN AND
THE MILITARY
<"24.htm">November 1947 Coup
<"25.htm">November 1951 Coup
<"26.htm">Phibun's Experiment
with "Democracy"
<"27.htm">SARIT AND THANOM
<"28.htm">Sarit's Return
<"29.htm">Thai Politics and
Foreign Policy, 1963-71
<"30.htm">November 1971 Coup
<"31.htm">End of Thanom Regime
<"32.htm">MILITARY RULE AND A
LIMITED DEMOCRACY
<"31.htm">Prem in Power
<"34.htm">Foreign Relations,
1977-83
Thailand
Thailand - EARLY HISTORY
Thailand
Over the course of millennia, migrations from southern China peopled
Southeast Asia, including the area of contemporary Thailand.
Archaeological evidence indicates a thriving Paleolithic culture in the
region and continuous human habitation for at least 20,000 years.
The pace of economic and social development was uneven and
conditioned by climate and geography. The dense forests of the Chao
Phraya Valley in the central part of Thailand and the Malay Peninsula in
the south produced such an abundance of food that for a long time there
was no need to move beyond a hunting-and- gathering economy. In
contrast, rice cultivation appeared early in the highlands of the far
north and hastened the development of a more communal social and
political organization.
Excavations at Ban Chiang, a small village on the Khorat Plateau in
northeastern Thailand, have revealed evidence of prehistoric inhabitants
who may have forged bronze implements as early as 3000 B.C. and
cultivated rice around the fourth millennium B.C. If so, the Khorat
Plateau would be the oldest rice-producing area in Asia because the
inhabitants of China at that time still consumed millet. Archaeologists
have assembled evidence that the bronze implements found at the Thai
sites were forged in the area and not transported from elsewhere. They
supported this claim by pointing out that both copper and tin deposits
(components of bronze) are found in close proximity to the Ban Chiang
sites. If these claims are correct, Thai bronze forgers would have
predated the "Bronze Age," which archaeologists had
traditionally believed began in the Middle East around 2800 B.C. and in
China about a thousand years later.
Before the end of the first millennium B.C., tribal territories had
begun to coalesce into protohistorical kingdoms whose names survive in
Chinese dynastic annals of the period. Funan, a state of substantial
proportions, emerged in the second century B.C. as the earliest and most
significant power in Southeast Asia. Its Hindu ruling class controlled all of present-day Cambodia
and extended its power to the center of modern Thailand. The Funan
economy was based on maritime trade and a well-developed agricultural
system; Funan maintained close commercial contact with India and served
as a base for the Brahman merchant-missionaries who brought Hindu
culture to Southeast Asia.
On the narrow isthmus to the southwest of Funan, Malay citystates
controlled the portage routes that were traversed by traders and
travelers journeying between India and Indochina. By the tenth century
A.D. the strongest of them, Tambralinga (present-day Nakhon Si
Thammarat), had gained control of all routes across the isthmus. Along
with other city-states on the Malay Peninsula and Sumatra, it had become
part of the Srivijaya Empire, a maritime confederation that between the
seventh and thirteenth centuries dominated trade on the South China Sea
and exacted tolls from all traffic through the Strait of Malacca.
Tambralinga adopted Buddhism, but farther south many of the Malay
city-states converted to Islam, and by the fifteenth century an enduring
religious boundary had been established on the isthmus between Buddhist
mainland Southeast Asia and Muslim Malaya.
Although the Thai conquered the states of the isthmus in the
thirteenth century and continued to control them in the modern period,
the Malay of the peninsula were never culturally absorbed into the
mainstream of Thai society. The differences in religion, language, and
ethnic origin caused strains in social and political relations between
the central government and the southern provinces into the late
twentieth century.
Thailand
Thailand - The Mon and the Khmer
Thailand
The closely related Mon and Khmer peoples entered Southeast Asia
along migration routes from southern China in the ninth century B.C. The
Khmer settled in the Mekong River Valley, while the Mon occupied the
central plain and northern highlands of modern Thailand and large parts
of Burma. Taking advantage of Funan's decline in the sixth century A.D.,
the Mon began to establish independent kingdoms, among them Dvaravati in
the northern part of the area formerly controlled by Funan and farther
north at Haripunjaya. Meanwhile the Khmer laid the foundation for their
great empire of the ninth to fifteenth centuries A.D. This empire would
be centered at Angkor (near modern Siem Reap) in Cambodia.
The Mon were receptive to the art and literature of India, and for
centuries they were the agents for diffusing Hindu cultural values in
the region. The frequent occurrence of Sanskrit place-names in modern
Thailand is one result of the long and pervasive Indian influence.
In the eighth century, missionaries from Ceylon (present-day Sri
Lanka) introduced the Mon to Theravada Buddhism. The Mon embraced
Buddhism enthusiastically and conveyed it to the Khmer and the Malay of
Tambralinga. The two Indian religious systems--Hindu and
Buddhist--existed side by side without conflict. Hinduism continued to
provide the cultural setting in which Buddhist religious values and
ethical standards were articulated. Although Buddhism was the official
religion of the Mon and the Khmer, in popular practice it incorporated
many local cults.
In spite of cultural dominance in the region, the Mon were repeatedly
subdued by their Burmese and Khmer neighbors. In the tenth century
Dvaravati and the whole of the Chao Phraya Valley came under the control
of Angkor. The Khmer maintained the HinduBuddhist culture received from
the Mon but placed added emphasis on the Hindu concept of sacred
kingship. The history of Angkor can be read in the magnificent
structures built to glorify its monarchy. Ultimately, however, obsession
with palaces and temples led the Khmer rulers to divert too much
manpower to their construction and to neglect the elaborate agricultural
system-- part of Angkor's heritage from Funan--that was the empire's
most important economic asset.
Thailand
Thailand - The Tai People: Origins and Migrations
Thailand
The forebears of the modern Thai were Tai-speaking people living
south of the Chang Jiang (Yangtze River) on the mountainous plateau of
what is now the Chinese province of Yunnan. Early Chinese records (the
first recorded Chinese reference to the Tai is dated sixth century B.C.)
document the Tai cultivating wetland rice in valley and lowland areas.
During the first millennium A.D., before the emergence of formal states
governed by Taispeaking elites, these people lived in scattered villages
drawn together into muang, or principalities. Each muang
was governed by a chao, or lord, who ruled by virtue of
personal qualities and a network of patron-client relationships. Often
the constituent villages of a muang would band together to
defend their lands from more powerful neighboring peoples, such as the
Chinese and Vietnamese.
The state of Nanchao played a key role in Tai development. In the
mid-seventh century A.D., the Chinese Tang Dynasty, threatened by
powerful western neighbors like Tibet, sought to secure its southwestern
borders by fostering the growth of a friendly state formed by the people
they called man (southern barbarians) in the Yunnan region.
This state was known as Nanchao. Originally an ally, Nanchao became a
powerful foe of the Chinese in subsequent centuries and extended its
domain into what is now Burma and northern Vietnam. In 1253 the armies
of Kublai Khan conquered Nanchao and incorporated it into the Yuan
(Mongol) Chinese empire.
Nanchao's significance for the Tai people was twofold. First, it
blocked Chinese influence from the north for many centuries. Had Nanchao
not existed, the Tai, like most of the originally non-Chinese peoples
south of the Chang Jiang, might have been completely assimilated into
the Chinese cultural sphere. Second, Nanchao stimulated Tai migration
and expansion. Over several centuries, bands of Tai from Yunnan moved
steadily into Southeast Asia, and by the thirteenth century they had
reached as far west as Assam (in present-day India). Once settled, they
became identified in Burma as the Shan and in the upper Mekong region as
the Lao. In Tonkin and Annam, the northern and central portions of
present-day Vietnam, the Tai formed distinct tribal groupings: Tai Dam
(Black Tai), Tai Deng (Red Tai), Tai Khao (White Tai), and Nung.
However, most of the Tai settled on the northern and western fringes of
the Khmer Empire.
The Thai have traditionally regarded the founding of the kingdom of
Sukhothai as marking their emergence as a distinct nation. Tradition
sets 1238 as the date when Tai chieftains overthrew the Khmer at
Sukhothai, capital of Angkor's outlying northwestern province, and
established a Tai kingdom. A flood of migration resulting from Kublai
Khan's conquest of Nanchao furthered the consolidation of independent
Tai states. Tai warriors, fleeing the Mongol invaders, reinforced
Sukhothai against the Khmer, ensuring its supremacy in the central
plain. In the north, other Tai war parties conquered the old Mon state
of Haripunjaya and in 1296 founded the kingdom of Lan Na with its
capital at Chiang Mai.
Thailand
Thailand - Sukhothai
Thailand
Situated on the banks of the Mae Nam Yom some 375 kilometers north of
present-day Bangkok, Sukhothai was the cradle of Thai civilization, the
place where its institutions and culture first developed. Indeed, it was
there in the late thirteenth century that the people of the central
plain, lately freed from Khmer rule, took the name Thai,
meaning "free," to set themselves apart from other Tai
speakers still under foreign rule.
The first ruler of Sukhothai for whom historical records survive was
Ramkhamhaeng (Rama the Great, 1277-1317). He was a famous warrior who
claimed to be "sovereign lord of all the Tai" and financed his
court with war booty and tribute from vassal states in Burma, Laos, and
the Malay Peninsula. During his reign, the Thai established diplomatic
relations with China and acknowledged the Chinese emperor as nominal
overlord of the Thai kingdom. Ramkhamhaeng brought Chinese artisans to
Sukhothai to develop the ceramics industry that was a mainstay of the
Thai economy for 500 years. He also devised the Thai alphabet by
adapting a Khmer script derived from the Indian Devanagari script.
Sukhothai declined rapidly after Ramkhamhaeng's death, as vassal
states broke away from the suzerainty of his weak successors. Despite
the reputation of its later kings for wisdom and piety, the politically
weakened Sukhothai was forced to submit in 1378 to the Thai kingdom of
Ayutthaya.
Thailand
Thailand - THE AYUTTHAYA ERA, 1350-1767
Thailand
The kingdom of Ayutthaya was founded by U Thong, an adventurer
allegedly descended from a rich Chinese merchant family who married
royalty. In 1350, to escape the threat of an epidemic, he moved his
court south into the rich floodplain of the Chao Phraya. On an island in
the river he founded a new capital, which he called Ayutthaya, after
Ayodhya in northern India, the city of the hero Rama in the Hindu epic Ramayana.
U Thong assumed the royal name of Ramathibodi (1350-60).
Ramathibodi tried to unify his kingdom. In 1360 he declared Theravada
Buddhism the official religion of Ayutthaya and brought members of a sangha,
a Buddhist monastic community, from Ceylon to establish new religious
orders and spread the faith among his subjects. He also compiled a legal
code, based on the Indian Dharmashastra (a Hindu legal text)
and Thai custom, which became the basis of royal legislation. Composed
in Pali--an Indo-Aryan language closely related to Sanskrit and the
language of the Theravada Buddhist scriptures--it had the force of
divine injunction. Supplemented by royal decrees, Ramathibodi's legal
code remained generally in force until the late nineteenth century.
By the end of the fourteenth century, Ayutthaya was regarded as the
strongest power in Southeast Asia, but it lacked the manpower to
dominate the region. In the last year of his reign, Ramathibodi had
seized Angkor during what was to be the first of many successful Thai
assaults on the Khmer capital. Thai policy was aimed at securing
Ayutthaya's eastern frontier by preempting Vietnamese designs on Khmer
territory. The weakened Khmer periodically submitted to Thai suzerainty,
but efforts by Ayutthaya to maintain control over Angkor were repeatedly
frustrated. Thai troops were frequently diverted to suppress rebellions
in Sukhothai or to campaign against Chiang Mai, where Ayutthaya's
expansion was tenaciously resisted. Eventually Ayutthaya subdued the
territory that had belonged to Sukhothai, and the year after Ramathibodi
died, his kingdom was recognized by the emperor of China's newly
established Ming Dynasty as Sukhothai's rightful successor.
The Thai kingdom was not a single, unified state but rather a
patchwork of self-governing principalities and tributary provinces owing
allegiance to the king of Ayutthaya. These states were ruled by members
of the royal family of Ayutthaya who had their own armies and warred
among themselves. The king had to be vigilant to prevent royal princes
from combining against him or allying with Ayutthaya's enemies. Whenever
the succession was in dispute, princely governors gathered their forces
and moved on the capital to press their claims.
During much of the fifteenth century Ayutthaya's energies were
directed toward the Malay Peninsula, where the great trading port of
Malacca contested Thai claims to sovereignty. Malacca and other Malay
states south of Tambralinga had become Muslim early in the century, and
thereafter Islam served as a symbol of Malay solidarity against the
Thai. Although the Thai failed to make a vassal state of Malacca,
Ayutthaya continued to control the lucrative trade on the isthmus, which
attracted Chinese traders of specialty goods for the luxury markets of
China.
Thailand
Thailand - Thai Kingship
Thailand
Thai rulers were absolute monarchs whose office was partly religious
in nature. They derived their authority from the ideal qualities they
were believed to possess. The king was the moral model, who personified
the virtue of his people, and his country lived at peace and prospered
because of his meritorious actions. At Sukhothai, where Ramkhamhaeng was
said to hear the petition of any subject who rang the bell at the palace
gate to summon him, the king was revered as a father by his people. But
the paternal aspects of kingship disappeared at Ayutthaya, where, under
Khmer influence, the monarchy withdrew behind a wall of taboos and
rituals. The king was considered chakkraphat, the Sanskrit-Pali
term for the "wheel-rolling" universal prince who through his
adherence to the law made all the world revolve around him. As the Hindu
god Shiva was "lord of the universe," the Thai king also
became by analogy "lord of the land," distinguished in his
appearance and bearing from his subjects. According to the elaborate
court etiquette, even a special language, Phasa Ratchasap, was used to
communicate with or about royalty.
As devaraja (Sanskrit for "divine king"), the king
ultimately came to be recognized as the earthly incarnation of Shiva and
became the object of a politico-religious cult officiated over by a
corps of royal Brahmans who were part of the Buddhist court retinue. In
the Buddhist context, the devaraja was a bodhisattva (an
enlightened being who, out of compassion, foregoes nirvana in order to
aid others). The belief in divine kingship prevailed into the eighteenth
century, although by that time its religious implications had limited
impact.
One of the numerous institutional innovations of King Trailok
(1448-88) was to create the position of uparaja, or heir
apparent, usually held by the king's senior son or full brother, in an
attempt to regularize the succession to the throne--a particularly
difficult feat for a polygamous dynasty. In practice, there was inherent
conflict between king and uparaja and frequent disputed
successions.
Thailand
Thailand - Social and Political Development
Thailand
The king stood at the apex of a highly stratified social and
political hierarchy that extended throughout the society. In Ayutthayan
society the basic unit of social organization was the village community
composed of extended family households. Generally the elected headmen
provided leadership for communal projects. Title to land resided with
the headman, who held it in the name of the community, although peasant
proprietors enjoyed the use of land as long as they cultivated it.
With ample reserves of land available for cultivation, the viability
of the state depended on the acquisition and control of adequate
manpower for farm labor and defense. The dramatic rise of Ayutthaya had
entailed constant warfare and, as none of the parties in the region
possessed a technological advantage, the outcome of battles was usually
determined by the size of the armies. After each victorious campaign,
Ayutthaya carried away a number of conquered people to its own
territory, where they were assimilated and added to the labor force.
Every freeman had to be registered as a servant, or phrai, with the local lord, or
nai, for military service and corvee labor on public works
and on the land of the official to whom he was assigned. The phrai
could also meet his labor obligation by paying a tax. If he found the
forced labor under his nai repugnant, he could sell himself
into slavery to a more attractive nai, who then paid a fee to
the government in compensation for the loss of corvee labor. As much as
one-third of the manpower supply into the nineteenth century was
composed of phrai.
Wealth, status, and political influence were interrelated. The king
allotted rice fields to governors, military commanders, and court
officials in payment for their services to the crown, according to the sakdi
na system. The size of each official's allotment
was determined by the number of persons he could command to work it. The
amount of manpower a particular nai could command determined
his status relative to others in the hierarchy and his wealth. At the
apex of the hierarchy, the king, who was the realm's largest landholder,
also commanded the services of the largest number of phrai,
called phrai luang (royal servants), who paid taxes, served in
the royal army, and worked on the crown lands. King Trailok established
definite allotments of land and phrai for the royal officials
at each rung in the hierarchy, thus determining the country's social
structure until the introduction of salaries for government officials in
the nineteenth century.
The Chinese alone stood outside this social structure. They were not
obliged to register for corvee duty, so they were free to move about the
kingdom at will and engage in commerce. By the sixteenth century, the
Chinese controlled Ayutthaya's internal trade and had found important
places in the civil and military service. Most of these men took Thai
wives because few women left China to accompany the men.
The sixteenth century witnessed the rise of Burma, which, under an
aggressive dynasty, had overrun Chiang Mai and Laos and made war on the
Thai. In 1569 Burmese forces, joined by Thai rebels, captured the city
of Ayutthaya and carried off the royal family to Burma. Dhammaraja
(1569-90), a Thai governor who had aided the Burmese, was installed as
vassal king at Ayutthaya. Thai independence was restored by his son,
King Naresuan (1590- 1605), who turned on the Burmese and by 1600 had
driven them from the country.
Determined to prevent another treason like his father's, Naresuan set
about unifying the country's administration directly under the royal
court at Ayutthaya. He ended the practice of nominating royal princes to
govern Ayutthaya's provinces, assigning instead court officials who were
expected to execute policies handed down by the king. Thereafter royal
princes were confined to the capital. Their power struggles continued,
but at court under the king's watchful eye.
In order to ensure his control over the new class of governors,
Naresuan decreed that all freemen subject to phrai service had
become phrai luang, bound directly to the king, who distributed
the use of their services to his officials. This measure gave the king a
theoretical monopoly on all manpower, and the idea developed that since
the king owned the services of all the people, he also possessed all the
land. Ministerial offices and governorships--and the sakdi na
that went with them--were usually inherited positions dominated by a few
families often connected to the king by marriage. Indeed, marriage was
frequently used by Thai kings to cement alliances between themselves and
powerful families, a custom prevailing through the nineteenth century.
As a result of this policy, the king's wives usually numbered in the
dozens.
Even with Naresuan's reforms, the effectiveness of the royal
government over the next 150 years should not be overestimated. Royal
power outside the crown lands--although in theory absolute- -was in
practice limited by the looseness of the civil administration. The
influence of central government ministers was not extensive beyond the
capital until the late nineteenth century.
Thailand
Thailand - Economic Development
Thailand
The Thai never lacked a rich food supply. Peasants planted rice for
their own consumption and to pay taxes. Whatever remained was used to
support religious institutions. From the thirteenth to the fifteenth
century, however, a remarkable transformation took place in Thai rice
cultivation. In the highlands, where rainfall had to be supplemented by
a system of irrigation that controlled the water level in flooded
paddies, the Thai sowed the glutinous rice that is still the staple in
the geographical regions of the North and Northeast. But in the
floodplain of the Chao Phraya, farmers turned to a different variety of
rice--the so-called floating rice, a slender, nonglutinous grain
introduced from Bengal--that would grow fast enough to keep pace with
the rise of the water level in the lowland fields.
The new strain grew easily and abundantly, producing a surplus that
could be sold cheaply abroad. Ayutthaya, situated at the southern
extremity of the floodplain, thus became the hub of economic activity.
Under royal patronage, corvee labor dug canals on which rice was brought
from the fields to the king's ships for export to China. In the process,
the Chao Phraya Delta--mud flats between the sea and firm land hitherto
considered unsuitable for habitation--was reclaimed and placed under
cultivation.
Thailand
Thailand - Contacts with the West
Thailand
In 1511 Ayutthaya received a diplomatic mission from the Portuguese,
who earlier that year had conquered Malacca. These were probably the
first Europeans to visit the country. Five years after that initial
contact, Ayutthaya and Portugal concluded a treaty granting the
Portuguese permission to trade in the kingdom. A similar treaty in 1592
gave the Dutch a privileged position in the rice trade.
Foreigners were cordially welcomed at the court of Narai (1657-88), a
ruler with a cosmopolitan outlook who was nonetheless wary of outside
influence. Important commercial ties were forged with Japan. Dutch and
English trading companies were allowed to establish factories, and Thai
diplomatic missions were sent to Paris and The Hague. By maintaining all
these ties, the Thai court skillfully played off the Dutch against the
English and the French against the Dutch in order to avoid the excessive
influence of a single power.
In 1664, however, the Dutch used force to exact a treaty granting
them extraterritorial rights as well as freer access to trade. At the
urging of his foreign minister, the Greek adventurer Constantine
Phaulkon, Narai turned to France for assistance. French engineers
constructed fortifications for the Thai and built a new palace at Lop
Buri for Narai. In addition, French missionaries engaged in education
and medicine and brought the first printing press into the country.
Louis XIV's personal interest was aroused by reports from missionaries
suggesting that Narai might be converted to Christianity.
The French presence encouraged by Phaulkon, however, stirred the
resentment and suspicions of the Thai nobles and Buddhist clergy. When
word spread that Narai was dying, a general, Phra Phetracha, killed the
designated heir, a Christian, and had Phaulkon put to death along with a
number of missionaries. The arrival of English warships provoked a
massacre of more Europeans. Phetracha (reigned 1688-93) seized the
throne, expelled the remaining foreigners, and ushered in a 150-year
period during which the Thai consciously isolated themselves from
contacts with the West.
Thailand
Thailand - Ayutthaya: The Final Phase
Thailand
After a bloody period of dynastic struggle, Ayutthaya entered into
what has been called its golden age, a relatively peaceful episode in
the second quarter of the eighteenth century when art, literature, and
learning flourished. Ayutthaya continued to compete with Vietnam for
control of Cambodia, but a greater threat came from Burma, where a new
dynasty had subdued the Shan states.
In 1765 Thai territory was invaded by three Burmese armies that
converged on Ayutthaya. After a lengthy siege, the city capitulated and
was burned in 1767. Ayutthaya's art treasures, the libraries containing
its literature, and the archives housing its historic records were
almost totally destroyed, and the city was left in ruins.
The country was reduced to chaos. Provinces were proclaimed
independent states under military leaders, rogue monks, and cadet
members of the royal family. The Thai were saved from Burmese
subjugation, however, by an opportune Chinese invasion of Burma and by
the leadership of a Thai military commander, Phraya Taksin.
Thailand
Thailand - THE BANGKOK PERIOD, 1767-1932
Thailand
As they had in the sixteenth century, the Thai made a rapid recovery
under a brilliant military leader. Taksin (1767-82) had slipped away
from besieged Ayutthaya and, starting with a handful of followers who
quickly grew into an army, organized a resistance to the Burmese
invaders, driving them out after a long and arduous war. Assuming the
royal title, he abandoned the ruined Ayutthaya and founded a new capital
farther south in the delta at Thon Buri, a fortress town across the
river from modern <"http://worldfacts.us/Thailand-Bangkok.htm">Bangkok. By 1776 Taksin had reunited the Thai kingdom,
which had fragmented into small states after the fall of the old
capital, and had annexed Chiang Mai. Taksin, who eventually developed
delusions of his own divinity, was deposed and executed by his
ministers, invoking the interests of the state. His manifold
accomplishments, however, won Taksin a secure place among Thailand's
national heroes.
Thailand
Thailand - The Chakkri Dynasty
Thailand
With the death of Taksin, the Thai throne fell to Chakkri, a general
who had played a leading role with Taksin in the struggle against the
Burmese. As King Yot Fa (Rama I, 1782-1809), he founded the present Thai
ruling house and moved the court to Bangkok, the modern capital. During an energetic reign, he revived the country's
economy and restored what remained of the great artistic heritage lost
in the destruction of Ayutthaya. The king is credited with composing a
new edition of the Ramakian (the Thai version of the Ramayana)
to replace manuscripts of the Thai national epic that were lost in the
conflagration.
In the following years Thai influence grew until challenged by
Western powers. In 1795 the Thai seized the provinces of Battambang and
Siem Reap in Cambodia, where throughout the first half of the next
century Chakkri kings would resist Vietnamese incursions. The conflict
between the Thai and the Vietnamese was resolved finally by a compromise
providing for the establishment of a joint protectorate over Cambodia.
The Thai also pressed their claim to suzerainty in the Malay state of
Kedah in the face of growing British interest in the peninsula. As a
result of the Anglo-Burmese War (1824-26), Britain annexed territory in
the region that had been contested by the Thai and the Burmese for
centuries. This move led to the signing of the Burney Treaty in 1826, an
Anglo-Thai agreement that allowed British merchants modest trade
concessions in the kingdom. In 1833 the Thai reached a similar
understanding with the United States.
Chakkri expansionism had been halted in all directions by the end of
the reign of Nang Klao (Rama III, 1824-51) as tributary provinces began
to slip away from Bangkok's control and Western influence grew. In 1850
Nang Klao spurned British and American requests for more generous
trading privileges similar to those that Western powers had exacted by
force from China. Succeeding Thai monarchs, however, were less
successful in controlling Western economic influence in their country.
The first three Chakkri kings, by succeeding each other without
bloodshed, had brought the kingdom a degree of political stability that
had been lacking in the Ayutthaya period. There was, however, no rule
providing for automatic succession to the throne. If there was no uparaja
at the time of the king's death--and this was frequently the case--the
choice of a new monarch drawn from the royal family was left to the
Senabodi, the council of senior officials, princes, and Buddhist
prelates that assembled at the death of a king. It was such a council
that chose Nang Klao's successor.
Thailand
Thailand - Mongkut's Opening to the West
Thailand
Nang Klao died in 1851 and was succeeded by his forty-seven- year-old
half brother, Mongkut (Rama IV, 1851-68). Mongkut's father, Loet La
(Rama II, 1809-24), had placed him in a Buddhist monastery in 1824 to
prevent a bloody succession struggle between factions loyal to Mongkut
and those supporting Nang Klao (although Nang Klao was older than
Mongkut, his mother was a concubine, whereas Mongkut's mother was a
royal queen). As a Buddhist monk, Mongkut won distinction as an
authority on the Pali Buddhist scriptures and became head of a reformed
order of the Siamese sangha. Thai Buddhism had become heavily
overlain with superstitions through the centuries, and Mongkut attempted
to purge the religion of these accretions and restore to it the spirit
of Buddha's original teachings.
Mongkut's twenty-seven years as a Buddhist monk not only made him a
religious figure of some consequence but also exposed him to a wide
array of foreign influences. Blessed with an inquiring mind and great
curiosity about the outside world, he cultivated contacts with French
Roman Catholic and United States Protestant missionaries. He studied
Western languages (Latin and English), science, and mathematics. His
lengthy conversations with the missionaries gave him a broad perspective
that greatly influenced his policies when he became king in 1851. He was
more knowledgeable of, and at ease with, Western ways than any previous
Thai monarch.
Mongkut was convinced that his realm must have full relations with
the Western countries in order to survive as an independent nation and
avoid the humiliations China and Burma had suffered in wars with
Britain. Against the advice of his court, he abolished the old royal
trade monopoly in commodities and in 1855 signed the Treaty of
Friendship and Commerce with Britain. (This treaty, commonly known as
the Bowring Treaty, was signed on Britain's behalf by Sir John Bowring,
governor of Hong Kong.) Under the terms of the treaty, British merchants
were permitted to buy and sell in Siam without intermediaries, a
consulate was established, and British subjects were granted
extraterritorial rights. Similar treaties were negotiated the next year
with the United States and France, and over the next fifteen years with
a number of other European countries. These agreements not only provided
for free trade but also limited the Siamese government's authority to
tax foreign enterprises. The elimination of these barriers led to an
enormous increase in commerce with the West. This expansion of trade in
turn revolutionized the Thai economy and connected it to the world
monetary system.
The demand for extraterritorial privileges also convinced the king
that unless Siam's legal and administrative systems were reformed, the
country would never be treated as an equal by the Western powers.
Although little in the way of substantive modernization was accomplished
during his reign, Mongkut eliminated some of the ancient mystique of the
monarch's divinity by allowing commoners to gaze on his face, published
a royal gazette of the country's laws, and hired a number of Western
experts as consultants, teachers, and technicians. Long-standing
institutions such as slavery remained basically untouched, however, and
the political system continued to be dominated by the great families.
Conservatives at court remained strong, and the king's death from
malaria in 1868 postponed pending reform projects.
Thailand
Thailand - Chulalongkorn's Reforms
Thailand
When Mongkut died, his eldest son, Chulalongkorn (Rama V, 1868-1910),
a minor at the time, succeeded him. Under his father's direction,
Chulalongkorn had received a thorough education by European tutors.
During the regency that preceded his coming of age, the young king
visited Java and India in order to witness European colonial
administration. Thus he was the first Chakkri monarch to leave the
country. At his coronation in 1873, he announced the abolition of the
ancient practice of prostrating before the monarch, which he regarded as
unsuitable for a modern nation. A number of reform decrees followed,
designed to modernize the judiciary, state finances, and political
structure. The reforms, however, provoked a revolt by conservatives
under Prince Wichaichan in December 1874. Although the revolt was
suppressed, it obliged Chulalongkorn to abandon "radicalism"
and proceed more carefully with reforms. It was more than a decade
before the king and his associates were in a position to enact more
significant changes.
One of the most far-reaching of the later reforms was the abolition
of slavery and the phrai corvee. Slavery was eliminated
gradually, allowing considerable time for social and economic
adaptation, and only disappeared in 1905. As a result of the
introduction of a head tax paid in currency and a regular army manned by
conscription, the corvee lost most of its function, and wage labor,
often provided by Chinese immigrants, proved more efficient for public
works projects. Likewise, the introduction of salaries for public
officials eliminated the need for the sakdi na. These reforms
wrought profound changes in Thai society.
In 1887 the king asked one of his princes, Devawongse, to initiate a
study of European forms of government and how European institutions
might be fruitfully adopted. The following year, the prince returned
with a proposal for a cabinet government consisting of twelve
functionally differentiated ministries. The king approved the plan,
though several years passed before it could be fully implemented. In
1893 Prince Damrong Rajanubhab, acting as minister of interior, began an
overhaul of Siam's antiquated provincial administration. The old
semifeudal system in the outer provinces was gradually replaced by a
centralized state administration. Under Damrong, the Ministry of
Interior became immensely powerful and played a central role in national
unification.
Like his father, Chulalongkorn fully appreciated the importance of
education. He founded three schools on European lines for children of
the royal family and government officials, including one for girls.
Specialized schools were attached to government departments for the
training of civil servants. Study abroad was encouraged, and promising
civil servants and military officers were sent to Europe for further
education. In 1891 Prince Damrong went to Europe to study modern systems
of education. Upon his return he became head of the new Ministry of
Public Instruction, though he was obliged to assume the Ministry of
Interior post a year later.
The country's first railroads were built during Chulalongkorn's
reign, and a line was completed between Bangkok and Ayutthaya in 1897.
This was extended farther north to Lop Buri in 1901 and to Sawankhalok
in 1909. A rail line built south to Phetchaburi by 1903 was eventually
linked with British rail lines in peninsular Malaya.
Thailand
Thailand - The Crisis of 1893
Thailand
The steady encroachment of the two most aggressive European powers in
the region, Britain and France, gravely threatened Siam during the last
years of the nineteenth century. To the west, Britain completed its
conquest of Burma in 1885 with the annexation of Upper Burma and the
involuntary abdication of Burma's last king, Thibaw. To the south, the
British were firmly established in the major Muslim states of the Malay
Peninsula.
Even more than Britain, France posed a serious danger to Siamese
independence. The French occupied Cochinchina (southern Vietnam, around
the Mekong Delta) in 1863. From there they extended their influence into
Cambodia, over which Vietnam and Siam had long been struggling for
control. Assuming Vietnam's traditional interests, France obliged the
Cambodian king, Norodom, to accept a French protectorate. Siam formally
relinquished its claim to Cambodia four years later, in return for
French recognition of Siamese sovereignty over the Cambodian provinces
of Siem Reap and Battambang.
The French dreamed of outflanking their British rivals by developing
a trade route to the supposed riches of southwestern China through the
Mekong Valley. This seemed possible once France had assumed complete
control over Vietnam in the 1880s. The small Laotian kingdoms, under
Siamese suzerainty, were the keys to this dream. The French claimed
these territories, arguing that areas previously under Vietnamese
control should now come under the French, the new rulers of Vietnam.
Auguste Pavie, French vice consul in Luang Prabang in 1886, was the
chief agent in furthering French interests in Laos. His intrigues, which
took advantage of Siamese weakness in the region and periodic invasions
by Chinese rebels from Yunnan Province, increased tensions between
Bangkok and Paris. When fighting broke out between French and Siamese
forces in Laos in April 1893, the French sent gunboats to blockade
Bangkok. At gunpoint, the Siamese agreed to the cession of Laos.
Britain's acquiescence in French expansionism was evident in a treaty
signed by the two countries in 1896 recognizing a border between French
territory in Laos and British territory in Upper Burma.
French pressure on Siam continued, however, and in 1907 Chulalongkorn
was forced to surrender Battambang and Siem Reap to French-occupied
Cambodia. Two years later, Siam relinquished its claims to the northern
Malay states of Kelantan, Trengganu, Kedah, and Perlis to the British in
exchange for legal jurisdiction over British subjects on its soil and a
large loan for railroad construction. In terms of territory under its
control, Siam was now much diminished. Its independence, however, had
been preserved as a useful and generally stable buffer state between
French and British territories.
Chulalongkorn's son and successor, Vajiravudh (Rama VI, 1910- 25),
had received his education in Britain. As much as the theme of
modernization had typified the policies of his father, Vajiravudh's
reign was characterized by support of nationalism. The king wrote
extensively on nationalist themes. He also organized and financed a
military auxiliary, the Wild Tiger Corps, which he looked on as a means
of spreading nationalist fervor.
Thai nationalist attitudes at all levels of society were colored by
anti-Chinese sentiment. For centuries members of the Chinese community
had dominated domestic commerce and had been employed as agents for the
royal trade monopoly. With the rise of European economic influence many
Chinese entrepreneurs had shifted to opium traffic and tax collecting,
both despised occupations. In addition, Chinese millers and middlemen in
the rice trade were blamed for the economic recession that gripped Siam
for nearly a decade after 1905. Accusations of bribery of high
officials, wars between the Chinese secret societies, and use of
oppressive practices to extract taxes also served to inflame Thai
opinion against the Chinese community at a time when it was expanding
rapidly as a result of increased immigration from China. By 1910 nearly
10 percent of Thailand's population was Chinese. Whereas earlier
immigrants had intermarried with the Thai, the new arrivals frequently
came with families and resisted assimilation into Thai society. Chinese
nationalism, encouraged by Sun Yat-sen, the leader of the Chinese
revolution, had also begun to develop, parallel with Thai nationalism.
The Chinese community even supported a separate school system for its
children. Legislation in 1909 requiring adoption of surnames was in
large part directed against the Chinese community, whose members would
be faced with the choice of forsaking their Chinese identity or
accepting the status of foreigners. Many of them made the accommodation
and opted to become Thai--if in name only. Those who did not became even
more alienated from the rest of Thai society.
To the consternation of his advisers, who still smarted from Siam's
territorial losses to France, Vajiravudh declared war on Germany and
took Siam into World War I on the side of the Allies, sending a token
expeditionary force to the Western front. This limited participation,
however, won Siam favorable amendments to its treaties with France and
Britain at the end of the war and also gained a windfall in impounded
German shipping for its merchant marine. Siam took part in the
Versailles peace conference in 1919 and was a founding member of the
League of Nations.
Thailand
Thailand - BEGINNING OF THE CONSTITUTIONAL ERA
Thailand
Early in his reign, King Prajadhipok (Rama VII, 1925-35) showed a
tendency to share responsibility for political decision making with his
ministers. He also appointed an advisory council to study the
possibility of providing the country with a constitution, but its
royalist members advised against such a measure. The civil bureaucracy,
by contrast, considered the time ripe for such a move. Siam faced severe
economic problems because of the world depression, which had caused a
sharp drop in the price of rice. Discontent among the political elite
grew in reaction to retrenchment in government spending, which
necessitated severe cutbacks in the numbers of civil servants and
military personnel, the demotion in rank of others, and the cancellation
of government programs.
Thailand
Thailand - 1932 Coup
Thailand
The long era of absolute monarchy was brought to a sudden end on June
24, 1932, by a bloodless coup d'etat engineered by a group of civil
servants and army officers with the support of army units in the Bangkok
area. The action was specifically directed against ministers of the
conservative royal government and not against the person of the king.
Three days after the coup a military junta put into effect a provisional
constitution drawn up by a young law professor, Pridi Phanomyong.
Prajadhipok reluctantly accepted the new situation that had stripped him
of his political power but in principle had left the prestige of the
monarchy unimpaired.
The coup leaders, who were known as the "promoters," were
representative of the younger generation of Western-oriented political
elite that had been educated to be instruments of an absolute
monarchy--an institution they now viewed as archaic and inadequate to
the task of modern government. The principals in the coup identified
themselves as nationalists, and none questioned the institution of the
monarchy. Their numbers included the major figures in Thai politics for
the next three decades. Pridi, one of the country's leading
intellectuals, was the most influential civilian promoter. His chief
rival among the other promoters was Phibun, or Luang Plaek
Phibunsongkhram, an ambitious junior army officer who later attained the
rank of field marshal. Phahon, or Phraya Phahonphonphayuhasena, the
senior member of the group, represented old-line military officers
dissatisfied with cuts in appropriations for the armed forces. These
three exercised power as members of a cabinet, the Commissariat of the
People, chosen by the National Assembly that had been summoned by the
promoters soon after the coup. To assuage conservative opinion, a
retired jurist, Phraya Manopakorn, was selected as prime minister.
A permanent constitution was promulgated before the end of 1932. It
provided for a quasi-parliamentary regime in which executive power was
vested in a unicameral legislature, the National Assembly, of which half
of the members were elected by limited suffrage and half appointed by
the government in power. The constitution provided that the entire
legislature would be elected when half of the electorate had received
four years of schooling or after ten years had elapsed, whichever came
first. The National Assembly was responsible for the budget and could
override a royal veto. Real power resided with the promoters, however,
and was exercised with army backing through their political
organization, the People's Party.
A rift soon developed within the ranks of the promoters between
civilian technicians and military officers. As finance minister, Pridi
proposed a radical economic plan in 1933, calling for the
nationalization of natural resources. This plan was unacceptable to
Manopakorn and the more conservative military members in the cabinet.
The prime minister closed the National Assembly, in which Pridi had
support, and ruled by decree. Accused of being a communist, Pridi fled
into exile, but army officers opposing the civilian prime minister's
move staged a coup in June 1933 that turned out Manopakorn, restored the
National Assembly, and set up a new government headed by Phahon. With
sentiment running in his favor, Pridi was permitted to return to Bangkok
and was subsequently cleared of the charges against him.
In addition to factionalism within the cabinet, the government was
also confronted with a serious royalist revolt in October 1933. The
revolt was led by the king's cousin, Prince Boworadet, who had been
defense minister during the old regime. Although the king gave no
support to the prince, relations between Prajadhipok and the political
leaders deteriorated thereafter.
The first parliamentary elections in the country's history were held
in November 1933. Although fewer than 10 percent of the eligible voters
cast their ballots, they confirmed Pridi's popularity. Pridi and his
supporters in the civilian left wing of the People's Party were
countered by a military faction that rallied around his rival, Phibun.
In 1934 Phibun was named defense minister and proceeded to use his
ministerial powers to build his political constituency within the army.
Campaigning for a stronger military establishment in order to keep the
country out of foreign hands, he took every opportunity to assert the
superior efficiency of the military administration over the civilian
bureaucracy, which looked to Pridi for leadership. Prime Minister Phahon
had to maintain a precarious balance between the Pridi and Phibun
factions in the government.
The civilian conservatives had been discredited during the Manopakorn
regime and by the support some had given to the royalist revolt. Their
loss of influence deprived the king of effective political allies in the
government. In March 1935, Prajadhipok abdicated without naming a
successor, charging the Phahon government with abuse of power in
curtailing the royal veto. He went into retirement in Britain. His
ten-year-old nephew, Ananda Mahidol (Rama VIII, 1935-46), who was
attending school in Switzerland, was named king to succeed him, and a
regency council, which included Pridi, was appointed to carry out those
functions of the monarchy retained under the constitution. The new king
did not return to his country until 1945.
Thailand
Thailand - Phibun and the Nationalist Regime
Thailand
The promoters, both civilian and military, had given their political
movement a nationalist label, but unanimity among them went no further
than acceptance of the official ideology. Although it was essential for
the stability of any cabinet that they work together, relations between
the civilian and military factions steadily deteriorated as more civil
offices went to military personnel. Sensing a tendency toward military
rule that he could no longer contain, Phahon retired in December 1938.
Phibun took office as prime minister, with his rival, Pridi, as finance
minister.
The Phibun regime sold nationalism to the public by using propaganda
methods borrowed from authoritarian regimes in Europe, and nationalism
was equated with Westernization. To make clear to the world--in Phibun's
words--that the country belonged to the Thai, in 1939 the name of the
country was officially changed to Muang Thai (Land of the Free), or
Thailand. That same year Pridi introduced his "Thailand for the
Thai" economic plan, which levied heavy taxes on foreign-owned
businesses, the majority of them Chinese, while offering state subsidies
to Thai-owned enterprises. The government encouraged the Thai to emulate
European fashions, decreeing, for example, that shoes and hats be worn
in public. Betel chewing was prohibited, and opium addicts were
prosecuted and, if Chinese, deported.
Although nationalism was equated with Westernization, it was not
pro-Western, either politically or culturally. Thai Christians,
especially those in government service, as well as Muslims, suffered
official discrimination. The clear inference of government statements
was that only Buddhists could be Thai patriots. At its source Thai
nationalism was anti-Chinese in character. Regulations were enacted to
check Chinese immigration and to reserve for the Thai numerous
occupations that had formerly been held predominantly by Chinese.
Phibun's nationalist regime also revived irredentist claims, stirring
up anti-French sentiment and supporting restoration of former Thai
territories in Cambodia and Laos. Seeking support against France, Phibun
cultivated closer relations with Japan. The Thai nationalists looked to
Japan as the model of an Asian country that had used Western methods and
technology to achieve rapid modernization. As Thailand confronted the
French in Indochina, the Thai looked to Japan as the only Asian country
to challenge the European powers successfully. Although the Thai were
united in their demand for the return of the lost provinces, Phibun's
enthusiasm for the Japanese was markedly greater than that of Pridi, and
many old conservatives as well viewed the course of the prime minister's
foreign policy with misgivings.
Thailand
Thailand - World War II
Thailand
Thailand responded pragmatically to the military and political
pressures of World War II. When sporadic fighting broke out between Thai
and French forces along Thailand's eastern frontier in late 1940 and
early 1941, Japan used its influence with the Vichy regime in France to
obtain concessions for Thailand. As a result, France agreed in March
1941 to cede 54,000 square kilometers of Laotian territory west of the
Mekong and most of the Cambodian province of Battambang to Thailand. The
recovery of this lost territory and the regime's apparent victory over a
European colonial power greatly enhanced Phibun's reputation.
Then, on December 8, 1941, after several hours of fighting between
Thai and Japanese troops at Chumphon, Thailand had to accede to Japanese
demands for access through the country for Japanese forces invading
Burma and Malaya. Phibun assured the country that the Japanese action
was prearranged with a sympathetic Thai government. Later in the month
Phibun signed a mutual defense pact with Japan. Pridi resigned from the
cabinet in protest but subsequently accepted the nonpolitical position
of regent for the absent Ananda Mahidol.
Under pressure from Japan, the Phibun regime declared war on Britain
and the United States in January 1942, but the Thai ambassador in
Washington, Seni Pramoj, refused to deliver the declaration to the
United States government. Accordingly, the United States refrained from
declaring war on Thailand. With American assistance Seni, a conservative
aristocrat whose antiJapanese credentials were well established,
organized the Free Thai Movement, recruiting Thai students in the United
States to work with the United States Office of Strategic Services
(OSS). The OSS trained Thai personnel for underground activities, and
units were readied to infiltrate Thailand. From the office of the regent
in Thailand, Pridi ran a clandestine movement that by the end of the war
had with Allied aid armed more than 50,000 Thai to resist the Japanese.
Thailand was rewarded for Phibun's close cooperation with Japan
during the early years of war with the return of further territory that
had once been under Bangkok's control, including portions of the Shan
states in Burma and the four northernmost Malay states. Japan meanwhile
had stationed 150,000 troops on Thai soil and built the infamous
"death railway" through Thailand using Allied prisoners of
war.
As the war dragged on, however, the Japanese presence grew more
irksome. Trade came to a halt, and Japanese military personnel
requisitioning supplies increasingly dealt with Thailand as a conquered
territory rather than as an ally. Allied bombing raids damaged Bangkok
and other targets and caused several thousand casualties. Public opinion
and, even more important, the sympathies of the civilian political
elite, moved perceptibly against the Phibun regime and the military. In
June 1944, Phibun was forced from office and replaced by the first
predominantly civilian government since the 1932 coup.
Thailand
Thailand - Pridi and the Civilian Regime, 1944-47
Thailand
The new government was headed by Khuang Aphaiwong, a civilian linked
politically with conservatives like Seni. The most influential figure in
the regime, however, was Pridi, whose antiJapanese views were
increasingly attractive to the Thai. In the last year of the war, Allied
agents were tacitly given free access by Bangkok. As the war came to an
end, Thailand repudiated its wartime agreements with Japan.
The civilian leaders, however, were unable to achieve unity. After a
falling-out with Pridi, Khuang was replaced as prime minister by the
regent's nominee, Seni, who had returned to Thailand from his post in
Washington. The scramble for power among factions in late 1945 created
political divisions in the ranks of the civilian leaders that destroyed
their potential for making a common stand against the resurgent
political force of the military in the postwar years.
Postwar accommodations with the Allies also weakened the civilian
government. As a result of the contributions made to the Allied war
efforts by the Free Thai Movement, the United States, which unlike the
other Allies had never officially been at war with Thailand, refrained
from dealing with Thailand as an enemy country in postwar peace
negotiations. Before signing a peace treaty, however, Britain demanded
war reparations in the form of rice for shipment to Malaya, and France
refused to permit admission of Thailand to the United Nations (UN) until
Indochinese territories annexed during the war were returned. The Soviet
Union insisted on the repeal of anticommunist legislation.
The government set up an agency to manage the delivery of rice as
part of Thai war reparations. These reparations were initially to total
1.5 million tons, or approximately 10 percent of the annual yield, but
the figure was adjusted downward, and the reparations were paid off
within two years. However, the government retained the policy of
regulating the rice trade as an income-producing device.
The Seni government survived only until the peace treaty with Britain
was signed in January 1946. Public discontent grew--the result of
inflation, the reparation payments to the British, the surrender of
territorial gains that many Thai considered to have been legitimate, and
mismanagement at every level of government. Pridi restored Khuang to
office for a time but in March 1946 was obliged to assume the prime
ministership himself in an effort to restore confidence in the civilian
regime.
Pridi, who argued that the strength of any civilian regime depended
on a functioning parliament, worked with his cabinet to draft a new
constitution that established parliamentary structures. The
constitution, promulgated in May 1946, called for a bicameral
legislature. The lower house the House of Representatives, was elected
by popular vote; the upper house, the Senate, was elected by the lower
house. This constitution was tailor made for Pridi's purposes, ensuring
him a parliamentary majority that would support his programs.
The 1946 election, which had in fact preceded enactment of the
constitution, was the first in which political parties participated. Two
coalition parties--Pridi's own party, the Constitutional Front, and the
Cooperation Party--won a large majority of seats in the lower house and,
in turn, sent a proPridi majority to the upper house. Parliamentary
opposition was led by the Democrat (Prachathipat) Party, headed by Seni
and Khuang.
Pridi's prestige suffered permanent damage two weeks after the
election of the upper house, however, when Ananda Mahidol, who had
returned from Switzerland a few months earlier, was found dead in his
bed at the palace, a bullet wound through his head. Although the
official account attributed the king's death to an accident, there was
widespread doubt because few facts were made public. Rumors implicated
Pridi. Two months later, in August, Pridi resigned on grounds of ill
health and went abroad, leaving Luang Thamrongnawasawat as prime
minister.
The late king's younger brother, nineteen-year-old Bhumibol Adulyadej
(Rama IX, 1946- ), was chosen as successor to the throne. The new king
had been born in the United States, had spent his childhood in
Switzerland, and had gone to Thailand for the first time in 1945 with
his brother. He returned to Switzerland to complete his schooling and
did not return to Bangkok to take up his duties until 1951.
Thailand
Thailand - RETURN OF PHIBUN AND THE MILITARY
Thailand
As a result of Pridi's fall from grace and the manner in which the
civilian government that succeeded him handled the investigation of the
king's death, Phibun's military faction regained some of the stature
that it had lost through its wartime association with the Japanese.
Reviving the nationalistic theme of its years in power, Phibun's group
played on intense public resentment of the war reparations Thailand had
to pay and the economic dislocation the payments were believed to have
caused. Army officers also blamed the civilian government for a
humiliation the military suffered in 1946 when their units, facing
expatriated Chinese Guomindang (Kuomintang--KMT) forces in the north,
were ordered to disband in the field and were left without supplies or
transport. They also criticized the civilian government's conciliatory
policy toward minorities--Chinese, Muslims, and hill tribes.
Phibun had been arrested as a war criminal in 1945 but was released
by the courts soon afterward. Always an efficient leader and known as a
staunch anticommunist, Phibun had retained his constituency of
supporters in the officer corps. Even the civilian elite, dismayed at
the economic disorder and frightened at the rise of communist
insurgencies in neighboring countries, regarded him as an attractive
candidate for office. Some observers contended that his rehabilitation
had been due to United States influence.
Thailand
Thailand - November 1947 Coup
Thailand
In November 1947, the so-called Coup d'Etat Group, led by two retired
generals and backed by Phibun, seized power from the civilian
government. Pridi, who had recently returned from his world tour, fled
the country again and eventually took refuge in China. The coup leaders
appointed an interim government headed by Khuang and promised a new
constitution. General elections held in January 1948 confirmed support
for the junta, particularly the Phibun faction. In order to placate
conservative civilian supporters, Khuang was retained as prime minister
until he proved too independent in his policies. In April 1948,
Phibun--by then a field marshal--forcibly removed Khuang from office and
took over as prime minister.
For the next three years Phibun struggled to maintain his government
against numerous attempted coups by rival military factions. To build
support, he allowed disaffected political groups, including Khuang's
conservative Democrat Party, to participate in drafting a new
constitution, which was promulgated in 1949. When leaders of an
anti-Phibun army group were arrested in October 1948, supporters of
former prime ministers Pridi and Khuang in the navy and the marines were
not seized. In February 1949, a revolt allegedly sponsored by Pridi
supporters in the marines and navy was suppressed after three days of
fighting. In June 1951, marine and navy troops again rebelled and
abducted Phibun. The revolt, which was put down by loyal army and air
force units, resulted in a serious cutback of navy strength and a purge
of senior naval officers.
Phibun's policies during his second government (1948-57) were similar
to those he had initiated in the late 1930s. He restored the use of the
name Thailand in 1949. (In reaction to extreme nationalism,
there had been a reversion to the name Siam in 1946.)
Legislation to make Thai social behavior conform to Western
standards--begun by Phibun before the war--was reintroduced. Secondary
education was improved, and military appropriations were substantially
increased. The Phibun regime was also characterized by harassment of
Chinese and the tendency to regard them as disloyal and, after 1949, as
communists.
Phibun's anticommunist position had great influence on his foreign
policy. Thailand refused to recognize the People's Republic of China,
supported UN action in Korea in 1950, and backed the French against
communist insurgents in Indochina. Phibun's Thailand was regarded as the
most loyal supporter of United States foreign policy in mainland
Southeast Asia.
Thailand
Thailand - November 1951 Coup
Thailand
By 1951 Phibun had begun to share political power with two associates
who had participated with him in the 1947 coup that overthrew the
civilian regime. One of these was General Phao Siyanon, director general
of police and a close associate of Phibun since the original coup of
1932. The other, more junior, partner was General Sarit Thanarat,
commander of the Bangkok garrison. As time passed, Phibun's stock within
the military declined as a result of the plots against him. Phao and
Sarit grew more powerful than Phibun, who was able to retain the prime
ministership only because of their rivalry for the succession.
In November 1951, military and police officers announced in a
radiobroadcast that the 1949 constitution was suspended by the
government and that the 1932 constitution was in force. The reason given
for restoring a unicameral parliament with half its membership appointed
by the government was the danger of communist aggression. Shortly after
the government-engineered coup, King Bhumibol Adulyadej was called back
to Thailand, and for the first time since 1935 an adult monarch resided
in the palace in Bangkok. A revised constitution was promulgated in
February 1952, and an election was held for seats in the new,
single-house legislature, half of the members of which were to be
appointed. Nearly all the appointed parliamentary members were army
officers.
The Phibun-Phao-Sarit triumvirate continued to operate along the
policy lines of the previous five years. In November 1952, the police
announced the discovery of a communist plot against the government and
began a series of arrests of Chinese. Many Chinese schools were closed
and Chinese associations banned. The campaign against communists, with
its anti-Chinese emphasis, gathered momentum throughout 1953.
In 1954 Thailand participated in the Manila meeting that resulted in
the Southeast Asia Collective Defense Treaty, of which the Southeast
Asia Treaty Organization (SEATO) was the operative arm. The next year SEATO, which made its headquarters
at Bangkok, was offered the use of military bases in Thailand. Relations
with the United States continued to be cordial during this period, and
substantial amounts of American economic, technical, and military aid
were provided.
In 1955 the Thai government had imposed a restrictive export tax on
rice--the controversial rice premium--and required that traders purchase
rice export licenses. The ultimate goal of this tax was to nurture
Thailand's developing industries and to discourage rice production. The
government hoped the tax on tonnage of rice exported would drive the
price of Thai rice in the world market beyond a competitive level, thus
discouraging exports. The government then purchased the rice that could
not be sold abroad to create a public rice reserve and sold it on the
domestic market at artificially low prices.
By providing low-cost rice, the government hoped to hold down the
cost of living in urban areas and prevent demands for higher wages,
thereby making Thai industrial production more competitive on world
markets. It also argued that the rice policy would encourage
diversification in the agricultural sector as traditional rice farmers
in the central plain turned to other cash crops--maize, sugarcane, and
pineapple. Export controls had no effect however, on rice farmers in the
North and Northeast, who produced glutinous rice for local consumption
only. Introduction of the rice premium fundamentally altered the liberal
policy toward free trade that had been in place since the Bowring
Treaty, and it cast the Thai government in an activist economic role,
such as that advocated by the nationalists since 1932.
Opponents of the rice policy charged that the rice premium was an
excessive tax that ultimately placed the heaviest burden on small
farmers in the central plain engaged in growing rice for export, who
were deprived of an increase in real income and were prevented from
sharing in the benefits of Thailand's economic boom in the 1960s.
Lacking incentive to increase their production, farmers planted less and
refrained from introducing improved seeds or using costly fertilizers.
Government officials, however, predicted that as rice production
increased abroad, world and domestic prices would come together and end
the need for the rice premium.
Thailand
Thailand - Phibun's Experiment with "Democracy"
Thailand
The struggle for control of the Thai government continued, meanwhile,
and Phibun attempted to offset Sarit's advantage among the military by
generating popular support for himself. In 1955 he toured the United
States and Britain and, on his return to Thailand, articulated a policy
of prachathipatai ("democracy"), which he stated he
was giving to the country as a gift. Encouraging the public to feel free
to criticize his "open regime," he set aside a portion of a
central park near the royal palace in Bangkok for public debate, in
emulation of Hyde Park in London, and gave the press free rein in
covering the dissent expressed there. Criticism, especially as it
appeared in the press, was outspoken and often extreme in its attacks on
the government. In addition to encouraging criticism, Phibun halted the
anti-Chinese campaign, made plans to increase the responsibilities of
local government, and again permitted political parties to register.
Phibun intended more to convey the appearance of democracy, however,
than to allow for its functional development.
Phao and Phibun devoted much effort to ensuring a government victory
in the general election scheduled for February 1957. Phao headed a newly
founded government party, the Seri Manangkhasila, which was the largest
and best funded of the twenty-five parties that had sprung up in
response to prachathipatai. Sarit, on the other hand, kept out
of the campaign and, after the election, dissociated himself from the
disappointing results, which gave the Seri Manangkhasila a bare majority
but saw half of the incumbent party members defeated. Sarit and others
questioned even these returns and accused the government party of
stuffing ballot boxes. When university students came out in great
numbers to protest the government's handling of the elections, Phibun
declared a state of emergency and shelved prachathipatai.
Thailand
Thailand - SARIT AND THANOM
Thailand
Phibun had failed to win the popular support that he had sought, and
the effort cost him what remained of his standing among the military
faction. As a result of the election, Phibun formed a new government in
March 1957, appointing Phao as interior minister with responsibility for
internal security. However, it was Sarit, whose prestige had not been at
stake in the election, who as newly named armed forces commander in
chief emerged as the strongest member of the ruling group. In September
he openly broke with his colleagues, ordered tanks into the streets, and
displaced Phibun and Phao in a bloodless coup d'etat. He suspended the
constitution and dissolved parliament. The king approved Sarit's action;
the royal family had opposed Phibun since the 1930s.
New elections were held in December under an interim civilian
government headed by Pote Sarasin, the secretary general of SEATO. No
single party won a parliamentary majority, but Sarit organized a
government party, the National Socialist Party, to contain the loose
coalition of parties and individuals backing his regime. Because of poor
health Sarit did not attempt to form a government but turned over
responsibility to his deputy in the armed forces, Thanom Kittikachorn.
Intraparty wrangling over political and economic spoils plagued Thanom's
government. The situation was further aggravated by the inclusion in the
government party of left-wing politicians who opposed its proWestern
foreign policy.
Thailand
Thailand - Sarit's Return
Thailand
In October 1958, Sarit, recently returned from the United States
where he had undergone extensive medical treatment, took over personal
control of the government with the consent of Thanom, who resigned as
prime minister. Sarit, who spoke of instilling "national
discipline" in the country, justified his action on the grounds
that Thailand's various constitutional experiments had not succeeded in
providing the stability needed for economic development. He outlawed
political parties and jailed critics of the regime--teachers, students,
labor leaders, journalists, and liberal parliamentarians. A dozen or
more newspapers were closed.
In January 1960, Sarit decreed an interim constitution that provided
for an appointed assembly to draft a new constitution, Thailand's eighth
since 1932. Work on the document continued throughout the 1960s. Sarit
assumed the office of prime minister provided for in the interim
constitution, but his regime was clearly that of a military
dictatorship.
Whatever else might be said about its political shortcomings, Sarit's
government was more dynamic than the previous regimes of the
constitutional era. Sarit gave ministers in his cabinet considerable
independence in the affairs of their own ministries. At the same time he
made all major decisions and kept members of the government responsible
solely to his office.
Despite recurring scandals involving official corruption, in the
early 1960s Sarit seemed to have succeeded in achieving political
stability and economic growth. In 1961 the government instituted the
first in a series of economic development schemes that were intended to
foster employment and expand production. Although military officers were
frequently appointed as directors of state and quasi-governmental
economic enterprises, civilian personnel gradually assumed a greater
share in implementing government policies. Sarit welcomed foreign
investment and assured investors of government protection. Major
electrification and irrigation projects began, with aid from the United
States and international agencies. In addition, Sarit initiated a
cleanup campaign to improve sanitation in the cities.
Sarit revived the motto "Nation-Religion-King" as a
fighting political slogan for his regime, which he characterized as
combining the paternalism of the ancient Thai state and the benevolent
ideals of Buddhism. He spoke of his intention to "restore" the
king, a retiring man, to active participation in national life, and he
urged Bhumibol Adulyadej and his consort, Queen Sirikit, to have more
contact with the Thai public, which had a strong affection for the
monarchy. Royal tours were also scheduled for the king and queen to
represent Thailand abroad. Sarit likewise played on the religious
attachments of the people. In 1962 he centralized administration of
monastic institutions under a superior patriarchate friendly to the
regime, and he mobilized monks, especially in the North and Northeast,
to support government programs. Critics protested that Sarit had
demeaned religion by using it for political ends and had compromised the
monarchy by using it to legitimize a military dictatorship. They
asserted that the regime's policies, rather than restoring these
institutions, had contributed to the growth of materialism and
secularism and to the erosion of religious belief in the country.
Under Sarit's guidance, Thailand's anticommunist policy continued,
and steps were taken to deal militarily with the growing threat of
insurgency posed by communist-inspired activities in neighboring
countries. Sarit sought closer ties with Thailand's anticommunist
neighbors and with the United States, and in 1961 Thailand and another
SEATO member, the Philippines, joined with newly independent Malaya
(since 1963, Malaysia) to form the Association of Southeast Asia (ASA).
The Pathet Lao (as the leftist Lao People's Liberation Army was known
until 1965) moved into northwestern Laos in March 1962. United States
secretary of state Dean Rusk and Thai foreign minister Thanat Khoman
agreed that their countries would interpret the Southeast Asia
Collective Defense Treaty of 1954 as a bilateral as well as multilateral
pact binding the United States to come to the aid of Thailand in time of
need, with or without the agreement of the other signers of the pact.
Two months after the foreign ministers' agreement, President John F.
Kennedy stationed United States troops in Thailand in response to the
deteriorating situation in Laos. The arrival of the troops in May 1962
was seen by the Thai government as evidence of the United States
commitment to preserving Thailand's independence and integrity against
communist expansion. Despite United States pressure, however, Sarit
refused to entertain ideas of democratic reform.
Thailand
Thailand - Thai Politics and Foreign Policy, 1963-71
Thailand
In December 1963 Sarit died in office. His deputy, Thanom, peacefully
succeeded to the prime ministership and pursued without major
modifications the foreign and domestic policies of his predecessor.
Retaining the cabinet that he inherited from Sarit, Thanom focused his
efforts on seeking to maintain political stability; promoting economic
development, especially in security-sensitive areas; raising the
standard of living; and safeguarding the country from the communist
threat at home and abroad.
A notable departure from Sarit's policies, however, was the Thanom
government's decision to shorten the timetable for the country's
transition from the military-dominated leadership structure to a
popularly elected government. The prime minister urged the Constituent
Assembly, appointed in 1959, to finish drafting a constitution as soon
as practicable. The new leadership also relaxed stringent official
controls on the press, an attempt that the authorities said was aimed at
creating a new, relatively liberalized, political climate.
Although the leaders agreed on the desirability of establishing what
they described as a more democratic political system in tune with the
country's heritage, there were indications that they disagreed on the
pace of the projected change. Some leading officials thought that an
early resumption of political activities would broaden the base of
politics and strengthen popular identification with the government, the
monarchy, and Buddhism. Others argued that the restoration of party
politics at a time when the country was confronted with serious internal
problems was likely to aid the communists in their efforts to infiltrate
civic, labor, student, and political organizations.
The constitution was finally proclaimed in June 1968, but martial
law, which had been imposed in 1958, remained in effect. Party politics
were legalized and resumed shortly after mid-1968, and general elections
for the new National Assembly were held in February 1969. Thanom's
United Thai People's Party returned 75 members to the 219-seat lower
house, giving them the largest representation of the 13 parties, while
the second-running Democrat Party won 57 seats.
Thailand's annual economic growth rate in the 1960s and early 1970s
averaged a booming 8 percent, much of it attributable to United States
military expenditures there during the years of its involvement in
Vietnam. An increased flow of foreign exchange resulted from United
States and multilateral aid loans as well as from foreign investment,
which came primarily from Japan, the United States, and Taiwan.
Foreign policy concerns focused on neighboring Laos, where it was
believed a Pathet Lao victory would destabilize the North and Northeast
and open Thailand to a direct attack by communist forces. Thailand
allied itself closely with the United States position in the Republic of
Vietnam (South Vietnam), permitting bases in Thailand to be used for
raids on both the Democratic Republic of Vietnam (North Vietnam) and
Cambodia. Although more than 45,000 United States troops and 500 combat
aircraft were stationed in the country by 1968, their mission was not
officially acknowledged for fear of possible communist retaliation
against Thailand. Sarit also committed a division of Thai army troops to
the war in South Vietnam.
President Lyndon B. Johnson's March 1968 announcement that the United
States would halt bombing in North Vietnam and seek a negotiated
settlement came as a blow to the Thai government, which had not been
consulted on the change in policy. Although the defense of Thailand
clearly remained essential to the security of Southeast Asia in United
States strategic thinking, no provision was made for Laos, whose
security the Thai saw as essential to their own defense.
While remaining loyal to its commitments, Thailand thereafter
determined to restore flexibility to its foreign policy by moving away
from one-sided dependence on the United States. The military, however,
was anxious to continue Thailand's active involvement in South Vietnam
and in Laos, where several thousand Thai "volunteers" were
engaged against the Pathet Lao. Thanom urged United States backing for
the Lon Nol regime in Cambodia in 1970 and proposed a formal alliance
linking Thailand with Laos, Cambodia, and South Vietnam that would give
the conflict in Southeast Asia the appearance of a war being fought by
Asian anticommunists for Asian security. The plan failed to get United
States support.
Communist activities in Laos and Malaya had already begun to affect
the domestic situation in the South and the Northeast in the 1950s, and
by the 1960s they presented a problem of increasing magnitude. Communist
guerrillas, mostly ethnic Chinese, operated in jungle areas north of the
Thai-Malayan border, where they had taken refuge from Commonwealth of
Nations security forces during the 1948-60 Emergency in Malaya. A more
serious threat in that same region were the Muslim insurgents of the
Pattani National Liberation Front, a Thai separatist group composed of
ethnic Malays. Meanwhile, in the northern provinces dissident Meo
tribesmen reportedly had begun receiving training and arms from the
Pathet Lao by 1950. In the Northeast, underground leftist parties took
advantage of grievances over relatively poor economic and social
conditions to rally opposition to the government. Faced with the
problems in the South, North, and Northeast, the Bangkok government
frequently identified regional unrest and protest against ethnic and
economic policies with the genuine communist-based insurgencies that
overlapped and often benefited from it. Opposition groups and critics of
the regime in Bangkok were also generally labeled as communists.
Thailand
Thailand - November 1971 Coup
Thailand
In November 1971, Prime Minister Thanom executed a coup against his
own government, thereby ending the three-year experiment with what had
passed for parliamentary democracy. The 1968 constitution was suspended,
political parties banned, and undisguised military rule imposed on the
country. Under the new regime, executive and legislative authority was
held by a military junta, the National Executive Council. Heading the
council was a triumvirate that included Thanom, who retained the office
of prime minister; Field Marshal Praphat Charusathian, his deputy prime
minister; and Thanom's son (also Praphat's son-in- law), Narong
Kittikachorn, an army colonel.
Despite stern moves to suppress opposition, popular dissatisfaction
with the dictatorial regime mounted in the universities and labor
organizations as well as among rival military factions. The discontent
focused on United States support for Thanom, the growth of Japanese
economic influence, and the official corruption that the regime made no
effort to conceal. The civilian political elite joined students and
workers in opposing Thanom's apparent aim to perpetuate a political
dynasty through his son, Narong, whose rise the officer corps
particularly resented. Thanom's aggrandizement of his family was at odds
with the image he tried to project and the standards of the "civic
religion" with its call for veneration of "NationReligion
-King." The triumvirate also ignored the king, who had moderated
his earlier enthusiasm for Thanom, and opponents charged that the junta
disregarded religion. Some critics detected signs of republicanism in
the regime and feared another Thanom-sponsored coup to overthrow the
monarchy.
Thailand
Thailand - End of Thanom Regime
Thailand
In December 1972, Thanom announced a new interim constitution that
provided for a totally appointed legislative assembly, two- thirds of
the members of which would be drawn from the military and police. This
move provoked widespread protest, however, especially among students and
led to Thanom's eventual removal. In May and June 1973, students and
workers rallied in the streets to demand a more democratic constitution
and genuine parliamentary elections. By early October, there was renewed
violence, protesting the detention of eleven students arrested for
handing out antigovernment pamphlets. The demonstrations grew in size
and scope as students demanded an end to the military dictatorship. On
October 13, more than 250,000 people rallied in Bangkok before the
Democracy Memorial, in the largest demonstration of its kind in Thai
history, to press their grievances against the government.
The next day troops opened fire on the demonstrators, killing
seventy-five, and occupied the campus of Thammasat University. King
Bhumibol, who had been seeking Thanom's ouster, took a direct role in
dealing with the crisis in order to prevent further bloodshed and called
Thanom and his cabinet to Chitralada Palace for talks. In the evening,
the king went on television and radio to announce a compromise solution:
Thanom had resigned as prime minister but would remain as supreme
commander of the armed forces. In consultation with student leaders, the
king appointed Sanya Dharmasakti (Sanya Thammasak) as interim prime
minister, with instructions to draft a new constitution. Sanya, a
civilian conservative, was the rector of Thammasat University and known
to be sympathetic to the students' position. On October 15, Thanom,
Praphat, and Narong--dubbed Thailand's "three most hated
men"-- were allowed to leave the country in secret, the king
overruling student militants who wanted to put them on trial. Their
departure was announced to the public only after they had left the
country, Praphat and Narong for Taiwan and Thanom initially for the
United States.
The student demonstrations of 1973 had not been intended as a prelude
to a revolution. They resulted, at least in part, from the frustration
of large numbers of students who were unable to fulfill professional
expectations after graduation, partly because university enrollment had
increased dramatically in the 1960s and early 1970s. Students were
careful, however, to legitimize their actions against the military
dictatorship by an appeal to religion and the monarchy, displaying in
the streets the symbols of the "civic religion"--figures of
Buddha, pictures of the king, and the national flag.
Prime Minister Sanya gave full credit to the student movement for
bringing down the military dictatorship. At the state ceremony honoring
those who had been killed during the 1973 demonstrations, he pledged,
"Their death has brought us democracy which we will preserve
forever." However, political change in Thailand did not bring the
shift to the left that had been hoped for by some and feared by many.
Student militants, who already felt betrayed by the king's complicity in
Thanom's escape, were not satisfied with the direction taken by the new
government, which seemed to have been preempted by the professional
politicians.
The new constitution, which went into effect in October 1974, called
for a popularly elected House of Representatives and elections within
120 days. Political parties proliferated following the passage in 1974
of legislation permitting their registration. As a result, the January
1975 parliamentary elections were inconclusive. With forty-two
officially sanctioned parties in the field, none won a parliamentary
majority. The parties for the most part had been organized around
familiar political personalities, and few had offered any ideological
base or even specific programs. Only 47 percent of eligible voters cast
ballots; public cynicism about politicians and improper management of
voter registration were blamed for the relatively low turnout. According
to observers, however, the election was not openly corrupt.
The election put a large bloc of right-wing and centrist parties in
control of nearly 90 percent of the seats. None could be described as
reformist, and, to a degree, all represented the status quo. On the
left, a small and inexperienced but idealistic group advocated land
redistribution and favored neutrality in foreign affairs. Seni Pramoj,
whose Democrat Party was the largest in the right-wing bloc, formed a
shaky government that could depend on only 91 of the 269 votes in the
House of Representatives. It fell within a month, after failing to win a
vote of confidence. In March Seni's brother, Kukrit Pramoj, leader of
the small, right-wing Social Action (Kit Sangkhom) Party, was able to
put together a more stable centrist coalition. During his year in
office, Kukrit proposed such reforms as decentralizing economic planning
to put development in the hands of locally elected committees, but
measures of this nature were repeatedly defeated as members of the
National Assembly rallied to protect their vested interests.
The overthrow of the Thanom regime had brought on a more vocal
questioning of ties with the United States. Nationalist sentiment, which
was frequently expressed in terms of anti- Americanism, ran high among
students, who protested alleged American involvement in domestic Thai
affairs and called for the speedy withdrawal of United States forces.
Moreover, the changed geopolitical situation in Southeast Asia refocused
the issue of the United States presence. Many Thai concluded that the
country could not be reconciled with its communist neighbors as long as
United States personnel were stationed on Thai soil.
The pullout of the 27,000 United States military personnel in
Thailand began in March 1975 and was completed in mid-1976. The Thai
government stressed the need for continued United States military
commitment in Southeast Asia, but from Bangkok's standpoint, the
emphasis in relations between the two allies clearly shifted from one of
military cooperation to economic and technical cooperation. United
States-Thai relations were dealt a setback, however, by the Mayaguez
incident in May 1975, when the United States used the airfield at Ban U
Taphao without Thai consent as a staging base for the rescue of an
American freighter detained by the Khmer Rouge. The incident was seen as
a blow to Thai sovereignty and touched off anti-American demonstrations
in Bangkok.
When South Vietnam, Laos, and Cambodia came under communist control
in the spring of 1975, the Thai government's initial reaction was to
seek an accommodation with the victors, but feelers extended to Hanoi
met with a chilly reception. In July, however, Thailand established
diplomatic relations with China, after two years of negotiations. That
same year, Thailand became active in regional technical and economic
cooperation as part of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations
(ASEAN), of which it had been a member since the organization's founding
in 1967.
In addition to political changes, both in its own government and in
its relationship with other powers, Thailand also experienced economic
shifts. Kukrit's government was plagued by labor unrest and rising
prices. The economic boom that had spurred employment and produced an
apparent prosperity in the 1960s fizzled with the phasing out of United
States military expenditures in Thailand. Furthermore, the impressive
economic growth was insufficient to keep pace with the growth of the
population, which had increased from 26 million in 1960 to 34 million in
1970. Although agricultural yield per hectare remained static,
agricultural production kept up with population growth during the 1960s
and 1970s because the amount of land under cultivation doubled during
that period. Arable land reserves were being used up by the mid-1970s,
however, except in the southern peninsula. Moreover, although increasing
rice production had indeed brought together world and domestic rice
prices, as government leaders of the 1960s had predicted, the premium
nevertheless remained in effect. Its purpose now was to augment
government revenues. More than US$40 million was derived from the rice
premium in 1975, much of it earmarked, according to government sources,
for agricultural development schemes as a form of income distribution.
The low incomes imposed by the rice premium and the lack of available
credit adversely affected small owner-operated farms in the central
plain's rice bowl that produced for the export market. Farmers left the
land either to become wage laborers on large farms or to secure
industrial and service jobs in the cities. This migration to the cities
was evident in the dramatic growth of the Bangkok-Thon Buri metropolitan
area, where population exploded by 250 percent in the 1960s and 1970s to
exceed 4.5 million in 1980.
Maintaining order was the most pressing problem facing the
parliamentary regime and the most difficult one to resolve. For one
thing, the communist-inspired insurgency persisted and generated a
mistrust of all dissidents. The radicalization of the student movement
was attributed to communist influence, and student leaders were
regularly accused of being agents for Beijing and Hanoi. Particularly
after the fall of South Vietnam, Laos, and Cambodia, all dissidents were
likely to be labeled communists by the military and by right-wing
politicians. Even in moderate government circles, misgivings were
expressed about continued student activism and the growth of militancy
against the monarchy. In April 1975, fourteen labor organizers and
student leaders were arrested under anticommunist legislation used for
the first time since Thanom's overthrow.
Adding to these political tensions were the plethora of new
newspapers that came into existence after censorship and restrictions on
the press were lifted in 1973. Although most were too small to be
economically viable, they gave a voice to political factions of every
persuasion and produced a cacophony with which many had difficulty
coping. News reporting was a low priority for many newspapers, some of
which operated solely as rumor mills engaging in extortion and
blackmail. Government officials admitted that they were intimidated by
the press.
Political murders and bombing became commonplace as open warfare
broke out between leftist students and workers and rightist paramilitary
groups, the latter openly supported by the police. In August 1975,
police in Bangkok, striking to protest government weakness toward
leftist students, went on a rampage through the Thammasat University
campus. Several senior military officers and civilian conservatives
formed the ultranationalist Nawa Phon (New Force) movement to defend
"Nation-Religion-King" against the students, and by mid-1975
it claimed 50,000 members. A group of paramilitary vigilantes, the Red
Gaurs (Red Bulls), recruited 25,000 members, largely unemployed
vocational graduates and technical students, to disrupt student rallies
and break strikes. The group was believed to have been organized by the
police as an unofficial auxiliary. Another right-wing group with similar
origins was the Village Scouts (Luk Sua Chaoban; literally,
"village tiger cubs").
Right-wing power grew early in 1976, as pressure from the military
forced Kukrit to resign after he had pressed corruption charges against
army officers. Violence during the parliamentary election campaign the
following April left more than thirty dead, including Socialist Party
leader Bunsanong Bunyothanyan, and the new alignment in the House of
Representatives brought back Seni as prime minister at the head of a
four-party, right-wing coalition.
In August Praphat reappeared in Thailand and was received by the
king. Although Seni asserted that he could not legally deport him, the
former dictator's presence provoked widespread demonstrations that
forced his return to Taiwan. The next month, however, Thanom was back in
Thailand, garbed in a monk's robe and expressing his intention to enter
a monastery. Despite renewed protests, the demoralized government
allowed him to stay.
Political tensions between leftist and rightist forces reached a
bloody climax in October 1976. On October 5, right-wing newspapers in
the capital published a photograph of student demonstrators at Thammasat
University reenacting the strangling and hanging of two student
protestors by police the previous month. The photograph, which was later
found to have been altered, showed one of the students as being made up
to resemble the king's son, Crown Prince Vajiralongkorn. The right wing
perceived the demonstration as a damning act of l�se-majeste. That
evening police surrounded the campus of Thammasat University, where
2,000 students were holding a sit-in. Fighting between students and
police (including contingents of the paramilitary Border Patrol Police)
broke out. The following day, groups of Nawa Phon, Red Gaurs, and
Village Scouts "shock troops" surged onto the campus and
launched a bloody assault in which hundreds of students were killed and
wounded and more than 1,000 arrested. That evening the military seized
power, established the National Administrative Reform Council (NARC),
and ended that phase of Thailand's intermittent experimentation with
democracy.
History Contents
<"3.htm">EARLY HISTORY
<"4.htm">The Mon and the Khmer
<"5.htm">The Tai People:
Origins and Migrations
<"6.htm">Sukhothai
<"7.htm">THE AYUTTHAYA ERA,
1350-1767
<"8.htm">Thai Kingship
<"9.htm">Social and Political
Development
<"10.htm">Economic Development
<"11.htm">Contacts with the
West
<"12.htm">Ayutthaya: The Final
Phase
<"13.htm">THE BANGKOK PERIOD,
1767-1932
<"14.htm">The Chakkri Dynasty
<"15.htm">Mongkut's Opening to
the West
<"16.htm">Chulalongkorn's
Reforms
<"17.htm">The Crisis of 1893
<"18.htm">BEGINNING OF THE
CONSTITUTIONAL ERA
<"19.htm">1932 Coup
<"20.htm">Phibun and the
Nationalist Regime
<"21.htm">World War II
<"22.htm">Pridi and the
Civilian Regime, 1944-47
<"23.htm">RETURN OF PHIBUN AND
THE MILITARY
<"24.htm">November 1947 Coup
<"25.htm">November 1951 Coup
<"26.htm">Phibun's Experiment
with "Democracy"
<"27.htm">SARIT AND THANOM
<"28.htm">Sarit's Return
<"29.htm">Thai Politics and
Foreign Policy, 1963-71
<"30.htm">November 1971 Coup
<"31.htm">End of Thanom Regime
<"32.htm">MILITARY RULE AND A
LIMITED DEMOCRACY
<"31.htm">Prem in Power
<"34.htm">Foreign Relations,
1977-83
Thailand
Thailand - MILITARY RULE AND A LIMITED DEMOCRACY
Thailand
With the support of the king and the military membership of NARC, a
new government was formed under the prime ministership of Thanin
Kraivichien, a former Supreme Court justice who had a reputation for
honesty and integrity. Though a civilian, Thanin was a passionate
anticommunist and established a regime that was in many ways more
repressive than those of earlier military strongmen. He imposed strict
censorship, placed unions under tight controls, and carried out
anticommunist purges of the civil service and education institutions.
Student leaders, driven underground by the October 1976 violence, left
urban areas to join the communist insurgency in the provinces. As a
result of his harsh rule and a growing feeling within the political
elite that university students, themselves members of the privileged
classes, had been poorly treated, Thanin was replaced in October 1977 by
General Kriangsak Chomanand.
Kriangsak was more conciliatory than his civilian predecessor and
promised a new constitution and elections by 1979. He courted moderate
union leaders, raising the minimum daily wage in the Bangkok area in
1978 and again in 1979. He allowed limited press freedom, and he gave
verbal support to the idea of land reform, though no action in this area
was forthcoming. In September 1978, he issued an amnesty for the
"Bangkok 18" dissidents who had been arrested in the October
1976 violence and tried by military courts.
A new constitution was promulgated in December 1978. The 1978
Constitution established a bicameral legislature, the National Assembly,
consisting of the popularly elected House of Representatives (301
members) and the appointed Senate (225 members). The military controlled
appointment to the Senate, and it could block House of Representatives
initiatives in important areas such as national security, the economy,
the budget, and votes of no confidence. The 1978 document also
stipulated that the prime minister and cabinet ministers did not have to
be popularly elected. When elections were held on schedule in April
1979, moderate rightist parties--the Social Action Party, the Thai
Citizens' Party, and the Chart Thai (Thai Nation) Party--won the largest
number of seats, whereas the Democrats lost most of their seats.
Further changes came during 1979 and 1980, however, as economic
conditions deteriorated in the wake of the second oil crisis.
Uncontrolled inflation caused the standard of living to fall in urban
areas, especially Bangkok, while government dilatoriness and corruption
in the villages stalled policies designed to help the farmers. In
February 1980, the Kriangsak government announced sudden increases in
the prices of oil, gas, and electricity. This action provoked opposition
from elected politicians and demonstrations similar to those of 1973 by
students and workers. As opposition grew, Kriangsak resigned. In March
1980, General Prem Tinsulanonda, who had been army commander in chief
and defense minister, became prime minister with the support of younger
officers of the armed forces and civilian political leaders.
Thailand
Thailand - End of Thanom Regime
Thailand
In December 1972, Thanom announced a new interim constitution that
provided for a totally appointed legislative assembly, two- thirds of
the members of which would be drawn from the military and police. This
move provoked widespread protest, however, especially among students and
led to Thanom's eventual removal. In May and June 1973, students and
workers rallied in the streets to demand a more democratic constitution
and genuine parliamentary elections. By early October, there was renewed
violence, protesting the detention of eleven students arrested for
handing out antigovernment pamphlets. The demonstrations grew in size
and scope as students demanded an end to the military dictatorship. On
October 13, more than 250,000 people rallied in Bangkok before the
Democracy Memorial, in the largest demonstration of its kind in Thai
history, to press their grievances against the government.
The next day troops opened fire on the demonstrators, killing
seventy-five, and occupied the campus of Thammasat University. King
Bhumibol, who had been seeking Thanom's ouster, took a direct role in
dealing with the crisis in order to prevent further bloodshed and called
Thanom and his cabinet to Chitralada Palace for talks. In the evening,
the king went on television and radio to announce a compromise solution:
Thanom had resigned as prime minister but would remain as supreme
commander of the armed forces. In consultation with student leaders, the
king appointed Sanya Dharmasakti (Sanya Thammasak) as interim prime
minister, with instructions to draft a new constitution. Sanya, a
civilian conservative, was the rector of Thammasat University and known
to be sympathetic to the students' position. On October 15, Thanom,
Praphat, and Narong--dubbed Thailand's "three most hated
men"-- were allowed to leave the country in secret, the king
overruling student militants who wanted to put them on trial. Their
departure was announced to the public only after they had left the
country, Praphat and Narong for Taiwan and Thanom initially for the
United States.
The student demonstrations of 1973 had not been intended as a prelude
to a revolution. They resulted, at least in part, from the frustration
of large numbers of students who were unable to fulfill professional
expectations after graduation, partly because university enrollment had
increased dramatically in the 1960s and early 1970s. Students were
careful, however, to legitimize their actions against the military
dictatorship by an appeal to religion and the monarchy, displaying in
the streets the symbols of the "civic religion"--figures of
Buddha, pictures of the king, and the national flag.
Prime Minister Sanya gave full credit to the student movement for
bringing down the military dictatorship. At the state ceremony honoring
those who had been killed during the 1973 demonstrations, he pledged,
"Their death has brought us democracy which we will preserve
forever." However, political change in Thailand did not bring the
shift to the left that had been hoped for by some and feared by many.
Student militants, who already felt betrayed by the king's complicity in
Thanom's escape, were not satisfied with the direction taken by the new
government, which seemed to have been preempted by the professional
politicians.
The new constitution, which went into effect in October 1974, called
for a popularly elected House of Representatives and elections within
120 days. Political parties proliferated following the passage in 1974
of legislation permitting their registration. As a result, the January
1975 parliamentary elections were inconclusive. With forty-two
officially sanctioned parties in the field, none won a parliamentary
majority. The parties for the most part had been organized around
familiar political personalities, and few had offered any ideological
base or even specific programs. Only 47 percent of eligible voters cast
ballots; public cynicism about politicians and improper management of
voter registration were blamed for the relatively low turnout. According
to observers, however, the election was not openly corrupt.
The election put a large bloc of right-wing and centrist parties in
control of nearly 90 percent of the seats. None could be described as
reformist, and, to a degree, all represented the status quo. On the
left, a small and inexperienced but idealistic group advocated land
redistribution and favored neutrality in foreign affairs. Seni Pramoj,
whose Democrat Party was the largest in the right-wing bloc, formed a
shaky government that could depend on only 91 of the 269 votes in the
House of Representatives. It fell within a month, after failing to win a
vote of confidence. In March Seni's brother, Kukrit Pramoj, leader of
the small, right-wing Social Action (Kit Sangkhom) Party, was able to
put together a more stable centrist coalition. During his year in
office, Kukrit proposed such reforms as decentralizing economic planning
to put development in the hands of locally elected committees, but
measures of this nature were repeatedly defeated as members of the
National Assembly rallied to protect their vested interests.
The overthrow of the Thanom regime had brought on a more vocal
questioning of ties with the United States. Nationalist sentiment, which
was frequently expressed in terms of anti- Americanism, ran high among
students, who protested alleged American involvement in domestic Thai
affairs and called for the speedy withdrawal of United States forces.
Moreover, the changed geopolitical situation in Southeast Asia refocused
the issue of the United States presence. Many Thai concluded that the
country could not be reconciled with its communist neighbors as long as
United States personnel were stationed on Thai soil.
The pullout of the 27,000 United States military personnel in
Thailand began in March 1975 and was completed in mid-1976. The Thai
government stressed the need for continued United States military
commitment in Southeast Asia, but from Bangkok's standpoint, the
emphasis in relations between the two allies clearly shifted from one of
military cooperation to economic and technical cooperation. United
States-Thai relations were dealt a setback, however, by the Mayaguez
incident in May 1975, when the United States used the airfield at Ban U
Taphao without Thai consent as a staging base for the rescue of an
American freighter detained by the Khmer Rouge. The incident was seen as
a blow to Thai sovereignty and touched off anti-American demonstrations
in Bangkok.
When South Vietnam, Laos, and Cambodia came under communist control
in the spring of 1975, the Thai government's initial reaction was to
seek an accommodation with the victors, but feelers extended to Hanoi
met with a chilly reception. In July, however, Thailand established
diplomatic relations with China, after two years of negotiations. That
same year, Thailand became active in regional technical and economic
cooperation as part of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations
(ASEAN), of which it had been a member since the organization's founding
in 1967.
In addition to political changes, both in its own government and in
its relationship with other powers, Thailand also experienced economic
shifts. Kukrit's government was plagued by labor unrest and rising
prices. The economic boom that had spurred employment and produced an
apparent prosperity in the 1960s fizzled with the phasing out of United
States military expenditures in Thailand. Furthermore, the impressive
economic growth was insufficient to keep pace with the growth of the
population, which had increased from 26 million in 1960 to 34 million in
1970. Although agricultural yield per hectare remained static,
agricultural production kept up with population growth during the 1960s
and 1970s because the amount of land under cultivation doubled during
that period. Arable land reserves were being used up by the mid-1970s,
however, except in the southern peninsula. Moreover, although increasing
rice production had indeed brought together world and domestic rice
prices, as government leaders of the 1960s had predicted, the premium
nevertheless remained in effect. Its purpose now was to augment
government revenues. More than US$40 million was derived from the rice
premium in 1975, much of it earmarked, according to government sources,
for agricultural development schemes as a form of income distribution.
The low incomes imposed by the rice premium and the lack of available
credit adversely affected small owner-operated farms in the central
plain's rice bowl that produced for the export market. Farmers left the
land either to become wage laborers on large farms or to secure
industrial and service jobs in the cities. This migration to the cities
was evident in the dramatic growth of the Bangkok-Thon Buri metropolitan
area, where population exploded by 250 percent in the 1960s and 1970s to
exceed 4.5 million in 1980.
Maintaining order was the most pressing problem facing the
parliamentary regime and the most difficult one to resolve. For one
thing, the communist-inspired insurgency persisted and generated a
mistrust of all dissidents. The radicalization of the student movement
was attributed to communist influence, and student leaders were
regularly accused of being agents for Beijing and Hanoi. Particularly
after the fall of South Vietnam, Laos, and Cambodia, all dissidents were
likely to be labeled communists by the military and by right-wing
politicians. Even in moderate government circles, misgivings were
expressed about continued student activism and the growth of militancy
against the monarchy. In April 1975, fourteen labor organizers and
student leaders were arrested under anticommunist legislation used for
the first time since Thanom's overthrow.
Adding to these political tensions were the plethora of new
newspapers that came into existence after censorship and restrictions on
the press were lifted in 1973. Although most were too small to be
economically viable, they gave a voice to political factions of every
persuasion and produced a cacophony with which many had difficulty
coping. News reporting was a low priority for many newspapers, some of
which operated solely as rumor mills engaging in extortion and
blackmail. Government officials admitted that they were intimidated by
the press.
Political murders and bombing became commonplace as open warfare
broke out between leftist students and workers and rightist paramilitary
groups, the latter openly supported by the police. In August 1975,
police in Bangkok, striking to protest government weakness toward
leftist students, went on a rampage through the Thammasat University
campus. Several senior military officers and civilian conservatives
formed the ultranationalist Nawa Phon (New Force) movement to defend
"Nation-Religion-King" against the students, and by mid-1975
it claimed 50,000 members. A group of paramilitary vigilantes, the Red
Gaurs (Red Bulls), recruited 25,000 members, largely unemployed
vocational graduates and technical students, to disrupt student rallies
and break strikes. The group was believed to have been organized by the
police as an unofficial auxiliary. Another right-wing group with similar
origins was the Village Scouts (Luk Sua Chaoban; literally,
"village tiger cubs").
Right-wing power grew early in 1976, as pressure from the military
forced Kukrit to resign after he had pressed corruption charges against
army officers. Violence during the parliamentary election campaign the
following April left more than thirty dead, including Socialist Party
leader Bunsanong Bunyothanyan, and the new alignment in the House of
Representatives brought back Seni as prime minister at the head of a
four-party, right-wing coalition.
In August Praphat reappeared in Thailand and was received by the
king. Although Seni asserted that he could not legally deport him, the
former dictator's presence provoked widespread demonstrations that
forced his return to Taiwan. The next month, however, Thanom was back in
Thailand, garbed in a monk's robe and expressing his intention to enter
a monastery. Despite renewed protests, the demoralized government
allowed him to stay.
Political tensions between leftist and rightist forces reached a
bloody climax in October 1976. On October 5, right-wing newspapers in
the capital published a photograph of student demonstrators at Thammasat
University reenacting the strangling and hanging of two student
protestors by police the previous month. The photograph, which was later
found to have been altered, showed one of the students as being made up
to resemble the king's son, Crown Prince Vajiralongkorn. The right wing
perceived the demonstration as a damning act of l�se-majeste. That
evening police surrounded the campus of Thammasat University, where
2,000 students were holding a sit-in. Fighting between students and
police (including contingents of the paramilitary Border Patrol Police)
broke out. The following day, groups of Nawa Phon, Red Gaurs, and
Village Scouts "shock troops" surged onto the campus and
launched a bloody assault in which hundreds of students were killed and
wounded and more than 1,000 arrested. That evening the military seized
power, established the National Administrative Reform Council (NARC),
and ended that phase of Thailand's intermittent experimentation with
democracy.
History Contents
<"3.htm">EARLY HISTORY
<"4.htm">The Mon and the Khmer
<"5.htm">The Tai People:
Origins and Migrations
<"6.htm">Sukhothai
<"7.htm">THE AYUTTHAYA ERA,
1350-1767
<"8.htm">Thai Kingship
<"9.htm">Social and Political
Development
<"10.htm">Economic Development
<"11.htm">Contacts with the
West
<"12.htm">Ayutthaya: The Final
Phase
<"13.htm">THE BANGKOK PERIOD,
1767-1932
<"14.htm">The Chakkri Dynasty
<"15.htm">Mongkut's Opening to
the West
<"16.htm">Chulalongkorn's
Reforms
<"17.htm">The Crisis of 1893
<"18.htm">BEGINNING OF THE
CONSTITUTIONAL ERA
<"19.htm">1932 Coup
<"20.htm">Phibun and the
Nationalist Regime
<"21.htm">World War II
<"22.htm">Pridi and the
Civilian Regime, 1944-47
<"23.htm">RETURN OF PHIBUN AND
THE MILITARY
<"24.htm">November 1947 Coup
<"25.htm">November 1951 Coup
<"26.htm">Phibun's Experiment
with "Democracy"
<"27.htm">SARIT AND THANOM
<"28.htm">Sarit's Return
<"29.htm">Thai Politics and
Foreign Policy, 1963-71
<"30.htm">November 1971 Coup
<"31.htm">End of Thanom Regime
<"32.htm">MILITARY RULE AND A
LIMITED DEMOCRACY
<"31.htm">Prem in Power
<"34.htm">Foreign Relations,
1977-83
Thailand
Thailand - Foreign Relations, 1977-83
Thailand
Beginning in 1977, the Thai government under Prime Minister Kriangsak
had sought a rapprochement with Indochina's new communist states. Trade
agreements and a transit accord were signed with Laos in 1978. In
September of that year, Pham Van Dong, premier of Vietnam, visited
Bangkok and gave assurances that his government would not support a
communist insurgency within Thailand. Troubles on the Thai-Cambodian
border, including assaults on Thai border villages by Cambodian forces,
however, continued to disrupt relations with Democratic Kampuchea.
Vietnam's invasion of Democratic Kampuchea in December 1978 initiated
a new crisis. Vietnamese forces captured Phnom Penh in January 1979 and
proclaimed the People's Republic of Kampuchea--a virtual satellite of
Vietnam--a few days later. This action altered Cambodia's position as a
buffer between Thailand and Vietnam. Thai and Vietnamese forces now
faced each other over a common border, and there were repeated
Vietnamese incursions into Thai territory. Moreover, a flood of refugees
from Cambodia placed great strains on Thai resources despite the
donation of emergency aid by outside nations.
As a frontline state in the Cambodian crisis, Thailand joined the
other members of ASEAN, the United States, and China in demanding a
Vietnamese withdrawal from Cambodia. In June 1982, the Thai government
extended support to the anti-Vietnamese coalition formed by Prince
Norodom Sihanouk, the Khmer Rouge's Khieu Samphan, and noncommunist
Cambodian leader Son Sann. One unforeseen benefit of the Cambodian
crisis was greatly improved relations between Thailand and China, as
both countries found themselves in confrontation with Vietnam. By 1983
China had drastically reduced aid and support for the Thai and other
Southeast Asian communist insurgencies as part of its new policy of
improved relations within the region.
Thailand
Thailand - Geography
Thailand
Thailand's 514,000 square kilometers lie in the middle of mainland
Southeast Asia. The nation's axial position influenced many aspects of
Thailand's society and culture. The earliest speakers of the Tai
language migrated from what is now China, following rivers into northern
Thailand and southward to the Mae Nam (river) Chao Phraya Valley. The
fertile floodplain and tropical monsoon climate, ideally suited to
wet-rice (thamna) cultivation, attracted settlers to this
central area rather than to the marginal uplands and mountains of the
northern region or the Khorat Plateau to the northeast. By the twelfth
century, a number of loosely connected rice-growing and trading states
flourished in the upper Chao Phraya Valley. Starting in the middle of
the fourteenth century, these central chiefdoms gradually came under the
control of the kingdom of Ayutthaya at the southern extremity of the
floodplain. Successive capitals, built at various points along the
river, became centers of great Thai kingdoms based on rice cultivation
and foreign commerce. Unlike the neighboring Khmer and Burmese, the Thai
continued to look outward across the Gulf of Thailand and the Andaman
Sea toward foreign ports of trade. When European imperialism brought a
new phase in Southeast Asian commerce in the late 1800s, Thailand (known
then as Siam) was able to maintain its independence as a buffer zone
between British-controlled Burma to the west and French-dominated
Indochina to the east.
Boundaries
Thailand in the late 1980s shared boundaries with Burma, Malaysia,
Laos, and Cambodia. Although neither China nor Vietnam bordered
Thailand, the territory of both countries came within 100 kilometers of
Thai territory. Many parts of Thailand's boundaries followed natural
features, such as the Mekong River. Most borders had been stabilized and
demarcated in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries in
accordance with treaties forced on Thailand and its neighbors by Britain
and France. In some areas, however, exact boundaries, especially along
Thailand's eastern borders with Laos and Cambodia, were still in dispute
in the late 1980s.
Disputes with Cambodia after 1950 arose in part from ill-defined
boundaries; the most notable case was a dispute over the Preah Vihear
Temple area submitted to the International Court of Justice, which ruled
in favor of Cambodia in 1962. During the years that the Cambodian
capital, Phnom Penh, was controlled by the Khmer Rouge regime of Pol Pot
(1975-79), the border disputes continued. In the early 1980s, the
People's Republic of Kampuchea and its mentor, Vietnam, made an issue of
boundaries in Prachin Buri Province in eastern Thailand. In contrast to
these incidents, which attracted international attention, boundary
disputes with Malaysia and Burma were usually handled more
cooperatively. Continuing mineral exploration and fishing in the Gulf of
Thailand, however, were sources of potential conflict with both
neighbors. Adding to general border tensions were the activities of
communist-led insurgents, whose operations had been of paramount concern
to the Thai government and its security forces for several decades. The
problem of communist insurgency was compounded by the activity of what
the Thai government labeled "antistate elements." Often the
real source of border problems was ordinary criminals or local merchants
involved in illegal mining, logging, smuggling, and narcotics production
and trade.
<"36.htm">Topography and Drainage
<"37.htm">Regions
<"38.htm">Climate
Thailand
Thailand - Topography and Drainage
Thailand
The most conspicuous features of Thailand's terrain are high
mountains, a central plain, and an upland plateau. Mountains cover much
of northern Thailand and extend along the Burmese border down through
the Malay Peninsula. The central plain is a lowland area drained by the
Chao Phraya and its tributaries, the country's principal river system,
which feeds into the delta at the head of the Bight of Bangkok. The Chao
Phraya system drains about one-third of the nation's territory. In the
northeastern part of the country the Khorat Plateau, a region of gently
rolling low hills and shallow lakes, drains into the Mekong River
through the Mae Nam Mun. The Mekong system empties into the South China
Sea and includes a series of canals and dams.
Together, the Chao Phraya and Mekong systems sustain Thailand's
agricultural economy by supporting wet-rice cultivation and providing
waterways for the transport of goods and people. In contrast, the
distinguishing natural features of peninsular Thailand are long
coastlines, offshore islands, and diminishing mangrove swamps.
Thailand
Thailand - Regions
Thailand
Landforms and drainage divide the country more or less into four
natural regions--the North, the Northeast, the Center, and the South.
Although Bangkok geographically is part of the central plain, as the
capital and largest city this metropolitan area may be considered in
other respects a separate region. Each of the four geographical regions
differs from the others in population, basic resources, natural
features, and level of social and economic development. The diversity of
the regions is in fact the most pronounced attribute of Thailand's
physical setting.
During the winter months, in the mountainous North the temperature is
cool enough for the cultivation of fruits such as lychees and
strawberries. These high mountains are incised by steep river valleys
and upland areas that border the central plain. A series of rivers,
including the Nan, Ping, Wang, and Yom, unite in the lowlands to form
the Chao Phraya watershed. Traditionally, these natural features made
possible several different types of agriculture, including wet-rice
farming in the valleys and shifting cultivation in the uplands. The
forested mountains also promoted a spirit of regional independence.
Forests, including stands of teak and other economically useful
hardwoods that once dominated the North and parts of the Northeast, had
diminished by the 1980s to 13 million hectares. In 1961 they covered 56
percent of the country, but by the mid-1980s forestland had been reduced
to less than 30 percent of Thailand's total area.
The Northeast, with its poor soils, is not favored agriculturally.
The region consists mainly of the dry Khorat Plateau and a few low
hills. The short monsoon season brings heavy flooding in the river
valleys. Unlike the more fertile areas of Thailand, the Northeast has a
long dry season, and much of the land is covered by sparse grasses.
Mountains ring the plateau on the west and the south, and the Mekong
delineates much of the eastern rim.
The "heartland" of the Central Thai, the Center is a
natural self-contained basin often termed "the rice bowl of
Asia." The complex irrigation system developed for wet-rice
agriculture in this region provided the necessary economic support to
sustain the development of the Thai state from the thirteenth-century
kingdom of Sukhothai to contemporary Bangkok. Here the rather flat
unchanging landscape facilitated inland water and road transport. The
fertile area was able to sustain a dense population, 422 persons per
square kilometer in 1987, compared with an average of 98 for the country
as a whole. The terrain of the region is dominated by the Chao Phraya
and its tributaries and by the cultivated paddy fields. Metropolitan
Bangkok, the focal point of trade, transport, and industrial activity,
is situated on the southern edge of the region at the head of the Gulf
of Thailand and includes part of the delta of the Chao Phraya system.
The South, a narrow peninsula, is distinctive in climate, terrain,
and resources. Its economy is based on rice cultivation for subsistence
and rubber production for industry. Other sources of income include
coconut plantations, tin mining, and tourism, which is particularly
lucrative on Phuket Island. Rolling and mountainous terrain and the
absence of large rivers are conspicuous features of the South.
North-south mountain barriers and impenetrable tropical forest caused
the early isolation and separate political development of this region.
International access through the Andaman Sea and the Gulf of Thailand
made the South a crossroads for both Theravada Buddhism, centered at
Nakhon Si Thammarat, and Islam, especially in the former sultanate of
Pattani on the border with Malaysia.
Thailand's regions are further divided into a total of seventy-three
provinces. The country's provinces have the same names as their
respective capitals.
Thailand
Thailand - Climate
Thailand
Thailand has a tropical monsoon climate; temperatures normally range
from an average annual high of 38� C to a low of 19� C. Southwest
monsoons that arrive between May and July (except in the South) signal
the advent of the rainy season (ridu fon), which lasts into
October. November and December mark the onset of the dry season.
Temperatures begin to climb in January, and a hot sun parches the
landscape. The dry season is shortest in the South because of the
proximity of the sea to all parts of the Malay Peninsula. With only
minor exceptions, every area of the country receives adequate rainfall,
but the duration of the rainy season and the amount of rain vary
substantially from region to region and with altitude. The Northeast
experiences a long dry season, and its red, porous (laterite) soils
retain water poorly, which limits their agricultural potential.
Thailand
Thailand - The Society
Thailand
NEITHER A STATIC nor a revolutionary society, Thailand has always
been able to harness the talents of its people, make effective use of
its natural environment, and progress at an evolutionary pace. The
tendency of the Central Thai--for centuries the controlling group in
Thai society--to eliminate or suppress ethnic or religious differences
was tempered by the Chakkri Dynasty, which had, for the most part,
fostered toleration since assuming the monarchy in 1782.
Although Thai society appeared homogeneous, it actually represented a
compromise among various groups, which, in order to preserve their own
identity, accepted certain aspects of general Thai identity, or Ekkalak
Thai. As in the past, in modern Thailand the basic social and communal
structure was controlled by a power elite system comprising the
monarchy, the military, and upper level bureaucrats. These groups had a
symbiotic relationship with the economic and business community that
strongly influenced decision making. As a result of modern education and
international influences, however, the composition of all parts of the
elite system was changing in the late 1980s.
As Thailand became more active in world trade and the international
community in general, the traditional practice of measuring status by
the extent of landholdings became less meaningful. Although the Buddhist
sangha (monastic community) and the royal family remained the
largest landholders, they were no longer the richest elements in
society. Their wealth was often surpassed by that of members of the
business community and the bureaucracy (including the military), who
derived their growing affluence from diverse sources.
Commerce and other economic endeavors had always had a place in Thai
society, but it was only in the late twentieth century that income
derived by means other than landholding became socially acceptable. In
modern Thailand, entrepreneurs, educated civil servants, and career
military officers were all accepted into the elite ranks. This expansion
of the ruling elite was reflected in the growing influence of elected
members of the National Assembly. More kinds of people had the
opportunity to participate in the shaping of Thai society after 1973;
however, the gap continued to widen between rich and poor.
As it made the transition from less developed country to
industrialized state, Thailand often was cited as one of the success
stories of the Third World. Although Thailand benefited from
modernization, being a rapidly developing nation was not without
problems and costs. One problem related to increased urbanization and a
growing market economy was the heightened desire for more consumer
products at the expense of locally made goods, services, and
recreational activities. The growing incidence of violent crime,
divorce, prostitution, and drug addiction also could be attributed in
part to increased urbanization. Modernization was also changing the
traditional ways by which individual Thai improved their economic and
social condition. A university education, for example, used to virtually
guarantee financial betterment; by the late 1980s, however, large
numbers of liberal arts graduates were either unemployed or
underemployed. Modernization also hurt the rural Thai. Previously, their
access to housing, forests, and usable water sources had been a given.
By the 1980s, however, environmental destruction and a growing scarcity
of arable land made it increasingly difficult for the rural Thai to be
relatively independent of the government.
Another cost of modernization was loss of security by some, including
the elderly and Thailand's Buddhist monks, who previously had had an
assured place in Thai society. Care of and respect for the elderly had
once been the responsibility of the immediate or extended family, but by
the 1980s Thailand was beginning to build public and private senior
citizen centers. Before World War II, the local monks and the sangha
had been the main source of advice and information; in the 1980s, civil
servants were often better equipped to attend to the needs of the people
in an increasingly urban society.
One of the greatest changes in society following World War II was the
emergence of a middle group that included affluent bureaucrats,
medium-scale entrepreneurs, educated professionals, and small
shopkeepers. The lower class included steadily employed wage workers and
unskilled laborers who worked intermittently, if at all. Those in the
middle and lower groups had not traditionally constituted self-conscious
classes; those categories were relatively new and just beginning to
develop common interests. Labor unions, for example, hopelessly divided
over political differences in the past, made active attempts to unite on
a number of issues, such as basic health and social benefits, in their
negotiations with the government and the private sector.
The peasants still comprised the majority of the population. They
were, however, much more differentiated than in the past. The peasantry
could be defined in terms of its desire for or ownership of land or
other agricultural resources, such as teak forests. The issue of
landlessness in the central plain arose in the early twentieth century
but was soon resolved by the opening of previously untilled areas in the
northern part of the country. As a result of rapid population growth in
the 1960s and 1970s, international competition in a number of Thailand's
traditional agro-economic industries, and migration to the city,
landlessness was again on the rise in the 1980s. The number of rural
Thai remained large and continued to increase. As Thailand's economy
continued to grow in the service areas of banking and tourism, more
young adults were attracted to city jobs, thus reducing the ability of
families to continue labor-intensive rice farming. At the same time,
land increased in value, and absentee landlords bought up small family
farms because there were no legally enforceable limits on the amount of
land that could be acquired.
Cutting across rural and national strata was the system of patron-
client relationships that tied specific households or individuals
together as long as both patron and client saw benefits in the
arrangement. In many respects, the dynamics of political and economic
life were comprehensible only in terms of patron-client relations.
Another traditional system of complex values and behaviors that the
majority of Thai shared through the 1980s was Theravada Buddhism.
Complementing the religion were beliefs and practices assuming the
existence of several types of spirits (phi) whose behavior was
supposed to affect human welfare. The Buddhism of the Thai villagers,
and even of poorly educated monks, often differed substantially from the
canonical religion.
<"40.htm">POPULATION
<"41.htm">ETHNICITY, REGIONALISM, AND LANGUAGE
<"50.htm">THE SOCIAL SYSTEM
<"53.htm">RELIGION
<"59.htm">EDUCATION AND THE ARTS
<"60.htm">HEALTH AND WELFARE
Thailand
Thailand - Population
Thailand
Since 1911 Thailand has taken frequent national censuses, and its
National Statistical Office, working closely with a number of
international agencies, was in the 1980s one of the most extensive
sources of statistical information in Asia. One of the 20 most populous
nations in the world, Thailand had in 1987 about 53 million people. This
total was divided about equally between males and females. The regional
breakdown was approximately 16.7 million in the Center (which included
the Bangkok metropolitan area), 17.8 million in the Northeast, 11.3
million in the North, and 6.8 million in the South. As in most Southeast
Asian nations, the population was youthful and agrarian; approximately
37 percent of the population was between the ages of 15 and 29. In the
decades after World War II, however, the percentage of agricultural
population declined; it decreased from 79.3 percent to 72.3 percent of
the population between 1970 and 1980, for example.
The shrinking of the rural population resulted in part from internal
migration to the capital and provincial centers. In 1987 about 10
percent of the population lived in Bangkok, which had 3,292 persons per
square kilometer. The 9 largest cities after Bangkok ranged in
population from 80,000 to 110,000. They were Khon Kaen, Hat Yai, Chiang
Mai, Ubon Ratchathani, Nakhon Sawan, Nakhon Ratchasima, Krabi, Udon
Thani, and Songkhla.
Bangkok, with 1,537 square kilometers, represented the combining of
the royal capital of the Chakkri Dynasty with Thon Buri, the capital of
King Taksin. In the late 1980s, this urban area was made up of 24
districts (khet), with a combined population of 5.5 million. In
spite of massive construction and changes in the economy, many of the
districts retained their unique identities. For example, Dusit District,
where the royal family had its principal residence, was also home to
many of the city's military officers and civil servants.
Rapid urbanization in the 1980s was changing not only where the Thai
lived but also how they lived. Separate private houses were located in
high-density areas or out in new sprawling suburbs. The Thai were also
moving into townhouses and condominiums; by 1984 sixty-nine residential
condominium communities had been built or were in the final phase of
construction. A family compound along a tree-shaded khlong
(canal) was a rare sight. Although ferries continued to ply the Chao
Phraya, the boat was no longer the main mode of transportation. Bangkok
had about 900,000 registered motor vehicles and a new superhighway
system partially completed in the late 1980s; massive traffic jams,
noise, and air pollution had become part of everyday life. Most of the
canals in the "Venice of the East" had been replaced with
roads; this replacement was in part causing the city to sink. Annual
flooding in the city and growing slums such as Khlong Toei often made
city services rather than politics the key issue in metropolitan
elections. Bangkok had 10 percent of the national population, but the
capital required a disproportionate percentage of the national budget to
maintain basic city services.
Thailand's rush both to develop and to satisfy the demand for
consumer products had several side effects, including dwindling
agricultural land, the destruction of forests, and damage to watersheds.
These consequences prompted the central government, with support from
international agencies, to make a concerted effort to limit population
growth. In 1968 the cabinet sanctioned a family-planning service, and by
March 1970 a national population policy was announced. The official
slogan "Many Children Make You Poor" and the economic
arguments for keeping the number of children at two per family found
acceptance among both city and rural populations. Successful programs
were undertaken by the Planned Parenthood Association of Thailand and
the Family Planning Services. By 1974 an estimated 25 percent of all
married couples of childbearing age were using modern contraceptives,
one of the highest percentages for developing countries. The population
growth rate, 3.4 percent per annum in the 1960s, had been reduced to 1.9
percent per annum by 1986. The goal for the late 1980s was a growth rate
of 1.5 percent.
<"41.htm">Ethnicity,
Regionalism and Language
Updated population figures for Thailand.
Thailand
Thailand - Ethnicity, Regionalism and Language
Thailand
Although the population was relatively homogeneous in the 1980s--an
estimated 85 percent or more spoke a language of the Tai family and
shared other cultural features, such as adherence to Theravada
Buddhism--regionalism and ethnic differences were socially and
politically significant. Moreover, these differences affected the access
of specific groups and regions to economic and other resources, which in
turn heightened ethnic or regional consciousness.
Perhaps the principal fact of regional and ethnic relations was the
social, linguistic, and political dominance of the Central Thai, who
were descendants of the subjects of the premodern kingdoms of the Chao
Phraya floodplain. The Central Thai were defined as those who considered
central Thailand their birthplace or the Central Thai (Standard Thai)
dialect their first language. With the advent of increased migration,
modern communication, and education, however, it was becoming
increasingly difficult to use language to determine place of origin.
The Central Thai constituted but one of the regionally defined
categories that made up the majority of Thai--the core Thai. The number
of persons belonging to groups other than the core Thai was difficult to
specify precisely, whether membership in those groups was defined by
language, by other features of culture, or by an individual's
self-identification. Part of the problem was the Thai government's
policy of promoting assimilation but not encouraging the active
collection of data on Thai ethnicity. Government statistics on aliens,
tribal minorities, and refugees were more readily available, although
sometimes disputed by both scholars and the groups in question.
Despite the inadequacy of the data, it was possible to make some
rough estimates of the ethnic composition of the minority sector of the
Thai population in 1987. Among the largest minority groups, Chinese
constituted about 11 percent of the population, Malay about 3 percent,
and long-term resident (as opposed to refugee) Khmer less than 1
percent. The remaining minority groups ranged in number from a few
hundred to more than 100,000. Of these, the largest group was the Karen,
estimated at about 250,000 in the 1980s. Some of the minority groups
spoke languages of the Tai family but differed in several ways from the
core Thai.
<"42.htm">The Thai and Other Tai-Speaking Peoples
<"43.htm">The Non-Tai Minorities
<"44.htm">The Highland, or Hill, Peoples
<"45.htm">The Khmer
<"46.htm">The Mon
<"47.htm">The Vietnamese
<"48.htm">The Chinese
<"49.htm">Ethnic and Regional Relations
More about the <"40.htm">Population
of Thailand.
Thailand
Thailand - The Thai and Other Tai-Speaking Peoples
Thailand
The core Thai--the Central Thai, the Northeastern Thai (Thai-Lao),
the Northern Thai, and the Southern Thai--spoke dialects of one of the
languages of the Tai language family. The peoples who spoke those
languages--generically also referred to as Tai--originated in southern
China, but they were dispersed throughout mainland Southeast Asia from
Burma to Vietnam. It was conventional in the 1980s to refer to
Tai-speaking peoples in Thailand as Thai (same pronunciation) with a
regional or other qualifier, e.g., Central Thai. There were, however,
groups in Thailand in the late twentieth century who spoke a language of
the Tai family but who were not part of the core population.
Although the four major Tai-speaking groups taken together clearly
constituted the overwhelming majority of Thailand's population, it was
not entirely clear what proportion of the core Thai fell into each of
the regional categories. Among the reasons for the uncertainty were the
movements of many who were not Central Thai in origin into the Bangkok
area and its environs and the movement of Central Thai, perhaps in
smaller numbers, into other regions as administrators, educators,
technicians, bureaucrats, soldiers, and sometimes as settlers. The
Central Thai, of generally higher status than the general populace,
tended to retain their identities wherever they lived, whereas those
from other regions migrating to the central plain might seek to take on
Central Thai speech, customs, and identity.
Although politically, socially, and culturally dominant, the Central
Thai did not constitute a majority of the population and barely exceeded
the Thai-Lao in numbers, according to a mid-1960s estimate. At that
time, the Central Thai made up roughly 32 percent of the population,
with the Thai-Lao a close second at about 30 percent. The Thai-Lao were
essentially the same ethnic group that constituted the dominant
population of Laos, although they far outnumbered the population of that
country.
A number of linguistic scholars mark the reign of King Narai
(1657-88) as the point when the Central Thai (or Ayutthaya Thai) dialect
was established as the standard to which other forms or dialects were
compared. Central Thai was the required form used in modern Thailand for
official, business, academic, and other daily transactions. From
Ayutthayan times, Central Thai borrowed words from Khmer, Pali, and
Sanskrit. Thailand still maintained a court language called Phasa
Ratchasap, although King Bhumibol Adulyadej (Rama IX, 1946- ) encouraged
the use of Central Thai. Similarly, Pali, the religious language,
although still used, gradually was being replaced by Central Thai for
many ceremonies and writings. Although the Thai Royal Academy was the
final arbiter of new words added to the language, post-World War II Thai
has been influenced heavily by American English, especially in the area
of science and technology.
Increasingly, Central Thai was spoken with varied fluency all over
the country as the education system reached larger numbers of children.
Nevertheless, regional dialects (or their local variants) remained the
language of the home and of the local community. Learning Central Thai
is not a simple matter. The dialects of the four regional components of
the core population are only mutually intelligible with difficulty.
There are lexical and syntactic differences as well as differences in
pronunciation.
Differences in dialect were sometimes an irritant in relations
between those whose native tongue was Central Thai and persons from
other regions. On the one hand, if persons migrating from other regions
to Bangkok spoke their own dialect, they might be treated with contempt
by the Central Thai. If, on the other hand, such persons failed to speak
Central Thai with sufficient fluency and a proper accent, that, too,
could lead to their being treated disrespectfully.
Generally, before the trend toward homogenization of dress, language,
and forms of entertainment fostered by modern communication, there were
regional differences in costume, folklore, and other aspects of culture
among the Thai people. The continuing retention of these differences
into the 1980s seemed to be a function of relative remoteness from
Bangkok and other urban areas. Of some importance, according to
observers, was the tendency to cling to, and even accentuate, these
regional differences as symbols of a sense of grievance.
In the past, some Thai governments put great pressure on the various
Thai peoples to forsake regional customs and dialects for
"modern" Central Thai culture. In the 1980s, however, there
was a rebirth of the study and teaching of local languages, especially
Lanna Thai in the North and also the Southern Thai dialect. Efforts were
also made to expose all Thai to the different cultures and traditions of
the various regions through regional translation and art programs. At
the same time, Central Thai became more readily accepted as a second
language. The success of the national identity programs could be
explained in part by the Thai literacy rate, one of the highest in Asia.
The Tai-speaking peoples of the Northeast, known as Thai-Lao or Isan,
live on the Khorat Plateau. Once the weakest in Thailand, the
Northeast's economy started to improve somewhat in the 1970s because of
irrigation and energy projects, such as the construction of the Khuan
Ubon Ratana (Nam Phong Dam). Moreover, because the Northeast was the
location of several United States military bases during the Second
Indochina War (1954-75), the region had one of the best transportation
systems in Asia, which facilitated internal migration as well as
communication with Bangkok. Historically, this area relied heavily on
border trade with Laos and Cambodia; in 1987 the Thai government
permitted increased Laotian border commerce and lifted a ban on the
export of all but 61 of 273 "strategic" items previously
barred from leaving Thailand. Also, traditional handicrafts, e.g., silk
weavings and mats, increasingly were being sold outside the region to
produce extra income. Still, approximately 82 percent of the region's
labor force was involved in agriculture.
In terms of language and culture, both the Northeastern Thai and the
Northern Thai were closer to the peoples of Laos than to the Central
Thai. Speakers of the Tai language of Kham Mu'ang (known as Yuan in its
written form) made up the majority of the population of the 9
northernmost provinces from the Burmese-Lao border down through the
province of Uttaradit, an area of about 102,000 square kilometers.
Highly independent, the Northern Thai lived mainly in small river
valleys where they grew glutinous rice as their staple food. The Chakkri
Dynasty continued to maintain a court in Chiang Mai, the largest city of
the North, which the Thai people looked to as a major religious and
cultural center.
The fourteen provinces of the South made up the poorest region of
Thailand. Primarily rural, the South had an urban population of only
12.2 percent of its total inhabitants. Although rice was the staple
food, the South's economy was not based on wet-rice agriculture. Never
directly colonized, the southern provinces, with their dependence on
rubber and tin production and fishing, had nonetheless long been
vulnerable to international economic forces. As world market prices for
rubber and tin declined in the 1970s, more southerners went to work in
the Middle East; and as neighboring countries established 200-mile
limits on their territorial waters, an increasing number of Thai fishing
vessels could be found as far away as the coast of Australia.
In 1985 there were more than 6 million Southern Thai. Malay
vocabulary was used in the Southern Thai dialect, and Malay in Jawi
(Arabic) script remained in many instances the medium of written
communication. Like the other regions of Thailand, the South at times
opposed the central government. Following the closer incorporation of
the Pattani region into the Thai kingdom as the result of the provincial
administrative reform of 1902, reactions in the form of rebellions,
underground movements, and violent uprisings were common. For many
years, any type of antistate behavior or banditry reported by the
government or press was usually attributed either to Muslim insurgents
or the Communist Party of Thailand. By the mid-1980s, the press and
government had become more objective in reporting and recognizing
problems caused by environmental factors, other groups, and government
policies. Moreover, the Muslim leadership, together with progressive
political and military forces in the Thai government, had begun
addressing some of the problems of the South, which led to increased
national tranquillity.
Of the more than 85 percent of the country's population that spoke a
language of the Tai family, only a small fraction constituted the
membership of the half-dozen or so ethnic groups outside the core Thai.
These groups lived in the North or Northeast and were often closely
related to ethnic groups in neighboring countries. In Thailand, the
largest of these Tai-speaking minorities were the Phutai (or Phuthai) of
the far Northeast, who numbered about 100,000 in the mid-1960s. There
were also many Phutai in neighboring Laos. The Phuan and the Saek, also
in the Northeast and with kin in Laos, were similar but much smaller
groups. Whereas all other Tai languages spoken in Thailand belonged to
the southwestern branch of the family, that spoken by the Saek belonged
to the northern branch, suggesting a more recent arrival from China. The
Khorat Thai were not considered Central Thai, despite their close
resemblance in language and dress, because they and others tended to
identify them as a separate group. The Khorat Thai were said to be
descendants of Thai soldiers and Khmer women. The Shan (a Burmese term)
in the North were part of a much larger group, the majority of whom
lived in Burma, while others lived in China. Different groups of the
Shan called themselves by names in which the term Tai was
modified by a word meaning "great" or something similar. The
Thai called them Thai Ngio or Thai Yai. Also in the North were a people
called the Lue, estimated in the mid-1960s to number less than 50,000.
Like the Shan, they resided in greater numbers elsewhere, particularly
in southern China.
Thailand
Thailand - The Non-Tai Minorities
Thailand
Besides the Tai-speaking minorities, there were a number of peoples
speaking languages of other families (although increasing numbers were
acquainted with a Thai dialect, especially Central Thai, if they
acquired the language in school). Some--such as the Khmer in the eastern
portion of the country, the Karen in the northern and western parts of
Thailand, and the Malay in the South--found themselves within the
boundaries of Thailand as a consequence of conflict and shifting
borders. Others, such as many of the hill peoples, were relatively
recent migrants from China and the Indochinese Peninsula. They found
their way to the peripheries of Thailand either in search of land or to
escape political turmoil. Groups entering Thailand that had been
minorities in their countries of origin, as hill peoples typically were,
became more or less permanent residents of Thailand, although still
largely unassimilated. Others, particularly the Mon, who lived in the
central region, became substantially integrated. The groups of
Vietnamese who had arrived for various reasons from the nineteenth
through the mid-twentieth centuries varied in the extent to which they
were rooted in Thailand. Some groups of Khmer, refugees from political
turmoil in their own country since 1975, were also recent arrivals in
Thailand. Finally, there were the Chinese. Of the estimated 6 million in
Thailand in 1987, most could be differentiated by the region of China
from which they came, when they had arrived, and the extent to which
they had been assimilated into Thai society.
Thailand
Thailand - The Highland, or Hill, Peoples
Thailand
Commonly included among the highland people were the ethnic groups
living in the mountains of northern and northwestern Thailand in the
area known, because of its illegal opium production, as the "Golden
Triangle." Until the 1970s, the Thai central government tended to
regard these groups chiefly as opium cultivators engaged in illegal
activities. Since that time the highland minorities, through their own
efforts and government-organized crop substitution projects, have become
involved in the legal market economy of the country.
Among the larger groups of highland people were the Karen (Kariang,
Yang), Hmong (Meo, Miao), Mien (Yao), Lahu (Mussur), Akha (Kaw), and
Lisu, or Lisaw. Some of the smaller groups preceded the Tai-speaking
peoples in the area, but many were relative latecomers. Through natural
increase and immigration, the population of the highlands increased from
approximately 100,000 in 1948 to about 700,000 in the late 1980s,
according to Ministry of Interior estimates. This population growth led
to a significant increase in the number of landless people in the
highlands. As a result, many of the landless began cultivating forest
reserves, thereby accelerating the depletion of the country's
forestland.
The varying estimates for specific groups in some cases reflected the
tendency of estimators to include only those still living in relatively
isolated mountain communities, whereas other observers might include
some or all of those who had come down from the mountains and were at
various points in the process of becoming Thai. Observers noted that for
some groups, more individuals were in the process of assimilation than
remained in the mountain communities that were their traditional homes.
The languages spoken by the hill peoples fell into three broad
categories: Tibeto-Burman (a subfamily of the larger Sino-Tibetan
language family), Mon-Khmer (a subfamily of the Austro-Asiatic language
family), and the small Miao-Yao language family. The language of the
most numerous of these hill peoples, the Karen, was generally considered
Sino-Tibetan, but some authorities included it in the subset
Tibeto-Burman, or placed it in a category of its own. The other
languages included in the Tibeto-Burman category--Akha, Lisu, Lahu, and
Jinghpaw (Kachin)--have been estimated as ranging from a few hundred
speakers (Jinghpaw) to about 25,000 speakers (Akha).
The category of Mon-Khmer included a number of highland groups: the
Kui (called Soai by the Thai), which totaled between 100,000 and 150,000
in the mid-1960s; the Tin, about 20,000; and several smaller groups,
including the Lua (also called Lawa), about 9,000; the Khmu, about
7,600; and the Chaobon, about 2,000. The Kui were said to be largely
assimilated into Thai society. The figure for the Khmu pertained only to
those presumably living in the highlands in a more or less traditional
setting. Substantial numbers were said to be pursuing a Thai way of
life.
The Miao-Yao languages were spoken by two peoples, the Hmong and
Mien, both originally from China (the terms Miao and Yao
are Chinese). There were Hmong and Mien still living in China as well as
other Southeast Asian countries. Called Meo by the Thai, the Hmong began
to arrive in Thailand in the late nineteenth century, and some continued
to migrate directly from China or other neighboring states, particularly
Laos. Numbering about 50,000 in 1970, the Hmong were one of the largest
groups of hill peoples. An additional 40,000 Hmong fled from Laos to
Thailand in 1975, but by the late 1980s many of these had migrated
elsewhere, some going to the United States. The Mien were even more
recent arrivals, most of them having come from Laos after 1945. Their
numbers were estimated at 30,000 in the 1980s. These two groups,
particularly the Hmong, were among those affected by the security
operations of the Thai government that began in the mid-1960s. These
actions occurred in part because the Hmong, like other mountain groups,
were said to be destroying forests in the course of practicing their
traditional shifting cultivation, and in part because their chief cash
crop was the opium poppy.
Thailand
Thailand - The Khmer
Thailand
Two groups of Khmer could also be distinguished--long-time
inhabitants of Thailand and more recent arrivals. By the midfifteenth
century, much of the western region of the Khmer Empire had come under
the control of Ayutthaya. Many of the Khmer peoples remained in the area
that had come under Thai domination. Five centuries later the protracted
civil conflict in Cambodia, which began with the overthrow of the Lon
Nol regime in 1975 and included the Vietnam-supported overthrow of the
Pol Pot regime in 1979, led to the arrival at the Thai-Cambodian border
of additional hundreds of thousands of Khmer. Some Khmer had crossed
over into Thailand; many others might be expected to do so if several
political obstacles were overcome.
Theravada Buddhists and wet-rice cultivators, the Khmer spoke a
language of the Mon-Khmer group and were heirs to a long and complex
political and cultural tradition. If long-term resident Khmer and Khmer
refugees were both included, there were perhaps as many as 600,000 to
800,000 Khmer living in Thailand in the 1980s. Many of the long-resident
Khmer were said to speak Thai, sometimes as a first language, and
religious and other similarities contributed over time to Thai-Khmer
intermarriage and to Khmer assimilation into Thai society. Newly arrived
Khmer, however, were not yet assimilated.
Thailand
Thailand - The Mon
Thailand
Perhaps the first Theravada Buddhists in Southeast Asia, and the
founders in the seventh century of the kingdom of Haripunjaya near
present-day Chiang Mai, the Mon greatly influenced the development of
Thai culture. Mon architecture dotted the North, where a number of
temples were still inhabited by Mon monks in the 1980s. The Mon, also
known as Raman or Tailaing, migrated from Burma during the sixteenth to
eighteenth centuries. They were welcomed by the Chakkri rulers, and
their religious discipline helped inspire the reforms made by King
Mongkut (Rama IV, reigned 1851-68). The Mon who settled chiefly in the
North and the central plain, e.g., at Nonthaburi, Ayutthaya, Lop Buri,
Uthai Thani, and Ratchaburi, generally were wet-rice farmers who also
had specialized skills such as pottery-making. They maintained a social
organization similar to that of the Thai and other lowland cultures.
Their villages were governed by Mon headmen, who in turn were
responsible to district and provincial officers of Mon ancestry.
Although their language was related to Khmer, the Mon incorporated a
large number of Thai words into their vocabulary. Moreover, language
differences became less important as Mon children, educated in Thai
schools, learned Central Thai. In the 1980s, some Mon still used their
own language in certain contexts, but few did not know Thai. In general,
the Mon were more integrated into Thai society than any other non-Thai
group.
Thailand
Thailand - The Vietnamese
Thailand
In the mid-1970s, the number of Vietnamese in Thailand was estimated
at between 60,000 and 70,000, most of them in the Northeast. Three broad
categories of Vietnamese were in the country. The first were the
descendants of persons who fled from political upheaval and persecution
during the precolonial era in the late eighteenth century and through
much of the nineteenth century. Most of them settled either in Bangkok
or in the area southeast of it, and many of their descendants were
absorbed into Thai society, although some still lived in villages that
were identifiably Vietnamese. Many who came in the nineteenth century
were refugees from anti-Catholic persecution by rulers in Cochinchina
(southern Vietnam, around the Mekong Delta) before the French
established political control over that area. The second category
consisted of persons who opposed the establishment of French domination
over all Vietnam in 1884 and presumably expected their stay in Thailand
to be short. With some exceptions, however, their descendants and those
of other Vietnamese who came to Thailand in the first decades of the
twentieth century remained. The earliest arrivals in this category, like
their predecessors, mostly came to southeast Thailand. Later immigrants
tended to go to the Northeast. The third category included those who
fled from Vietnam between the end of World War II in 1945 and the
consolidation of North Vietnamese rule over all of Vietnam in 1975. For
those who came after the Second Indochina War had ended, Thailand was
simply a way station en route to somewhere else, usually the United
States.
Most of the 40,000 to 50,000 Vietnamese who came in 1946 and shortly
thereafter were driven from Laos by the French, who were then reimposing
their rule over all of Indochina. More Vietnamese came later, and, like
those who came in the 1920s and 1930s, they expected to return to
Vietnam. Between 1958 and 1964 (when the intensification of the war in
Vietnam inhibited their return), arrangements were made for the
repatriation of Vietnamese to the Democratic Republic of Vietnam (North
Vietnam), and an estimated 40,000 left Thailand. Over the years a few
families went to the Republic of Vietnam (South Vietnam). The movements
of this period, both voluntary and involuntary, left between 60,000 and
70,000 Vietnamese in Thailand, an undetermined portion of which were
post-World War II migrants who could not or would not return to their
homeland.
Thailand
Thailand - The Chinese
Thailand
The largest number of non-Tai peoples were the Chinese. In 1987 an
estimated 11 percent of the total Thai population, or about 6 million
people, were of Chinese origin, which meant that Thailand had the
largest Chinese population in Southeast Asia. Assimilation of the
various Chinese communities was a continuing process. Chinese were
encouraged to become Thai citizens, and in 1970 it was estimated that
more than 90 percent of the Chinese born in Thailand had done so. When
diplomatic relations were established with China in the 1970s, resident
Chinese not born in Thailand had the option of becoming Thai citizens;
the remaining permanent Chinese alien population was estimated at fewer
than 200,000.
Given their historic role as middlemen, Chinese were found everywhere
in Thailand, particularly in the towns. There was, however, a major
concentration in the Bangkok metropolitan area and another in the
central part of peninsular Thailand, where many Chinese were engaged in
several capacities in the tin mines and on the rubber plantations.
Although many Chinese played an important part in the ownership and
management of economic enterprises and in the professions, a substantial
portion had less lucrative and significant occupations.
Except for a minority, the Chinese not only were Thai nationals but
also had, in some respects at least, assimilated into Thai society; many
spoke Thai as well as they spoke Chinese. Most of the descendants of
pretwentieth-century immigrants and those people of mixed Chinese-Thai
ancestry (the so-called Sino-Thai) were so fully integrated into Thai
society that they were not included in the Chinese population estimates.
The accommodation between Thai and Chinese historically depended in
part on the changing economic and political interests and perspectives
of the Thai monarchs and others in the ruling group. Also relevant were
the roles assigned to the Chinese at various times, e.g., in the
nineteenth century, that of tax farmers. Under the tax farming system,
private individuals were sold the right to collect taxes at a price
below the actual value of the taxes. The barriers between Thai and
Chinese became more rigid in the early twentieth century with the
emergence of Thai and Chinese nationalism and also the increased
tendency of Chinese females to accompany male immigrants, which reduced
the amount of intermarriage. Consequently, despite a level of Chinese
integration in the host society surpassing that found elsewhere in
Southeast Asia, the Chinese remained a separate ethnic community,
although the boundaries became less defined in the more mobile
post-World War II society. The Chinese spoke a number of southern
Chinese dialects, the most important being Teochiu, which was used by
most Chinese as a commercial lingua franca.
Thailand
Thailand - Ethnic and Regional Relations
Thailand
In the past, the government took the position that all Tai people
should be accorded all the rights, privileges, and opportunities that
went with being a citizen. In the 1980s, members of non-Tai minority
groups were being afforded similar rights, and efforts were being made
to incorporate them into the Ekkalak Thai. The higher a person's
aspirations, however, the more thoroughly he or she needed to assimilate
into Central Thai culture. Thus, most of the representatives of the
government were either from Central Thailand or had absorbed the
perspective of that region.
By law the Central Thai dialect was taught in all government schools,
and all who aspired to government positions, from village headman on up,
were expected to master Central Thai. Nonetheless, because local
dialects remained the medium of communication in schools, markets, and
provincial government offices, differences between the Central Thai and
other dialects survived. The Central Thai tended to see other Thai as
both different and inferior. In turn, the latter saw the Central Thai as
exploiters. Inevitably, many non-Central Thai sometimes felt inferior to
the Central Thai, who represented progress, prestige, wealth, and
national power.
In the past, the government had often ignored the needs of the
outlying regions. Neglect, corrupt administration, and heavy taxation
perhaps affected the Thai-Lao more than others. Until King Mongkut
established central control through administrators in the nineteenth
century, the Thai-Lao region was governed by local Lao princes who were
really vassals of the Thai monarch. Corvee (forced) labor and oppressive
taxation supported a rapidly expanding Thai court, bureaucracy, and
military. Peasant revolts erupted and were suppressed. Real social and
economic changes did not began until the reign of King Bhumibol, who in
the early 1960s was assisted in these efforts by Prime Minister Sarit
Thanarat, a northeasterner. In the 1960s, programs of community and
agricultural development were coupled with counterinsurgency measures;
these efforts continued into the 1980s with mixed results.
The problems had accumulated over time, and solutions were difficult.
Whether the tensions and the potential for conflict between the central
government and the Thai-Lao could be understood solely or even largely
in ethnic terms was questionable. Besides ethnicity and regionalism, a
number of other factors required consideration, including the inadequacy
of most economic reform measures and the insensitivity or repressiveness
of administrators. The Central Thai lack of understanding of social
forms and practices different from their own contributed to the
mishandling of local situations and the imposition of so-called reforms
without full consideration of the effects of these changes on the local
people. The Thai-Lao had a close cultural and linguistic relationship
with the people of Laos that was further strengthened by trade and
kinship. Laos was viewed by many northeasterners as their home country.
In the South the language, religion, and culture of the Malay or Thai
Muslims were markedly different from those of other Thai. Although
Islamic religious and cultural practices accentuated the differences,
more divisive and destabilizing were economic and political factors. In
the past, Central Thai administrators from the national government
assigned to the South often spent their time amassing personal fortunes
rather than attending to the welfare of the people of the region.
Government provision of health, education, and welfare services was
inadequate or nonexistent; schools were established only in the cities,
for the benefit of children of Central Thai officials. In the 1980s,
King Bhumibol and government leaders, especially those from the South,
were deeply involved in rectifying those inequalities, but resentment
and suspicion hampered development.
Substantial numbers of Malay were loyalists who saw no point in
making impossible demands. They were prepared to work within the system
toward amelioration of their economic, educational, and administrative
situation. Those Malay were not prepared to become Thai culturally, but
they saw government programs, including secular education in Thai-
language schools, as a means to social mobility and to an expansion of
their administrative and economic roles.
Because of severe restrictions on Chinese immigration that were put
into effect in the early 1950s, the great majority of Thailand's Chinese
in the late 1980s had been born in Thailand. Not only did most Chinese
speak Thai, many also acquired Thai names (in addition to their Chinese
ones) and were Mahayana Buddhists (one of the major schools of Buddhism,
active in China, Japan, Korea, and Nepal). Although many Thai resented
the significant role the Chinese played in commerce and envied their
wealth, the Thai also admired Chinese industriousness and business
acumen, a pattern common elsewhere in Southeast Asia.
Thailand
Thailand - THE SOCIAL SYSTEM
Thailand
The rural areas, where most Thai live, have been affected by change
for many decades, especially since the mid-nineteenth century, when the
impact of European economic and political activity was first felt. The
full effects of change started to become manifest in the 1930s. Among
the factors reflecting and creating change in local social patterns was
the coup of 1932, which brought military and bureaucratic elites into
power and extended the power of the central government more effectively
than before into rural areas. More important in its cumulative effect,
however, was the rapid growth of the population and the consequent
shortage of land, which led to the development of occupations outside
agriculture and the emergence of a rural and small-town bourgeoisie.
At the national level, society was stratified at the beginning of the
twentieth century into three classes--kin of the reigning king and his
immediate predecessors, government officials (often nobles granted their
particular status by the king), and, by far the largest group, the
peasantry. These classes comprised a social system in which those who
had political power and status also had prestige and access to wealth.
Buddhist monks had a special status outside this system. Also outside
the system were the Chinese, who were largely laborers and small traders
in the early twentieth century.
As the twentieth century progressed, the government bureaucracy
proliferated. A growing number in the higher ranks had their origins
outside the hereditary nobility, as did the upper ranks of the expanding
armed forces. By the 1960s, the military and the bureaucracy included
persons from several levels of the social and economic hierarchy.
Directly or indirectly, the military and bureaucratic elites disposed of
power and economic resources, the latter often in combination with those
Chinese who controlled the major business enterprises of Thailand.
Hereditary nobles retained high status, but they no longer wielded power
and did not match some of the members of the military oligarchy in
wealth. Monkhood remained a source of special status and was an avenue
of social mobility for persons of rural origin with talent and a
willingness to give part or all of their lives to the sangha;
but monkhood was less and less attractive to urbanites or to those who
had access to other avenues to power, wealth, and status. After World
War II, an incipient urban middle class and an urban proletariat also
emerged, particularly in Bangkok, partly in response to a commercial and
tourist boom generated by the presence of large numbers of foreigners,
particularly Americans.
Still outside the social system, in the sense that their direct
access to political power was restricted and that their sense of a
worthwhile career differed from that of most Thai, were the Chinese.
Members of other non-Thai ethnic groups could occasionally make a place
for themselves in the middle or upper reaches of Thai society by
assimilating Thai culture. The Chinese were less able to do so until the
1960s and 1970s, when they began to move into the upper bureaucracy in
larger numbers.
More significant in the daily life of many Thai than differences in
status was the relationship between patron and client. This link between
two specific persons required the client to render services and other
kinds of support in return for protection, the use of the patron's
influence on the client's behalf, and occasional favors or financial
aid. The basic pattern was old, but the relationship had evolved from a
social one with economic overtones to one in which economic transactions
and political support were more important.
<"51.htm">Rural Social Patterns
<"52.htm">National and Urban Structures: Class and Status
Thailand
Thailand - Rural Social Patterns
Thailand
Certain basic rural social patterns were discernable in modern Thai
society. According to United States anthropologist Jack M. Potter,
"The spatially defined rural village, which receives the allegiance
of its members, furnishes an important part of their social identity,
manages its own affairs and communal property, and has its own temple
and school, is present in all parts of Thailand as an ideal cultural
model, although in many cases the actual form of community life only
approximates it."
Affecting the degree to which specific communities approached the
model were "ecological, economic and demographic circumstances and
the nature of rural administration," Potter writes. In the densely
settled central plain, villages were often spatially indistinct,
although boundaries defined by patterns of marriage, wat
(Buddhist religious complex) attendance, and other social factors might
be discerned. In other cases, some of the important features of a
functioning community were lacking. Thus, if the proportion of
nonlandholders was high and if landowners were absentee and did not
provide the social or political leadership typically supplied by wealthy
local peasants, community structure was weak.
The wat in the 1980s remained the center of the rural
community in many respects, although some of its functions, e.g., as an
educational center, were lost, and it was increasingly difficult to
retain monks. Most rural communities built and maintained a wat
because, as Potter states, the Thai consider it "necessary for a
civilized social existence." The wat included the special
quarters and facilities reserved for monks, a building for public
worship and religious ceremony, and a community meeting place.
Typically, the wat was run by a temple committee that consisted
of prominent laymen as well as monks who had left the sangha
without prejudice. Abbots and senior monks often enjoyed considerable
prestige. In times of personal crisis, people often sought their advice.
The wat was first of all a center for religious ceremony,
much of which was regularly carried out according to a ritual calendar.
These scheduled rites involved the community as a whole, even if their
ultimate purpose was the acquisition of merit by individuals. Other
irregularly held rites also took place in the wat and almost
always included the community or a significant segment of it. The temple
was also the locus for astrological and other quasi-magical activities.
Although such rites were outside the canon of Buddhism, they were
important to the community and were often carried out by monks. Thus, a
person would go to a monk versed in these matters to learn the
propitious day for certain undertakings (for example, a wedding) or to
be cured of certain illnesses by the application of holy water. A large wat
usually had a crematorium; almost all dead were cremated.
The temple committee often administered a loan fund from which the
poor of the community might borrow in emergencies. The wat was
also the repository of mats, dishes, and other housewares that could be
borrowed by members of the community. If an aged person had nowhere else
to go, the wat was a refuge. The wat was not reserved
solely for serious matters; entertainment and dances open to the
community were also held there.
Within the village in the 1980s, the basic organizational unit was
the family, which changed its character in the course of a developmental
cycle. A nuclear family became, in time, a larger unit, but the death of
the older generation once again left a nuclear family. Typically, a man
went to live with the parents of the woman he married. Such residence
was temporary except in the case of the youngest daughter. She and her
husband (and their unmarried children) remained with her parents,taking
care of them in their old age and inheriting the house when they died.
Thus, at some point in the cycle, the household included what has been
referred to as a matrilineal extended stem family: the aging parents,
their youngest daughter and her husband, and the younger couple's
children.
Emerging from this developmental cycle was a cluster of related and
cooperating households consisting of the extended stem family household
and the households of those daughters who had settled nearby with their
husbands. That pattern was predicated on the continuing control over
land and other resources by the senior couple. The closeness of these
related households and the extent of their cooperation in a range of
domestic activities varied considerably. With a growing shortage of
arable land in parts of the country and the aggregation of substantial
holdings by a limited number of landowners, the pattern was no longer as
common as it had been. The senior couple may have had little or no land
to allocate to their older daughters, and the daughters and their
husbands may have had to move elsewhere. In the case of wholly landless
agricultural workers, even the extended stem family might not be
possible.
Most villages were divided into local units or neighborhoods. In the
North, neighborhoods were often the entities that on a weekly basis
collectively provided food for the monks in the local wat, but
these neighborhoods also engaged in other forms of cooperation. Inasmuch
as the nucleus of a neighborhood, perhaps all of it, often consisted of
related households, activities such as house-raisings might be
undertaken in response to either territorial or kinship requirements. If
the community was the result of relatively recent pioneering by landless
families from other communities, the neighborhood was important, and
those living in the same area might come to address each other in
kinship terms.
The labor exchange system was initially based on villagers' relative
parity in landholding and their participation in subsistence
agriculture. Typically, those involved in an exchange system were kin or
neighbors, but the system sometimes extended beyond these categories.
Each household arranged with others to provide labor at various stages
in the agricultural cycle; in return, the same number of units of labor
would be provided to those who had worked for it. Besides a labor
exchange, the system provided opportunities for socializing and
feasting. Although the arrangements were made by a single household with
other specific households, the regularity with which representatives of
households worked together gave the households a grouplike character.
The growing commercialization of agriculture in certain parts of the
country and increasing landlessness and tenancy in the 1980s diminished
the ubiquity of reciprocal work arrangements. Wealthy peasants hired
labor; those who had no land or too little to subsist on worked for
wages. Commercialization alone, however, did not prevent the use of a
labor exchange system if those in it held roughly equivalent amounts of
land. In some cases, a household would hire labor for one task and
engage in the exchange system for others.
Peasants could be categorized on the basis of the nature of their
land rights and the quantity of the land they held. The holdings that
made a peasant family rich in one part of Thailand might not make it
rich elsewhere. A rich rural family was one with substantial
landholdings, some of which it might rent out. Moreover, if a family had
the capital to hire agricultural labor and the implements necessary to
cultivate additional land, it might rent plots from others. In any case,
such a family would rely almost exclusively on hired labor rather than
on the system of labor exchange, and it was likely to invest in other
local enterprises, such as rice mills, thereby acquiring additional
sources of income. The category of rich peasants could be subdivided
into those with very large quantities of land and those with smaller but
still substantial amounts. Usually that distinction would correlate with
the magnitude of their nonfarming enterprises and the extent to which
they had money to lend to others. In any case, rich peasants tended to
be creditors, while other peasants were often debtors.
At the other end of the scale were the agricultural laborers, who
held no land as owners or tenants except, perhaps, for the small plot on
which their houses stood. To the extent that opportunities were
available, they supported themselves as hired farm workers. Life was so
precarious for some families, however, that they had to resort to
hunting and gathering. Between the wealthy peasants and agricultural
workers were two other categories. The families in the first group had
sufficient land (some of it rented) to meet their own rice needs. If
there were a crop surplus, it would be sold, but the families in this
category did not produce primarily for the market, as the rich peasants
did. They might also acquire cash through wage labor from time to time
if opportunities were available. The families in the second category
owned less land and had to rent additional parcels. Owned and rented
holdings combined, however, did not always provide the means for
subsistence, so these families frequently had to resort to wage labor.
Not all tenants were poor. In some cases, tenants did well in good crop
and market years, particularly in central Thailand. In general, however,
the tenant farmer's situation was precarious. Rents, whether in cash or
in kind, tended to be fixed without regard for the size of the harvest,
and in a bad year tenant farmer families were likely to go into debt.
Tenants and agricultural laborers had little or nothing of their own to
pass on to their children.
In some areas, particularly in central Thailand, the land was
controlled by absentee landlords who lived in Bangkok or in provincial
towns and for whom landownership was another form of investment. They
could have direct or indirect effect on the social and political lives
of their tenants, and some occasionally acted as patrons to their
tenants. At the local level, however, it was the rich peasant who
wielded political power and was granted deference by others in the
community. Differences in wealth were consistent with the Thai
villager's understanding of the Buddhist concept of merit. According to this view, the accumulation of merit led not
to nirvana but to a better personal situation in this world, preferably
in this life. Wealth signified that one had merit. One might, therefore,
demonstrate one's merit by striving and succeeding. Villagers at the
lower end of the social scale, however, sometimes questioned the
doctrine of merit if they perceived the behavior of those at the upper
end as unrighteous.
Most observers agreed that the patron-client relationship was
pervasive in Thai society, not only at the village level but throughout
the military and the bureaucracy. There was less agreement on its links
to a class system and the degree to which the relationship was typically
marked by social ties of affection and concern as opposed to a clearly
calculated assessment of relative economic or political advantage. At
the village level, it was not necessary to be rich to have a client,
although a wealthy family was likely to have more than one client. It
was possible for an ordinary peasant (although not a landless one) to
provide limited benefits to someone less fortunate in return for certain
services. Often such a relationship was arranged between kin. In the
modern era, however, it was the wealthy villager who could provide
benefits and expect, even demand, certain services from his client.
In principle, a patron-client relationship lasted only so long as
both parties gained something from it, and the relationship could be
broken at the option of either. Often, however, the client had few
alternatives and would remain in the relationship in the hope of
eliciting more benefits than had hitherto been forthcoming. To the
extent, however, that prestige and power accrued to the person (or
family) who had and could retain a large number of clients, the patron
was motivated to provide benefits to those dependent on him.
The patron-client relationship also linked villagers and persons at
other levels of the social, political, and economic orders: leading
figures in the village, themselves patrons of others in the rural
community, became clients of officials, politicians, or traders at the
district or provincial levels. In such cases, clientship might reinforce
the status of the rich villager who could, at least occasionally, call
on his patron at a higher level for benefits that he might in turn use
to bind his own clients to him. Just the fact that the rich villager was
known to have a powerful patron outside the village could enhance his
status.
Thailand
Thailand - National and Urban Structures: Class and Status
Thailand
Although in the 1980s the hierarchy of social status or prestige and
the hierarchy of political and economic power in the rural community
overlapped, a disjunction of sorts existed between them at the national
level. A rich villager--other things being equal--wielded political and
economic power and had prestige. In the national system, the hierarchy
of status began with the hereditary nobility--the royal family and the
holders of royal titles. None of these people were poor; the royal
family owned much land and some of its members had political influence.
The royal family was not part of the ruling class, however, nor did it
control the economy. The ruling class consisted of several levels, the
uppermost of which comprised the military and, to a lesser extent, the
bureaucratic elite.
In general, the Thai accorded high status to those who wielded power,
and the prestige accorded the highest bureaucrats was consistent with a
historical pattern, even if in modern times these bureaucrats were
rarely members of the royal family. Whether the position of the military
was fully legitimated in the eyes of most Thai was uncertain. The
military was given deference, but it was not clear that its members were
freely accorded esteem.
Below the military and bureaucratic elites were those in high
government posts who performed the tasks requiring considerable
knowledge, technical competence, or simply experience in the ways of
bureaucracy. Like the bureaucratic elites, these upper middlelevel
bureaucrats were well educated, often holding undergraduate or graduate
degrees from foreign universities. From the point of view of the Thai,
such officeholders had much prestige even if they were not the primary
wielders of power.
Positions at the highest levels of the military and the bureaucracy
brought very good incomes to those holding them. Often these positions
provided access to other sources of income, including large landholdings
and other real estate, or participation in the actual ownership of
businesses, often in conjunction with Chinese businessmen. With some
exceptions, the latter exercised day-to-day control of financial,
commercial, and industrial organizations and institutions.
The social status of the Chinese economic elite was not clear. After
World War II, a limited number of Chinese business families, who had
begun as middlemen financing aspects of agricultural production and
marketing, became bankers and industrial and commercial entrepreneurs.
These families had considerable economic power, and they clearly
influenced some political decisions through the Thai military and
bureaucrats with whom they had connections. Whether the Thai in general
granted them the prestige ordinarily given to those holding high posts
in government was another matter.
These Chinese businessmen should be distinguished from the many Thai
in the military and the civil bureaucracy who had Chinese ancestry. In
many cases, this Chinese ancestry was several generations removed. In
any case, such individuals were considered Thai, operated chiefly in a
Thai social and cultural milieu, and were evaluated on the same social
scale as other Thai.
Until the 1970s, persons who were fully Chinese entered the
bureaucracy only at the middle levels or, if higher, as technical staff.
This was in part a matter of Thai policy, in part a matter of Chinese
orientation. The Chinese were not indifferent to political power or
administrative skill as desirable qualities or as sources of prestige,
but they adapted to the limits imposed by their minority status. Within
the Chinese community there was a hierarchy of political influence, and
there were organizations (ranging from chambers of commerce to community
groups and mutual aid societies) in which Chinese had the opportunity to
exercise their power and skills. Even there, however, political power
and prestige flowed to those who had been successful as entrepreneurs,
whereas among the Thai, achievement in the military or the bureaucracy
preceded access to significant economic opportunities or resources.
Chinese in the economic elite who moved into important positions in
Chinese-centered organizations or, occasionally, other organizations,
not only gained prestige within the Chinese community but also became
the links between that community and Thai elites, particularly with
respect to the establishment of economic ties.
By the early 1970s, significant numbers of Chinese had been admitted
to the higher bureaucracy. According to one analyst, they held roughly
30 percent of the posts in the special grades (upper ranks) at that
time. Presumably they were the sons and daughters of wealthy
entrepreneurs and had acquired the higher education necessary for
admission to the bureaucracy's upper ranks.
Below the hereditary nobility and the ruling class was a socially and
occupationally heterogeneous middle class that emerged in the years
after World War II, especially after 1960. Its members were diverse with
respect to their control over wealth, their social status, and their
access to power. The simplest distinction within this amorphous category
was based partially on income and partially on occupation, but
subcategories thus drawn were rather mixed. The wealthier segment of
this middle class (for convenience, the upper middle class) consisted of
bureaucrats and military men at middle levels (including higher
provincial officials), salaried administrative and managerial workers in
private enterprise, middle-level businessmen, provincial notables and
landlords living in provincial towns, and professionals. A much larger
group, the petty bourgeoisie, comprised those who provided a range of
services, largely in Bangkok, to the ruling class, the upper middle
class, and to tourists and other foreigners. Often this petty
bourgeoisie consisted of small-scale independent businessmen, some of
them shop owners, others furnishing their services contractually. Some
were salaried clerical staff. Both upper and lower segments of this
middle category include many Chinese as well as Thai.
In the Thai scale of values, higher prestige tended to be accorded to
those in government employment and perhaps to those in the professions.
The private sector as a source of substantial income was a relatively
new idea to the Thai, however, and their scale of values might change as
an entrepreneurial bourgeoisie began seeking to have its status
validated. In any case, the elements in the upper segment of this middle
category could be said to share the same outlook and values or the same
political status implied in the notion of class. The position of
bureaucrats and notables (middle-level businessmen and landowners) who
lived in provincial towns was of particular interest. On their home
ground they exercised considerable power, formally and informally, but
they owed this power at least in part to their connections, usually as
clients to patrons in Bangkok, although they in turn had clients at
lower levels.
There was also a lower urban stratum, but this too was heterogeneous.
On the one hand, there were the more or less steady wage workers in
commercial and industrial enterprises, mainly in Bangkok (and in mining
outside Bangkok). On the other hand, there were large numbers of
persons, like the wage workers, often from rural areas, who had no
steady work and sought to eke out a living by offering their services as
unskilled labor.
There were two other urban groups that were not part of the status
hierarchy. Just as the monks of a village wat were outside the
local rural system of stratification but enjoyed a special status, so
too was the hierarchy of the sangha, the highest elements of
which were located in Bangkok. Within the monkhood, the supreme
patriarch and the Council of Elders exercised considerable authority,
and they were given a great deal of deference by laymen, even those in
the royal family and the ruling class. They did not have significant
power outside the sangha, although some monks have had a
substantial impact on politics.
Also outside the urban status hierarchy--but sometimes with higher
incomes than those in the upper middle class and themselves requiring
the services of those in the lower middle category--were the many men
and women engaged in illegal activities that were nonetheless
countenanced or protected. Among them were prostitutes, pimps, and
narcotics dealers. In the mid1980s , the number of women in Bangkok
estimated to be engaged in prostitution or in related services ranged
from 100,000 to 1 million. Some observers noted that prostitution was
firmly entrenched in modern Thailand as a result of historical,
economic, and social factors. The majority of Bangkok prostitutes were
rural migrants providing economic support to relatives back in the
country, which was expected of Thai daughters within the extended stem
family system. In other words, Thai prostitutes were not fleeing from a
family background or rural society that oppressed women in conventional
ways but were engaging in an entrepreneurial move designed to sustain
the family units of the rural economy, which had come under increasing
pressure. Since these women usually did not reveal the source of their
remittances back to the village, their families could retain or gain
status based upon their earnings.
Class Consciousness
Of the categories or strata discernible in Thai society, only
one--the royal family and the hereditary nobility--constituted a
self-conscious group. It was not clear that class consciousness had
developed among the power elites or upper middle-level bureaucrats by
the 1980s, in spite of their shared views and aspirations. Nevertheless,
as social mobility diminished, which it had begun to do in the early
1980s, and as each category or section increasingly generated its own
replacements, distinct status groups might emerge. Outwardly there were
many indications of a conscious middle class, consumer-oriented,
cosmopolitan way of life. For example, golf, tennis, delicatessens,
fast-food restaurants, boutiques, and shopping malls were very popular
among the Thai residents of Bangkok in the late 1980s.
Militating against solidarity, particularly at the upper and middle
levels, was the continuing competition for political power and the
access to economic opportunities and resources that flowed from such
power. People competing for high-level positions in the military, the
bureaucracy, or within the economy were engaged in a complex and
shifting pattern of patron-client relationships. In this system, all but
the individuals at the highest and lowest ends of a chain of such
relationships were simultaneously patrons to one or more others and
clients to someone above them. A developing career was likely to put a
person at different places in the chain at various stages.
Given the fluctuations in the fortunes of individuals (to which the
patron-client system contributed), patrons and clients, particularly at
the higher levels, had to make judgments as to the benefits accruing to
them from their relationship. Moreover, a client had to assess present
and potential sources of power and the extent to which his support and
services would be reciprocated by the current or alternative patrons. It
was not uncommon in this system for both patrons and clients to shift
allegiances. Patrons often had several clients, but there were no real
bonds between the clients of a single patron.
Social Mobility
The expansion of the bureaucracy and the military and the movement of
the Thai into a rapidly growing private sector created opportunities for
social mobility, although the major part of the population remained
rural workers or moved into low-level occupations in the urban labor
force. Associated with upward mobility, given the Thai orientation
toward bureaucratic careers, was the availability of education.
Expansion of education facilities beyond the secondary level occurred in
the early 1970s. In 1961, for example, about 42,000 full-time and
part-time students were enrolled in 6 higher education institutions, but
by 1972 there were roughly 72,000 in more than a dozen institutions. The
oldest and most prestigious universities, such as Chulalongkorn,
Thammasat, and Mahidol, were in Bangkok. Many students attended
universities outside Thailand, but these were more likely to be the
children of Thai or Chinese who had already attained a fairly high
socioeconomic position.
Education was necessary for entry into the bureaucracy, but other
capabilities or characteristics, including political reliability and
involvement in the patron-client system, also played a part in upward
mobility within the bureaucracy. In the military, the system played
perhaps a greater role than education. Military expertise as such did
not seem to be an important consideration.
The sangha offered a special avenue of social mobility to
some of the sons of the peasants at the base of Thailand's socioeconomic
pyramid. Positions in the upper tiers were filled by examination, and
monks were offered higher education at two Buddhist universities
(Mahachulalongkorn and Mahamongkut), which by the 1960s included
significant secular components in their curricula. The Buddhist
education system provided support for its talented students through the
highest level; access to these opportunities by villagers might reflect
the declining interest among the urban classes and the provincial middle
group in a career in the sangha. The social mobility achieved
through the sangha was not necessarily limited to those who
were lifetime monks. Monks who left the sangha in their
thirties and forties could legitimately enter other careers, and their
education and experience in the sangha were helpful.
By the mid-1970s, the number of aspirants to the bureaucracy with
undergraduate and even graduate degrees had begun to exceed the number
of openings. Moreover, the economy was no longer expanding as it had in
the 1960s and early 1970s. Opportunities for upward mobility had
lessened in the early 1980s, and children of families already
established in the upper or middle reaches of the socioeconomic system
were able to maintain their head start in a system that was no longer
growing so rapidly.
Thailand
Thailand - RELIGION
Thailand
Theravada Buddhism, the form of Buddhism practiced in Sri Lanka,
Burma, Cambodia, and Laos, was the religion of more than 80 percent of
the Thai people in the 1980s. These coreligionists included not only the
core Thai, but most other Tai speakers, as well as the Khmer, the Mon,
and some members of other minorities, among them the Chinese. Relatively
few Thai were adherents of Mahayana Buddhism or other religions,
including Hinduism, Christianity, Taoism, animism, and Islam. Of these
only Islam, largely identified with but not restricted to Southern Thai
of Malay origin, was a dominant religion in a specific geographic area.
Theravada Buddhism was the established religion, in that there were
formal organizational and ideological links between it and the state.
Thai rulers (the king formerly, and the military and bureaucratic
oligarchy subsequently) sought or--if they thought it
necessary--commanded the support of the Buddhist clergy or sangha,
who usually acquiesced to (if not welcomed) the state's support and
protection. A Thai religious writer pointed out that Thailand was the
only country in the world where the king was constitutionally required
to be a Buddhist and upholder of the faith.
Buddhism's place in Thai society was by no means defined solely by
its relation to the state. The role of religious belief and institutions
in Thai life had changed, and, with increasing commercialism and
urbanization, some observers questioned the prevalence of Thai piety and
good works. However, the peasant's or villager's view of the world
remained at least partly defined by an understanding of Buddhist
doctrine, and significant events in his or her life and community were
marked by rituals performed or at least supervised by Buddhist clergy.
Often, the villager's city-dwelling siblings would return to the home
village for significant events such as weddings and funerals.
Additionally, much of Thai village life--social, political, economic,
and religious--centered on the local wat.
As is often the case when a scripturally based religion becomes
dominant in a largely agrarian society, the religious beliefs and
behavior of most Thai were compounded of elements derived from both
formal doctrine and other sources. The latter either developed during
the long history of Buddhism or derived from religious systems
indigenous to the area. Implementation of the same Buddhist rite and
tradition often varied from region to region. In Central Thailand, for
example, praiseworthy priests were selected and honored by the king,
whereas in the Northeast this recognition was bestowed by the people.
<"54.htm">Historical Background
<"55.htm">Buddhist Doctrine and Popular Religion
<"56.htm">The Sangha
<"57.htm">Buddhism, Politics, and Values
<"58.htm">Religious Minorities
Thailand
Thailand - RELIGION - Historical Background
Thailand
Thai Buddhism was based on the religious movement founded in the
sixth century B.C. by Siddhartha Gautama Sakyamuni, later known as the
Buddha, who urged the world to relinquish the extremes of sensuality and
self-mortification and follow the enlightened Middle Way. The focus was
on man, not gods; the assumption was that life was pain or suffering,
which was a consequence of craving, and that suffering could end only if
desire ceased. The end of suffering was the achievement of nirvana (in
Theravada Buddhist scriptures, nibbana), often defined
negatively as the absence of craving and therefore of suffering,
sometimes as enlightenment or bliss.
By the third century B.C., Buddhism had spread widely in Asia, and
divergent interpretations of the Buddha's teachings had led to the
establishment of several sects. The teachings that reached Ceylon
(present-day Sri Lanka) were given in a final written form in Pali (an
Indo-Aryan language closely related to Sanskrit) to religious centers
there in the first century A.D. and provided the Tipitaka (the
scriptures or "three baskets"; in Sanskrit, Tripitaka) of
Theravada Buddhism. This form of Buddhism reached what is now Thailand
around the sixth century A.D. Theravada Buddhism was made the state
religion only with the establishment of the Thai kingdom of Sukhothai in
the thirteenth century A.D.
The details of the history of Buddhism in Thailand from the
thirteenth to the nineteenth century are obscure, in part because few
historical records or religious texts survived the Burmese destruction
of Ayutthaya, the capital city of the kingdom, in 1767. The
anthropologist-historian S.J. Tambiah, however, has suggested a general
pattern for that era, at least with respect to the relations between
Buddhism and the sangha on the one hand and the king on the
other hand. In Thailand, as in other Theravada Buddhist kingdoms, the
king was in principle thought of as patron and protector of the religion
(sasana) and the sangha, while sasana and the
sangha were considered in turn the treasures of the polity and
the signs of its legitimacy. Religion and polity, however, remained
separate domains, and in ordinary times the organizational links between
the sangha and the king were not close.
Among the chief characteristics of Thai kingdoms and principalities
in the centuries before 1800 were the tendency to expand and contract,
problems of succession, and the changing scope of the king's authority.
In effect, some Thai kings had greater power over larger territories,
others less, and almost invariably a king who sought successfully to
expand his power also exercised greater control over the sangha.
That control was coupled with greater support and patronage of the
ecclesiastical hierarchy. When a king was weak, however, protection and
supervision of the sangha also weakened, and the sangha
declined. This fluctuating pattern appears to have continued until the
emergence of the Chakkri Dynasty in the last quarter of the eighteenth
century.
By the nineteenth century, and especially with the coming to power in
1851 of King Mongkut, who had been a monk himself for twenty-seven
years, the sangha, like the kingdom, became steadily more
centralized and hierarchical in nature and its links to the state more
institutionalized. As a monk, Mongkut was a distinguished scholar of
Pali Buddhist scripture. Moreover, at that time the immigration of
numbers of Mon from Burma was introducing the more rigorous discipline
characteristic of the Mon sangha. Influenced by the Mon and
guided by his own understanding of the Tipitaka, Mongkut began a reform
movement that later became the basis for the Dhammayuttika order of
monks. Under the reform, all practices having no authority other than
custom were to be abandoned, canonical regulations were to be followed
not mechanically but in spirit, and acts intended to improve an
individual's standing on the road to nirvana but having no social value
were rejected. This more rigorous discipline was adopted in its entirety
by only a small minority of monasteries and monks. The Mahanikaya order,
perhaps somewhat influenced by Mongkut's reforms but with a less
exacting discipline than the Dhammayuttika order, comprised about 95
percent of all monks in 1970 and probably about the same percentage in
the late 1980s. In any case, Mongkut was in a position to regularize and
tighten the relations between monarchy and sangha at a time
when the monarchy was expanding its control over the country in general
and developing the kind of bureaucracy necessary to such control. The
administrative and sangha reforms that Mongkut started were
continued by his successor. In 1902 King Chulalongkorn (Rama V,
1868-1910) made the new sangha hierarchy formal and permanent
through the Sangha Law of 1902, which remained the foundation of sangha
administration in modern Thailand.
Thailand
Thailand - Buddhist Doctrine and Popular Religion
Thailand
The doctrine of Theravada Buddhism can be found in the three-part
Tipitaka. The first of the three baskets (or sections) sets forth the
discipline governing the monastic order. The second presents the sermons
or discourses of the Buddha and contains the dharma (literally,
doctrine). The third comprises the commentaries and explications
produced by learned monks in the centuries after the death of the
Buddha. It is here that significant differences exist between Theravada
and Mahayana Buddhism.
In the first basket, and central to the structure of Buddhist belief,
are the doctrines of karma, the sum and the consequences of an
individual's actions during the successive phases of his existence, and samsara,
the eternal cycle of birth, death, and rebirth. Both doctrines were
derived from the Indian thought of the Buddha's time, although he
invested the concept of karma with very strong ethical implications.
Broadly, these ideas taken together assert that evil acts have evil
consequences for those committing them, and good acts yield good
consequences, not necessarily in any one lifetime, but over the
inevitable cycle of births and deaths. A concomitant to the belief in
karma and samsara is the view that all forms of life are
related because every form originated in a previous one. In the
canonical view, but not in the popular one, the entity that undergoes
reincarnation is not the soul (although the idea of soul exists) but a
complex of attributes--actions and their consequences--that taken
together are said to constitute the karma of an individual. It is karma
in this sense that survives in another form.
The second basket, containing the dharma, provides the essentials
that define the way to nirvana. The foundation of the system lies in the
Four Noble Truths: suffering exists, it is caused by craving or desire,
it can be made to cease, and it can be brought to an end by following
the Noble Eightfold Path. The last Noble Truth contains the eight
precepts to be followed by Buddhists: right view, or having an
understanding of the Four Noble Truths; right thought--freedom from
lust, ill will, and cruelty; right speech, which means abstention from
lying, gossiping, harsh language, and vain talk; right action, by which
killing, stealing, and sexual misconduct are proscribed; right
livelihood, which requires an individual's sustenance be earned in a way
that is not harmful to living things; right effort, by which good
thoughts are encouraged and bad thoughts are avoided or overcome; right
mindfulness, or close attention to all states of the body, feeling, and
mind; and right concentration, that is, concentration on a single object
to bring about a special state of consciousness in meditation. Following
the Noble Eightfold Path conscientiously is necessary if a person
aspires to become an arhat (usually translated as saint), ready
for nirvana.
Virtually from the beginning, however, the Buddha acknowledged that
it would be difficult for a layperson to follow all aspects of the Noble
Eightfold Path singlemindedly. The conditions appropriate to such
pursuit are available only to mendicant monks. The demands on the
layperson are therefore less rigorous, and most interpret the doctrine
as requiring acts gaining merit so that the layperson may achieve a
condition in the next life that will allow stricter attention to the
requirements of the path.
The acts that bring merit are, in principle, those that conform as
closely as possible to the ethical demands of the Noble Eightfold Path.
Acts that support the brotherhood of monks are also included.
Consequently, providing material support, e.g., food, to the members of
the sangha, showing them deference, underwriting and
participating in certain ceremonies, and supporting the construction and
maintenance of the wat have come to be the chief methods of
gaining merit. The powerful ethical content of the Noble Eightfold Path
is reduced to five precepts or injunctions. The laity are expected to
refrain from the following: taking life, stealing, lying, engaging in
illicit sexual relations, and drinking intoxicating liquors. Thai
Buddhists--like many followers of other religions--select only a few of
the Buddha's teachings to guide them. Many Buddhist principles, while
not actually practiced, are venerated as ideals.
According to some observers, most Thai place little emphasis on the
achievement of nirvana, whether as a final state after many rebirths or
as an interior condition. What is hoped for is an improved condition in
this life or the next. In Thai thinking, the ideas of merit and demerit
so essential to the doctrine of karma are linked linguistically to those
of good and evil; good and merit are both bun; evil and the
absence of merit are bap. The Theravada idea of karma (and the
Thai peasant's understanding of it) charges the individual with
responsibility for good and evil acts and their consequences. Thai do
not rely solely on the accumulation of merit, however gained, to bring
that improved state into being. Other forms of causality, ranging from
astrology to the action of spirits of various kinds, are also part of
their outlook.
The world of the Thai villager (and that of many city folk as well)
is inhabited by a host of spirits of greater or lesser relevance to an
individual's well-being. Although many of these are not sanctioned by
Buddhist scripture or even by Buddhist tradition, many monks, themselves
of rural origin and essentially tied to the village, are as likely as
the peasant to accept the beliefs and rituals associated with spirits.
Most important are the spirits included in the rather heterogeneous
category of phi, thought to have power over human beings. The
category includes spirits believed to have a permanent existence and
others that are reincarnations of deceased human beings. Phi
exist virtually everywhere--in trees, hills, water, animals, the earth,
and so on. Some are malevolent, others beneficial.
The ghosts of persons who died violently under mysterious
circumstances or whose funeral rites were improperly performed
constitute another class of phi; almost all of these spirits
are malevolent. In contrast, the ghosts of notable people are said to
reside in small shrines along the roads and are referred to as
"spirit lords." They are often petitioned in prayers and can
enter and possess the bodies of mediums to give oracles. Among the more
important of the spirits and ghosts is the evil phi pop (ghoul
spirit), which, at the instigation of witches, can enter human beings
and consume their internal organs.
Another category consists of the chao (guardian spirits), of
which perhaps the most important is the chao thi, or guardian
of the house compound (an alternative name is phra phum). Fixed
on a post in the compound of most houses in Thailand's central region is
a small spirit dwelling. Food offerings are made to the chao thi
on the anniversary of the spirit's installation in the house, on New
Year's Day, and on other special days. The spirit is told of the arrival
of guests who are to stay any length of time, of projected journeys by
members of the family, and of births and deaths. The spirit's
intercession is also sought during illness and misfortune.
Other spirits protect gardens, the rice fields, and the wat.
The spirit of the rice field is worshiped only once a year, at the
beginning of the rice planting; the Rice Goddess receives offerings when
the seedbed is to be prepared and when the harvest is ready. The Mother
Earth Goddess often receives offerings at transplanting time.
In addition to the rites dedicated to an assortment of spirits either
regularly or as the occasion demands, other rites intended to maximize
merit for the participants are practiced. The Buddha prescribed no
ceremonies for birth, death, and marriage, but the Hindu rites, which
were adopted by the Thai people, entail the participation of Buddhist
monks. The ceremonies, which are held at home rather than in the wat,
have no scriptural sanction. The monks limit their participation to
chanting the appropriate Buddhist scriptural texts or to providing holy
water.
The propitiation of an individual's khwan (body spirit or
life soul) remains a basic feature of Thai family rites. Any ceremony
undertaken to benefit a person, animal, or plant is referred to as the
making of khwan. On important occasions, such as birth,
ordination into the priesthood, marriage, a return from a long journey,
or the reception of an honored guest, a khwan ceremony is
performed.
Of all the life cycle and family ceremonies, funeral rites are the
most elaborate. When a person is dying, he or she should fix his or her
mind on the Buddhist scriptures or repeat some of the names of the
Buddha. If the last thoughts of the dying person are directed toward the
Buddha and his precepts, the fruits of this meritorious behavior will be
repaid to the deceased in the next incarnation. After his or her death,
other meritorious acts are performed for the benefit of the deceased,
such as attendance at the wake and provision of food to the officiating
monks. Every effort is made to banish sorrow, loneliness, and fear of
the spirits by means of music and fellowship.
Ceremonies in the wat consist of those that benefit the
entire community and those that primarily affect the sangha.
The first kind include the rites held on such occasions as Mahka Bucha
(an important February holiday that marks the beginning of the season
for making pilgrimages to Phra Phuttabaht, the Buddha's Footprint
Shrine), Wisakha Bucha (a festival commemorating the Buddha's birth,
enlightenment, and death), Khao Phansa (the holiday marking the
beginning of the three-month Buddhist holy season, July to October), and
Thot Kathin (a festival during which robes and other items are given to
the monks by the laity). Ceremonies that primarily concern the sangha
include ordination, confession, recitation of the 227 monastic rules,
and distribution of new robes after Thot Kathin.
Of all the ceremonies affecting the sangha, ordination is
the one in which the laity are most involved, both physically and
spiritually. Frequently, before a young man makes his initial entry into
the sangha, a ceremony is held in the home of the aspirant to
prepare him for ordination. His khwan is invited to enter the sangha
with him; otherwise, evil and illness might befall him. He is informed
of his parents' happiness with his decision, of the sacrifices they have
made for him, and of the life of austerity and discipline he is to
begin. In Thailand, it is a popular belief that by becoming a monk great
merit is gained, merit which also accrues to persons or parents who
sponsor the ordination.
Thailand
Thailand - The Sangha
Thailand
The sangha comprises two sects or schools, the Mahanikaya
and the Dhammayuttika. The first has far more members than the second,
but the Dhammayuttika--exercising a more rigorous discipline, having a
reputation for scholarship in the doctrine, and having a close
connection to royalty--continues to wield influence beyond its numbers
among intellectuals and in sangha administration. Both schools
are included in the same ecclesiastical hierarchy, which is very closely
tied to the government. The strengthening of those ties began in the
nineteenth century, ostensibly to deal with problems of internal
disorganization in the sangha but also so that the sangha
could be used to help integrate a government that was just beginning to
extend and strengthen its administrative control over the North and
Northeast. Each of these regions in effect had had its own sangha,
and the unification of the sangha was seen as an important step
toward the unification of Thailand. The pattern of legislative and other
steps culminating in the Sangha Act of 1963 tended to tighten government
control of the sangha; there was no significant resistance to
this control from the monks. Conflicts existed between the two schools,
however, over issues such as position in the hierarchy.
In spite of a long tradition of monkhood in Thailand, the great
majority of males did not become monks. Those who did usually entered in
their early twenties but did not necessarily remain monks for a long
time. During the three-month holy season Khao (Phansa), sometimes
referred to as the Buddhist Lent, monks go into retreat, and more
attention than usual is given to the study of dharma. In the mid-1980s,
Thai male civil servants were given three months leave with full pay if
they spent the Lenten period as monks. It has been estimated that the
proportion of temporary monks during this period varies between 25 and
40 percent of the total. The motivation for monkhood of such short
duration is complex, but even the temporary status, for those who are
unable or unwilling to commit themselves to the discipline for life,
brings merit, not only to the monk but also to his parents, particularly
to his mother. (Some Buddhist women live as nuns, but they enjoy lower
status than monks do.) Whether temporary or permanent, a monk in
principle is subject to the 227 rules of conduct embodied in that
portion (basket) of the Tipitaka devoted to the sangha.
Aside from the religious motivation of those who enter and remain in
the sangha, another inducement for many is the chance to pursue
the contemplative life within the monastic community. Other reasons in
modern Thailand include the opportunity for education at one of the two
Buddhist universities and the chance, particularly for monks of rural
origin, to gain social status.
Thai villagers expect monks to be pious and to adhere to the rules.
Beyond that, monks are expected to provide services to individual
members of the laity and local communities by performing various
ceremonies and chanting appropriate passages from the Buddhist
scriptures on important occasions. The presence of monks is believed to
result in the accrual of merit to lay participants.
Thai Buddhists generally do not expect monks to be directly involved
in the working world; the monks' sustenance is provided by the members
of the community in which the monks live. Their contribution to
community life, besides their religious and ceremonial functions, is
primarily educational. Beginning in the late 1960s, the government
encouraged monks to engage in missionary activity in the remote, less
developed provinces, particularly among the hill peoples, as part of the
effort to integrate these groups into the polity. Leaders at the
Buddhist universities have taken the stand that monks owe something to
society in return for the support given them and that, in addition to
the advanced study of Buddhism, the universities ought to include
secular subjects conducive to the enrichment of the nation.
Thailand
Thailand - Buddhism, Politics, and Values
Thailand
The organizational links between the sangha and the
government are an indication of their interdependence, although the fine
points of that relationship may have changed over time. The traditional
interdependence was between religion and the monarchy. The king was, in
theory, a righteous ruler, a bodhisattva (an enlightened being who, out
of compassion, foregoes nirvana in order to aid others), and the
protector of the religion. Because succession to the throne was
problematic and the position of any king in many respects unstable, each
ruler sought legitimation from the sangha. In return, he
offered the religion his support.
After the king became a constitutional monarch in 1932, actual power
lay in the hands of the elites, primarily the military but also the
higher levels of the bureaucracy. Regardless of the political complexion
of the specific persons in power (who, more often than not, had rightist
views), the significance of Buddhism to the nation was never attacked.
In the late 1980s, the king remained an important symbol, and public
ideology insisted that religion, king, and nation were inextricably
intertwined. Opposition groups have rarely attacked
this set of related symbols. Some observers have argued that the
acceptance of religion, king, and nation as ultimate symbols of Thai
political values was misleading in that the great bulk of the
population--the Thai villagers--although attached to Buddhism and
respectful of the king, often resented the particular manifestations of
government in local communities and situations. It seemed, however, that
whatever discontent there was with the political, social, and economic
orders, most Thai remained at least passively committed to a national
identity symbolized by the king and Buddhism.
Puey Ungphakorn, a former rector of Thammasat University and human
rights advocate, viewed the ethical precepts of Buddhism as insurance
against oppressive national development. Although the fundamental role
of development was to improve the welfare of the villagers, in a number
of nations without the protection of religion the rights of the villager
were often abused. In Thailand, according to Puey, the peasant, like the
urban dweller, has an individual identity protected by the shared belief
in Buddhism.
The support given the king (and whatever political regime was in
power) by the sangha was coupled with a prohibition on the
direct intervention of monks in politics, particularly in party,
political, and ideological conflicts. It was taken for granted that
members of the sangha would oppose a communist regime, and
available evidence suggested that virtually all Thai monks found Marxist
thought alien, although monks elsewhere in Southeast Asia have been
influenced by socialist, if not explicitly communist, ideas.
Historically, monks occasionally have been involved in politics, but
this involvement was not the norm. In the second half of the twentieth
century, however, monks became aware of the political and ideological
ferment in Southeast Asia and in a few cases engaged in political
propaganda, if not in direct action. A few were accused of doing so from
a position on the left, but the most explicit instance of political
propaganda in the 1970s was that of a highly influential monk,
Kittivuddha Bikkhu, who preached that it was meritorious to kill
communists. Although not supported by the religious and political
establishments, he provided right-wing militants with a Buddhist
ideological justification for their extremist activities.
Thailand
Thailand - Religious Minorities
Thailand
Defining Thai minority religions was as complex as defining Thai
ethnic minorities. This problem was further compounded by the number of
Thai whose Buddhism was a combination of differing beliefs. In the
1980s, the religious affiliation of the Chinese minority was
particularly difficult to identify. Some adopted the Theravada beliefs
of the Thai, and many participated in the activities of the local wat.
Most Chinese, however, consciously retained the mixture of Confucian
social ethics, formal veneration of ancestors, Mahayana Buddhist
doctrine, and Taoist supernaturalism that was characteristic of the
popular religious tradition in China. To the Chinese community as a
whole, neither organized religion nor theological speculation had strong
appeal. There were some Chinese members of the sangha, and most
large Chinese temples had active lay associations attached to them. It
was estimated in the 1980s that there were about twenty-one Chinese
monasteries and thirteen major Vietnamese monasteries in Thailand.
The practice of Islam in the 1980s was concentrated in Thailand's
southernmost provinces, where the vast majority of the country's
Muslims, predominantly Malay in origin, were found. The remaining
Muslims were Pakistani immigrants in the urban centers, ethnic Thai in
the rural areas of the Center, and a few Chinese Muslims in the far
north. Education and maintenance of their own cultural traditions were
vital interests of these groups.
Except in the small circle of theologically trained believers, the
Islamic faith in Thailand, like Buddhism, had become integrated with
many beliefs and practices not integral to Islam. It would be difficult
to draw a line between animistic practices indigenous to Malay culture
that were used to drive off evil spirits and local Islamic ceremonies
because each contained aspects of the other. In the mid-1980s, the
country had more than 2,000 mosques in 38 Thai provinces, with the
largest number (434) in Narathiwat Province. All but a very small number
of the mosques were associated with the Sunni branch of Islam; the
remainder were of the Shia branch. Each mosque had an imam (prayer
leader), a muezzin (who issued the call to prayer), and perhaps other
functionaries. Although the majority of the country's Muslims were
ethnically Malay, the Muslim community also included the Thai Muslims,
who were either hereditary Muslims, Muslims by intermarriage, or recent
converts; Cham Muslims originally from Cambodia; West Asians, including
both Sunni and Shias; South Asians, including Tamils, Punjabis and
Bengalis; Indonesians, especially Javanese and Minangkabau; Thai-Malay
or people of Malay ethnicity who have accepted many aspects of Thai
language and culture, except Buddhism, and have intermarried with Thai;
and Chinese Muslims, who were mostly Haw living in the North.
The National Council for Muslims, consisting of at least five persons
(all Muslims) and appointed by royal proclamation, advised the
ministries of education and interior on Islamic matters. Its presiding
officer, the state counselor for Muslim affairs, was appointed by the
king and held the office of division chief in the Department of
Religious Affairs in the Ministry of Education. Provincial councils for
Muslim affairs existed in the provinces that had substantial Muslim
minorities, and there were other links between the government and the
Muslim community, including government financial assistance to Islamic
education institutions, assistance with construction of some of the
larger mosques, and the funding of pilgrimages by Thai Muslims to Mecca.
Thailand also maintained several hundred Islamic schools at the primary
and secondary levels.
During the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, Portuguese and
Spanish Dominicans and other missionaries introduced Christianity to
Siam. Christian missions have had only modest success in winning
converts among the Thai, and the Christian community, estimated at
260,000 in the 1980s, was proportionately the smallest in any Asian
country. The missions played an important role, however, as agents for
the transmission of Western ideas to the Thai. Missionaries opened
hospitals, introduced Western medical knowledge, and sponsored some
excellent private elementary and secondary schools. Many of the Thai
urban elite who planned to have their children complete their studies in
European or North American universities sent them first to the
mission-sponsored schools.
A high percentage of the Christian community was Chinese, although
there were several Lao and Vietnamese Roman Catholic communities, the
latter in southeastern Thailand. About half the total Christian
population lived in the Center. The remainder were located in almost
equal numbers in the North and Northeast. More than half the total
Christian community in Thailand was Roman Catholic. Some of the
Protestant groups had banded together in the mid-1930s to form the
Church of Christ in Thailand, and nearly half of the more than 300
Protestant congregations in the country were part of that association.
Other religions represented in Thailand included Hinduism and
Sikhism, both associated with small ethnic groups of Indian origin. Most
of the Hindus and Sikhs lived in Bangkok.
Thailand
Thailand - EDUCATION AND THE ARTS
Thailand
In the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, United States
and British missionaries introduced formal European education, primarily
in the palaces. Up to that time, scholarly pursuits had been confined
largely to Buddhist temples, where monastic instruction, much of it
entailing the memorization of scriptures, was provided to boys and young
men. Like his father Mongkut, King Chulalongkorn (Rama V, 1868-1910)
wanted to integrate monastic instruction with Western education.
Unsuccessful in this effort, he appointed his half brother, Prince
Damrong Rajanubhab, to design a new system of education. Western
teachers were engaged to provide assistance, and in 1921 a compulsory
education law was enacted. In 1917 the first university in the country,
Chulalongkorn University, was established.
Emphasis on education grew after the 1932 coup as a result of the new
constitutional requirement for a literate populace able to participate
in electoral politics. Government efforts focused on primary education;
private schools, concentrated in Bangkok and a few provincial centers,
supported a major share of educational activity, especially at the
secondary level. Despite ambitious planning, little was accomplished.
Even after World War II, the educated segment of Thai society continued
to consist mainly of a small elite in Bangkok. The postwar years showed
the influence of American education. By the mid-1980s, perhaps as many
as 100,000 Thai students had studied in the United States, and tens of
thousands had benefited from Peace Corps and other United States
government educational assistance projects.
Only 4 million children were enrolled in government schools in the
1960s, but by the late 1980s nearly 80 percent of the population above
the age of 11 had some formal education. This dramatic change reflected
government interest in accelerating the pace of social development
through education, especially in less secure areas of the country, as a
means of promoting political stability. By 1983 an estimated 99.4
percent of the children between the ages of 7 and 12 attended primary
school. (Compulsory schooling lasted only until grade six.) Adult
literacy reportedly was more than 85.5 percent in the mid-1980s,
compared with about 50 percent in the 1950s. Substantial public
investment and foreign assistance made significant gains possible in
literacy and school enrollments.
The government operated schools in all parts of the country, but
there were many private schools as well, chiefly in Bangkok, sponsored
principally by missionaries or Chinese communal organizations. Several
universities ran what were effectively their own preparatory academies.
In the late 1970s, the schools were reorganized into a six-three-three
pattern that comprised six years of primary schooling, three years of
lower secondary education, and three years at the upper secondary level.
Students in the upper secondary program could choose either academic
or vocational courses. A core curriculum was common to both tracks, but
the academic program focused on preparation for university entrance,
whereas the vocational program emphasized skilled trades and
agriculture. Only a small percentage of students continued their
education beyond secondary school. Some who would have chosen to do so
failed to qualify for university acceptance. Secondary-school graduates
often had difficulty finding suitable employment. Even vocational
graduates in rural areas frequently found their industrial skills poorly
fitted to the agro-economic job market.
Access to education and the quality of education varied significantly
by region. At the primary level, rural schools, administered since 1963
by the Ministry of Interior, tended to have the least qualified teachers
and the most serious shortage of teaching materials. In an effort to
increase the number of teachers, other ministries, including the
Ministry of Defense, offered teacher-training programs. Although more
students gained access to education, this arrangement led to a
duplication of resources. Competition began to replace cooperation among
some of the teachers' colleges and universities. Opportunities for
secondary education were concentrated in major towns and in the Center.
In the mid-1970s, Bangkok, with 10 percent of the country's population,
had 45 percent of the secondary-school population, while the North and
the Northeast combined, with 55 percent of the nation's population, had
only 26 percent of these students. The government has since attempted to
rectify these inequities by improving administrative structure, making
education more relevant to socioeconomic development, and adding
qualitative and quantitative support to both public and private systems.
Nevertheless, in the late 1980s the underlying problem of inequitable
distribution of funds between the Center and the outlying provinces
remained.
The Office of University Affairs administered higher education at
government universities (except for teachers' colleges, military
academies, and the two Buddhist universities) and supervised higher
education in private colleges. By the late 1980s, the country had 13
public universities, 3 institutes, and about 10 private colleges, the
latter accounting for only about 7 percent of total university
enrollment. A Western education was highly valued, and those who could
afford to study abroad often did. Chulalongkorn University was the
leading domestic university. Until the establishment of Ramkhamhaeng
University in 1971, Chulalongkorn had the largest student body (18,000
full- time and part-time students in 1987). Thammasat University (11,000
student population in 1987) ranked next in academic quality. Operations
at Thammasat suffered somewhat from punitive measures imposed after the
massive student disorders of October 1973. Thereafter, Mahidol University (formerly the
University of Medical Sciences), which had nearly 9,000 students in
1987, began to overtake Thammasat University as Thailand's second-best
university. Another respected academic institution was the agricultural
university, Kasetsart University, which in 1987 had 11,000 students. All
the major universities were located in Bangkok. The various provincial
universities, which were established in the 1960s and the 1970s, and a
number of specialized academies, some of them in Bangkok, mostly had
small student populations. Chiang Mai University, founded in 1964,
however, had 13,000 students by 1987.
Pressure from a society that increasingly valued career-oriented
education was in part responsible for the government's establishment of
two "open universities," beginning in 1971. Both open
universities were established for those who could not be accommodated by
the older institutions of higher learning, and each admitted secondary
school graduates without any competitive examination. Ramkhamhaeng
University conducted classes, whereas Sukhothai Thammathirat University
offered its courses via national radio and television broadcasts and by
correspondence. In 1987 Ramkhamhaeng had more than 400,000 students
enrolled and Sukhothai Thammathirat more than 150,000.
To maintain its own language and script, Thailand constantly promoted
reading through both formal and informal education. Thailand had one of
the highest levels of functional literacy in Asia as well as one of the
largest publishing rates per person of any developing nation. In 1982
there were 5,645 titles published, more than 7 million radio receivers,
830,000 televisions, 69 daily newspapers, and 175 periodicals.
Thai-language paperbacks, often translations of English-language
best-sellers or "how to" books, had a wide audience. The
publishing house of Kled Thai, with 60 percent of the national market,
distributed between 80,000 and 120,000 volumes monthly.
Thailand had a long history of written literature dating back to the
thirteenth century, when much of the literature written in poetic style
was religious or related to the monarchy. Examples include the Maha
Chat Kham Luang, an epic adapted from the Buddhist Jataka tales,
and Kotmai Tra Sam Duang, a legal work on Buddhist ethics.
Beginning with the Chakkri Dynasty in the late eighteenth century,
writing for both the court and the public flourished. New trends in
literary style included Phra Aphai Mani, by Thailand's greatest
poet Sunthon Phu (1786-1855), the written version of the popular epic
romance poem called Khun Chang Khun Phaen, and Sang Thong,
attributed to King Loet La (Rama II, 1809-24). Dynastic chronicles and
poetry usually were dominant until the twentieth century, when King
Vajiravudh (Rama VI, 1910-25) helped foster the birth of the modern Thai
novel. Modern life was the theme of books such as Phudi (The
Genteel) by Dotmai Sot (1905-63) or Songkhram Chiwit (The War
of Life) by social realist Si Burapha (1905-74). Specific social ills,
such as inadequate education, were documented in Khammaan Khonkhai's Khru
Ban Nok, translated by Genhan Wijeyeaardene as The Teachers of
Mad Dog Swamp, or in the revolutionary writings of Chit Phumisak
and the progressive poetry of Naovarat Pongpaiboon.
American culture influenced modern Thai art forms both through Thai
artists studying in the United States and through the popularity of
Hollywood movies. Modern artists such as Kamol Tassananchalee have
integrated American ideas into Thai art, just as centuries before the
artists of Sukhothai and Ayutthaya applied Indian or Khmer concepts to
Thai design. The modern period in Thai art began in 1932 with the
breakdown of the traditional patterns of static society. A strong
artistic influence in the modern period was exerted by the work of Silpa
Bhirasri, an Italian-born professor. The Thai motion picture industry's
first film was made by a younger brother of King Chulalongkorn in 1900.
By the late 1980s, some 3,000 feature films had been produced and a
National Film Archives established. Although a few of these films, such
as Tong Pha Luang (Yellow Sky, 1980) and Sut Thon Nun
(End of the Road, 1985), were well known outside Thailand, the language
barrier rather than their quality or relevance limited their
distribution internationally.
In theater in the 1980s, Thailand produced khon (classical
masked drama) based on epics such as the Indian Ramayana (Ramakian
in Thai), as well as more modern plays. Drama, like books, movies, and
art, has moved out of the royal palaces within the last century to be
enjoyed by a wider audience in a less controlled form, which
incorporates Western elements. The Thai people accepted Westernization
in all areas, including the arts, on their own terms as a pragmatic
necessity and not as something imposed by foreigners. For example,
modern techniques in set and costume designs, makeup, lighting, sound
systems, and theater construction were combined with traditional drama
such as the khon. Thai monarchs beginning with King Mongkut
initiated and led this modernization. King Bhumibol not only continued
this movement but also widened its scope in an effort to make regional
art forms an integral part of the Thai national identity.
Thailand
Thailand - HEALTH AND WELFARE
Thailand
By Asian standards, the level of public health in Thailand was
relatively good. In 1986 the life expectancy for men was 61 years; for
women it was 65 years. In 1960 for both sexes life expectancy had been
only 51 years. In 1984 deaths among children under age 4 averaged 4 per
1,000, while infant mortality for the same year was 47.7 per 1,000. The
crude death rate for the population as a whole declined fairly
consistently between 1920 and 1984, from 31.3 to 7.7 per 1,000. Much of
the decline was a reflection of the successful struggle against malaria,
which once had been the single greatest cause of illness and death. The
expansion of the public health system in general, however, was also an
undeniable factor in the improved health picture.
Health and related social welfare services received an allocation of
10.3 percent of the total 1984 budget. Of this amount, about 50 percent
was assigned to public health activities; the remainder went to social
security and welfare, housing, and community services. Although a
disproportionate number of health care facilities were concentrated in
the Bangkok area, Western-style medical treatment was provided
throughout the country by a network of hospitals, regional health
centers, and other clinics. In 1981 there were 359 hospitals, with 1 bed
per 734 people and 1 physician per 6,951 people. In the same year, the
nation registered 1,142 dentists and more than 50,000 nurses and
midwives.
Despite progress in lengthening life expectancy, combating disease,
and building public health facilities, Thailand in the late 1980s faced
a bleak public health situation. One of the most critical national
health problems was the water supply. In the mid-1970s, little more than
20 percent of the population, most of that portion being urban dwellers,
was reported to have access to safe water. Even in Bangkok, where the
proportion with such access was highest, only about 60 percent of the
population had access to potable public water. In the countryside,
inhabitants depended on shallow wells, roof drainage, rivers, and
canals.
Throughout Thailand, but especially in Bangkok, the traditional
skyline with its Buddhist temples was becoming overshadowed by
Western-style buildings and skyscrapers. Construction was done mostly by
laborers who usually lived on site with their families. In 1980 there
were more than 373,000 construction workers (79 percent of whom had once
been farmers) living in temporary housing, which typically measured only
3 to 4 meters square and had a door but no windows. Workers'
compensation and paid sick leave were almost nonexistent, and illness
and inadequate sanitation were common in these shantytowns. Although
public and private agencies were becoming aware of the seriousness of
the problem from both a health and a legal point of view, the transient
nature of the burgeoning construction community made this population
difficult to serve. In the urban areas, modern development and outward
prosperity often masked deficiencies in basic infrastructure that arose
from rapid and unplanned growth. Urban planners were confronted with
traffic congestion, housing shortages, and air, water, and noise
pollution.
The development of an international consumer economy brought new
challenges and Western diseases, particularly for urban dwellers.
Prostitution and narcotics use, which had been part of Thai culture for
centuries, took on new dimensions as health hazards. With the worldwide
spread of acquired immune deficiency syndrome (AIDS) and new strains of
venereal diseases, Thailand became concerned about the welfare of its
female citizens and the effects on tourism. By mid-1987 eleven people in
Thailand were reported to have AIDS and about another eighty to be AIDS
carriers. The government had begun to take such action as testing
homosexuals and drug addicts for AIDS, testing donated blood supplies,
sponsoring public information campaigns, and funding the development of
an inexpensive AIDS testing kit by Mahidol University.
In the mid-nineteenth century, narcotics were seen as a domestic
problem, but one limited mostly to the Chinese. By the 1960s, drug use
was considered a security or a foreign affairs issue. Only by the late
1970s did Thailand recognize drugs as a growing domestic problem. By
that time, in addition to organic narcotic production, there was a
dramatic rise in the production and use of synthetic drugs.
Narcotics-related crimes ranked third among all types of criminal
activity in 1983. In that year, there were 28,992 convictions for drug
offenses nationally and 11,777 in Bangkok, which resulted in the
overcrowding of prisons and detention centers. To combat the problem,
the government instituted both public information campaigns and drug
treatment centers. The national media began to make daily announcements
about the social effects of drug use, and even in small provincial
cities billboards were used to carry the message. Some traditional
social systems were also employed in an innovative fashion. For example,
Wat Tam Krabok, in Sara Buri Province, became one of the most important
centers for the treatment of opiate addiction. Moreover, the government
responded to the increase in health-related problems by placing new
emphasis on meeting basic social needs in its economic and social
development planning.
Thailand
Thailand - The Economy
Thailand
THE THAI ECONOMY of the 1980s continued to function much along the
open market lines that had traditionally characterized it. It remained
capitalist in orientation, largely operated by the private sector with
supportive infrastructure furnished by the government, which had some
participation in production and commerce through a limited number of
state-owned enterprises. Commitment to the existing economic system
appeared general--none of the numerous Thai governments of the
post-World War II years had advocated significant changes.
In the 1960s and 1970s, Thailand was among the fastest growing and
most successful developing countries in the world. Rapid growth in
production, accompanied by progress in alleviating poverty, was
impressive, especially in the 1970s. By the early 1980s, however,
Thailand's economic performance had slowed, partly as a result of the
worldwide recession. Although its annual growth rate remained higher
than the average for middle-income countries, earlier expectations had
not been met. The targets of the Fifth Economic Development Plan
(1982-86) had not been achieved, and serious macroeconomic imbalances
persisted.
The government sought balanced economic growth and the closing of the
income gap, along with improvement of the inequitable distribution of
social services. Social and economic trends included increasing
urbanization, expansion of industrial activities at a faster rate than
agriculture, and growth of income in the service industries. These
trends, often associated with modernization, produced problems with
which the government tried to cope. Bangkok continued to face serious
housing shortages and severe pressure on such basic services as water,
sewerage, energy, and transport facilities. Although agriculture had
been the most important economic activity of the country with most of
the population living in the rural areas, the area of land under
cultivation was unlikely to increase. Rather, it was projected that any
increase in income would have to be gained through higher productivity
of the labor and land now in use and by the development and
diversification of industrial production. Accordingly, the government
promoted enterprises that produced agricultural products, chemicals, and
mechanical and electronic equipment and those that were labor intensive
or export oriented.
Because foreign trade and investment were an important part of the
economy, external conditions greatly influenced the country's economic
performance. Thailand's harvests exceeded domestic consumption, enabling
the country to export large quantities of food each year. The major
agricultural exports were rice, cassava products, rubber, maize, and
sugar; the major nonagricultural exports were textiles, electronics, and
tin. Imports included more than half the country's national petroleum
consumption. Although Thailand was a member of the Association of
Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) with preferential trading arrangements,
its principal trading partners were Japan, the United States, countries
of the European Economic Community (EEC), and Australia.
Long-term prospects depended greatly on the effects of international
economic conditions on the Thai economy. In the late 1970s and early
1980s, rising interest rates, declining demand and prices for Thai
exports, and rising petroleum prices had caused a serious economic
slump. Further growth of the economy depended, in part, on the success
of the Thai government in improving economic efficiency and increasing
domestic savings through development planning.
<"62.htm">ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT
<"66.htm">INDUSTRY
<"67.htm">AGRICULTURE
<"72.htm">
FORESTRY
<"73.htm">
MINING
<"74.htm">
ENERGY
Thailand
Thailand - ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT
Thailand
In the 1960s and 1970s, the country's abundant natural resources, an
enterprising and competitive private sector, and cautious and pragmatic
economic management resulted in the emergence of one of the fastest
growing and most successful economies among the developing countries.
Between 1960 and 1970, the country's average annual growth rate of gross
domestic product (
GDP) was 8.4 percent, compared with 5.8 percent for
all middle-income, oil-importing countries. Between 1970 and 1980, the
GDP rate of growth was 7.2 percent, compared with 5.6 percent for the
middle-income oil-importing countries. The world slowdown by the late
1970s was mainly caused by the rise in oil prices. The Thai GDP in 1982
was US$36.7 billion. It rose to US$42 billion in 1985. The projected rate of growth for GDP during the early
1980s was around 4.3 percent as a result of falling demand and prices
for Thai exports despite a drop in oil price. It was apparent that in
the 1980s Thailand had lost its momentum; its Fifth Economic Development
Plan targets had not been met because of serious macroeconomic
imbalances, such as decreasing savings and investment rates, increasing
budget deficits, and increasing debt and debt- servicing obligations.
Whether Thailand could regain its former momentum depended on the
success of its Sixth Economic Development Plan (1987-91).
Between 1970 and 1980, investment represented on the average 25.2
percent of GDP, compared with 24.7 percent by the mid-1980s. This
proportion was one of the lowest investment rates in Southeast Asia. The
national savings rate had fallen even more, from an average of 22
percent during the 1970s to around 17.8 percent by the mid-1980s. Hence,
the average current-account deficit of 7 percent of GDP during the early
1980s had been caused by a declining savings rate rather than by an
increase in investment rate. This imbalance was more serious than one
caused by rising investment because rising investment could pay for
itself with increased output and, possibly, increased savings so that
debt could be repaid. With falling savings, foreign borrowing was used
not to raise investment but merely to fill the investment-savings gap,
which was mirrored in the external debt ratio of 39 percent of GDP and
146 percent of exports by the mid1980s . The total debt service ratio
went up from 17.3 percent in 1980 to more than 25 percent by the
mid-1980s. The increase was an important factor in the decision of the
government to sharply reduce authorization for new commitments of public
debt.
<"63.htm">Public Finance
<"64.htm">Money and Banking
<"65.htm">Employment and Wages
Thailand
Thailand - Public Finance
Thailand
By the mid-1980s, government revenues averaged around 14 percent of
GDP and consumption averaged around 13 percent, leaving a public savings
net of interest payments of 1 percent of GDP. This was low compared with
an average savings of 7 percent for the lower middle-income countries
and 10 percent for the upper middle-income countries.
The financing of public expenditures caused a major imbalance because
of high deficit and low public savings. Although not a new problem,
increases in public expenditure needed to be matched by increases in
revenues. Efforts were made to tackle the problem, and the public
capital expenditures annual growth rate had dropped from 64.7 percent in
1980 to 8.5 percent in 1982 and 7.4 percent by the mid-1980s. The
problem remained serious, however, because of political unwillingness to
raise public revenue to the required level. In fact, the central
government managed to finance only its public current expenditures with
its revenues. Almost all capital expenditures, which averaged around 3.5
percent of GDP by the mid-1980s, were financed with borrowed funds, and
often even some of the current expenditures had been financed with
borrowed funds, thus increasing the debt-servicing burden.
Total revenue averaged around 13 percent of GDP in the 1970s and
remained at the same level in the mid-1980s. In view of the
disappointing revenue level, a new tax package was instituted in 1984-85
to raise revenues, including an increase in the tax rates on interest
earnings from 10 percent to 12.5 percent, a reduction in the standard
deduction for self-employed persons, the introduction of an estate tax,
the abolition of preferential rates for companies listed on the stock
exchange, the abolition of tax exemptions for selected state
enterprises, streamlined exemptions and deductions for business taxes,
and other measures. The resulting gains in revenue were, however,
partially offset by measures to simplify the personal and corporate tax
system. No effort had been made to reduce legal exemptions and illegal
evasions. The net revenue effect of the package was therefore
negligible.
Some experts concluded that a broader tax base, less complicated tax
structure, and lower tax rates needed to be considered in the tax
reform. Also, contributions and taxes paid by the state-owned
enterprises should be increased because they had dropped from 41 percent
of profit in the late 1970s to only 23 percent by the mid-1980s.
The Ministry of Finance required state enterprises to make specific
improvements in their financial condition as a prerequisite for
obtaining guarantees for borrowing. The measures included financing 25
percent of new investment from the state enterprises' own resources,
forwarding at least 30 percent of their profits to the treasury,
privatizing commercial enterprises, introducing corporate-planning
systems, and limiting debt financing. Such measures did not lessen the
burden of state enterprises on the budget, and their capital expenditure
financed by the government had stayed at the same average annual rate of
3.5 percent of GDP in the 1970s and mid-1980s. It was noteworthy,
however, that their performance had improved, with savings rising from
0.2 percent of GDP during the Fourth Economic Development Plan period
(1977-81) to 1.4 percent of GDP by the mid-1980s.
With approximately 68 state-owned enterprises, Thailand had fewer
than the average in other Southeast Asian countries, such as the
Philippines, with 264. Nevertheless, the government was very concerned
with their performance. The largest ones in terms of assets were in
public utilities, transport and communication, financial institutions,
and petroleum. The smaller ones were in manufacturing, agriculture,
commerce, and services. The state enterprises did not represent the
entire extent of public ownership in the economy; in the mid-1980s, the
government received 75 percent of the shares of 24 troubled finance
companies in order to rescue them from bankruptcy. In addition, the
Ministry of Finance held minority shares in eighty-eight other private
firms. All state enterprises were attached to a parent ministry or to
the Office of the Prime Minister, and there were five core agencies and
two committees to supervise their activities. Some experts suggested
that, in order to improve the efficiency of state enterprises, the
enterprises needed to be more decentralized and exposed to free market
competition.
The government spent approximately US$16 billion during the period
from 1982 to 1985. In real terms, this represented an increase of about
52 percent over public expenditures from 1977 to 1981, the fourth plan
period. Because an increasing percentage of the budget was devoted to
recurring obligations, fewer funds were available for capital
investment. Close to 70 percent of current expenditure was used for
wages, salaries, interest costs, and defense. Investment in energy,
transport, and communication had taken nearly 64 percent of total
capital expenditure by the mid-1980s. Agriculture received a fairly
constant proportion of about 15 percent of total public capital
expenditure, and industry dropped from 1.3 percent to 0.9 percent
between the end of the 1970s and the mid-1980s. Education, health, and
welfare together continued to receive about 12 percent throughout the
same period.
Thailand
Thailand - Money and Banking
Thailand
Thailand's performance in managing its money and banking affairs
through successful development and diversification of its financial
institutions was impressive in the 1960s and 1970s. However, economic
imbalances in the early 1980s and the rising tendency of governmental
intervention put the financial sector under stress, thus reducing its
efficiency in resource mobilization and allocation. Efforts to remedy
the economic imbalances in the Fifth Economic Development Plan included
restructuring monetary, exchange rate, and interest rate policies;
strengthening the open securities market; and encouraging competition
among financial institutions.
Financial Institutions
Thailand had many types of financial institutions, subject to
different laws and regulated by different agencies. Most of them were
privately owned, but some were state owned. The primary state-owned
facility was the Bank of Thailand, which had responsibility and
authority for monetary control in its role as the central bank. It
served as the fiscal agent and the financier of the government;
regulated the money supply, foreign exchange, and the banking system;
and also served as the lender of last resort to the banks. Other
state-owned facilities included the Government Savings Bank, the Bank
for Agriculture and Agricultural Cooperatives, the Industrial Finance
Corporation of Thailand, the Government Housing Bank, and the Small
Industry Finance Corporation of Thailand.
By the mid-1980s, the 30 commercial banks had 1,526 branches handling
the majority of all financial transactions in Thailand. The 16 largest
banks accounted for over 90 percent of assets, deposits, and loans of
the commercial banks, indicating a high concentration and little
competition in the banking industry. Moreover, despite the impressive
growth of banks, entrance by new banks was limited.
Finance and security companies comprised the second largest group of
financial institutions with assets equaling nearly 22 percent of those
of commercial banks. Concentration also existed in the securities
industry, the 5 largest companies (out of 112) holding 19 percent of all
finance and security assets. The finance companies were created by many
domestic and foreign banks to overcome banking restrictions. Although
they were intended to increase competition with commercial banks, the
objective was not met because many banks used the companies as an
extension of their own activities.
Money and Capital Markets
The money and capital markets were still underdeveloped in the
mid-1980s. One striking fact was that the money market was very
rudimentary and there was practically no open market for short-term
securities; the only investors in treasury bills and government bonds
were commercial banks and a few other financial institutions, which had
to hold them until maturity. Certificates of deposits did not exist,
and, for all intents and purposes, promissory notes issued by the
finance companies were nonnegotiable. In order to increase the liquidity
aspect of government bonds, in April 1979 the Bank of Thailand
established the government bond repurchase market. In reality this was
only a brokerage window at the central bank for institutional investors
and, therefore, did not help to achieve the desired objective of
open-market operation. Thus, Thai interest rates were determined, to a
significant degree, by international forces rather than central bank
sales and purchases of government securities.
The Security Exchange of Thailand (SET) had combined the functions of
securities market and securities commission, providing the legal
framework for underwriting and trading of corporation shares of common
stocks and bonds as well as government securities. In 1974 the SET
assumed the functions of the Bangkok Stock Exchange, which never had
been very active. In 1976 the SET had an upsurge because of expansionary
monetary policy. In 1978 the SET collapsed, however, because of massive
speculation, easy margin finance of up to 70 percent of a transaction,
unpreparedness and inexperience of the brokers as well as the investors,
and inadequate regulation and supervision of the market and such
activities as inside trading and manipulation. The government created at
that time two special public funds to purchase securities in order to
limit the negative effects of price swings in the SET. Many investors,
however, held on to their investments that had declined in value in
order to wait for a better price, thus decreasing normal stock market
activity. The hesitation to trade in the market created a surplus
problem for the SET, further damaging investor confidence. Some
economists suggested that more specific regulations and supervisory
systems were needed in order to revive the SET and restore public
confidence.
Rural Finance
Beginning in the late 1960s, the government gave top priority to
increasing credit availability to the agricultural sector despite the
fact that agricultural performance had been excellent during the
previous two decades. The emphasis was on providing credit to
agriculture at below market interest rates and channeling credit to poor
farmers. In 1975 the central bank imposed a mandatory credit allocation
system, under which a required minimum of 5 percent of all outstanding
bank loans were allocated to agriculture. This quota was increased to 7
percent, then 9 percent, and finally to 13 percent by the mid-1980s.
Moreover, all new rural and provincial branches of banks were required
to lend 60 percent of their local deposits in the area served by the
branch, with one-third of that amount reserved for farmers.
In 1966 the government established the Bank for Agriculture and
Agriculture Cooperatives to supply credit for the development of the
agricultural sector. In the 1980s, it became the most important single
source of credit for farmers, and it had a wide coverage of 62 branches
and 514 field units located throughout the country; more than 2 million
farm families were reached directly and indirectly via the cooperatives
and farmers associations. Noninstitutional sources, such as agriculture
and savings cooperatives, supplied 50 percent of agricultural credit,
and commercial banks and the agricultural banks each supplied 25
percent. Finance for nonagricultural activities in the rural sector,
which provided 50 percent of rural income, was largely neglected.
Industrial Finance
The government did not use a mandatory allocation system or interest
controls to affect the distribution of credit among industrial
subsectors or regions or classes of industrial borrowers. The interest
rate ceiling, however, did limit credit availability to small and medium
industrial firms. Therefore, most credit went to the larger firms, which
were mainly engaged in import substitution and were concentrated in the
Bangkok metropolitan area.
Commercial banks, finance companies, and the Industrial Finance
Corporation of Thailand (IFCT) were the main suppliers of credit to the
industrial sector. Commercial banks accounted for nearly 70 percent of
the total credit granted to the manufacturing sector by the mid-1980s,
the finance companies 24 percent, and IFCT the rest. Although the share
of the IFCT was modest, it was the only one that offered extensive
term-financing on a project basis. It was a private institution, but its
mandate was to grant loans for projects having a low financial rate of
return, which were unacceptable to commercial banks but were important
to the economy as a whole. Such loans were possible because of the
government guaranty for liquidity assistance to small borrowers and
soft-term loans. The activities of the IFCT were hampered, however, by
its being limited to fixed assets financing and by the lengthy
project-evaluation procedure.
Finance companies tended to deal with smaller borrowers than did
commercial banks in their lending to manufacturing firms because they
were allowed to charge higher rates to offset the higher risk associated
with smaller borrowers. Yet, because of the limited regional spread of
their branch networks and their limited resources, they could not fill
all the gaps left by commercial banks, such as the supply of long-term
loans.
Commercial banks provided the widest range of services. Besides
credit, they offered checking services, short-term trade credits,
guarantees for third-party borrowing, foreign exchange services, and
letters of credit. The breakdown of bank loan portfolios showed 19
percent for discount of trade bills, 58 percent for overdrafts, and 23
percent for loans. Because discounting and overdrafts were short-term
activities, the 23- percent share for loans meant that long-term
financing was scarce relative to short-term financing. Because fixed
assets such as land and buildings represented the preferred collateral
for banks, smaller borrowers with fewer fixed assets tended to be
limited in their access to loans. Once a borrower had pledged its assets
to banks for short-term financing, it could not use the assets for
collateral with another institution, such as the IFCT, for long-term
loans.
Monetary Policies
Monetary policy was traditionally passive. Control over the rate of
credit extension was the primary means for supporting growth,
maintaining price stability, and monitoring the balance of payments.
Interest rates were allowed to adjust to the rate of credit expansion
and were very much affected by international rates as a result of the
Thai open economy. Low returns tended to discourage private savings and
encourage high demand for consumer goods.
Domestic prices also were largely determined by world price movements
as a result of the country's open economy and minimal domestic price
controls. In fact the oil price increases in the early 1970s caused
inflation to rise from 4.8 percent in 1972 to 24.3 percent in 1974. The
deceleration of world prices in the early 1980s caused domestic
inflation to decline from 13 percent in 1981 to 5 percent in 1982.
Measuring by the price indexes, with 1972 as a base of 100, price
increase was less for agricultural products, going from 130.2 in 1973 to
227.7 in 1983 compared with 115.7 to 276.3 for nonagricultural products.
The highest increase among agricultural goods was for forest products,
which went from 122.9 to 403.2 during the same period. Among
nonagricultural goods, mining and quarrying showed the highest
increases. The consumer price index, taking 1976 as the base of 100,
showed the highest increase in transportation prices with 231.2 in 1982,
while the rest of the consumption basket had an increase of about 180
between 1976 and 1982. The Bangkok metropolitan area had the highest
increase with 194 in 1983, compared with 188.4 for the Northeast region,
181.6 for the Center, 180 for the North, and 178.4 for the South (these
being Thailand's four geographic regions).
Thailand
Thailand - Employment and Wages
Thailand
The average annual rate of employment growth in the 1970s was 2.7
percent, compared with 2.9 percent in labor force growth caused by rapid
population growth in the 1950s and 1960s. As a result, unemployment
reached 1.7 million in 1985, which corresponded to an unemployment rate
of around 6.3 percent. Agriculture was the major employer with about 69
percent of total employment in the mid-1980s, a decline from 84 percent
in 1960. Between 1970 and 1983 manufacturing increased its share of the
total employed labor force from 4.1 percent to 7.4 percent. Commerce
increased from 1.6 percent to 8.7 percent, and services from 7 percent
to 10 percent during the same period.
The work force had gone through some structural changes in terms of
age and sex. The fastest growing age-group in the 1960s was eleven- to
fourteen-year-olds. In the 1980s, that age-group dropped as a result of
a falling birth rate in the early 1970s and increasing primary and
secondary school enrollment. By the mid-1980s, the fastest growing group
in the work force was aged between twenty and thirty, with increasing
participation by females. The proportion of women employed went from 66
percent in 1971 to around 70 percent by the mid-1980s. Female employment
was highest in commerce with 54 percent in 1979, followed by 50 percent
in agriculture, 43 percent in industries, and 36 percent in services.
In terms of regional distribution, the North had the lowest rate of
labor force growth, with 3 percent between 1971 and 1985, followed by
the Northeast, with 3.3 percent as a result of limited job opportunities
and migration. Bangkok had the highest labor force growth with 6.9
percent. Regional growth of the labor force depended partly on the level
of education. An increasing (although still small) number of new
entrants in the work force had received a higher education. In 1971 the
percentage of the total labor force that had an elementary education was
90.2. This figure declined to 72.6 percent in 1985. For people with
lower and upper secondary education, the share went from 4.8 percent to
10.4 percent during the same period. The percentage of the labor force
with vocational training jumped from 1.9 percent to 10.4 percent between
1971 and 1985. Yet unemployment in Thailand for those with a college or
vocational education rose from 8.4 to 9 percent by the mid-1980s, mostly
because of an average increase of 13.7 percent per year in the educated
work force between 1977 and 1985.
The real wage rate between 1978 and 1985 remained the same for most
of the country, but in some regions, such as the North, it dropped from
B1.81 per hour to B1.66. Only in Bangkok did wages increase--from B3.64
to B4.20--during the period.
Real wages were stagnant because minimum wage adjustments were not
always closely linked to inflation rates, and compliance with the
minimum wage laws was not observed by the various sectors of the economy
and regions of the country. Minimum wage laws were first introduced in
April 1973 after the legalization of unions in 1972. At the outset, the
laws covered only Bangkok. They were subsequently applied to the entire
country, which was divided into three regions with three different
scales for various types of activities; agriculture and government
administration were exempted. By 1982 minimum wages in Bangkok had been
raised by 100 percent; those in other regions had been raised by 50 to
70 percent.
Thailand
Thailand - INDUSTRY
Thailand
The industrial sector in Thailand contributed considerably to
economic growth during the 1970s and 1980s. As a percentage of GDP,
industry accounted for an average of 25.7 percent in the 1970s and about
29 percent in the mid-1980s. The average annual growth rate was 9.3
percent for the 1970s, with a slowdown to 6.7 percent in 1985, which was
still very respectable by international standards. Manufacturing
constituted the most important industrial subsector, providing an
average of 17.9 percent of GDP in the 1970s and about 19.8 percent in
the mid1980s . Construction accounted for an average of 4.8 percent of
GDP during the 1970s and rose to 5.1 by the mid-1980s. Mining and
quarrying represented an average of 1.8 percent of GDP in the 1970s and
remained fairly constant. The annual growth rate was the highest for the
public utilities industrial subsector in the 1970s and mid-1980s, 13.1
percent and 8.8 percent, respectively. The annual growth rate for
manufacturing dropped from an average of 10.1 percent in the 1970s to
7.3 percent in 1985. A decline in the growth rate of mining and
construction occurred during the same period.
Manufacturing
Manufacturing was the most important industrial subsector in
Thailand, comprising on average 25 percent of each addition to GDP
(incremental GDP), or 70 percent of all industrial value added during
the 1970s and mid-1980s. Manufacturing was characterized by a high
reliance on agricultural products, including rubber products, textile
products, food processing, beverages, and tobacco. Thailand's food and
agriculture share of manufacturing value added was about 36 percent by
the mid-1980s, compared with 20 percent for South Korea and 22 percent
for Malaysia. The next most important area of manufacturing was
textiles, clothing, and leather products, produced mainly for export,
with 23 percent of manufacturing value added. Machinery and transport
equipment, which consisted mostly of repair and assembly of motor
vehicles, accounted for 11 percent, and chemicals accounted for 7
percent. The remaining 23 percent included processed minerals, wood,
rubber, carpets, batteries, rope, gunnysacks, plastic goods, tires,
footwear, and an expanding domestic small arms production.
The composition of Thai foreign trade reflected the manufacturing
sector of the Thai economy. Exports of processed food, leather, wood,
rubber, and basic metals represented a considerable share of
manufacturing output. The capital and intermediate goods industries were
less developed, however, necessitating high levels of imports of those
products. Exports of manufactured goods grew from 5.5 percent of total
exports in the 1970s to about 30 percent by the mid-1980s. Textiles and
garments were the most important contributors in the 1970s, accounting
for almost half of the total manufactured exports, but by the mid-1980s
they had dropped to about 13 percent because of rising foreign
protectionism of textiles. Exports of manufactured goods that grew
rapidly during this period were wood products, nonmetallic minerals,
electronics, electrical machinery, jewelry, and precious stones.
Employment in the manufacturing subsector accounted for 7.9 percent
of total employment by the mid-1980s and had absorbed over 16 percent of
labor force growth during the 1970s. Textile, apparel, and leather firms
had the highest share of manufacturing employment, with 25.8 percent in
the early 1980s, followed by processed food, beverage, and tobacco
firms, which accounted for 19.9 percent. Furniture and other wood
products firms accounted for 15.8 percent of manufacturing employment;
minerals, metals, and metal products, 12.6 percent; transportation
equipment, 8.5 percent; and other manufacturing firms accounted for the
remaining 17.4 percent. The growth in manufacturing employment resulted
both from the absolute growth of the subsector itself and from the labor
intensiveness of such industries as textiles. Small-scale firms with
fewer than 10 workers employed 50 percent more workers at the beginning
of the 1980s than all larger firms. However, both groups had the same
average annual growth rate of around 10 percent in the 1970s.
Manufacturing was heavily concentrated in the Bangkok metropolitan
area, as indicated by its share of 35.3 percent of total manufacturing
employment. The next highest area of concentration was in the Center.
Industries outside Bangkok were based primarily on the processing of
agricultural products, such as rubber, sugar, cassava, and rice, or on
the repair of agricultural implements. Bangkok's role as the
manufacturing center resulted from its position as the leading port, the
largest market, and the transportation, communications, and financial
center of the country.
State-owned manufacturing firms produced tobacco, playing cards,
liquor, marble, jute, sugar, paper, textiles, leather goods, glass,
batteries, and pharmaceutical products. Each state enterprise was
required to submit an annual operational and investment budget to be
approved by its board of directors, its parent ministry, the Bureau of
the Budget, and the National Economic and Social Development Board under
the Office of the Prime Minister. Each firm had on its board of
directors between nine and eleven members, all of whom were appointed by
the parent ministry. The board was responsible for setting prices with
the approval of the parent ministry. State enterprises were more
unionized and more powerful than private firms and often had salaries 50
percent higher than those in the civil service and in some private
firms. They also offered higher fringe benefits, bonuses, and overtime
pay. Planning for privatization of some unprofitable state-owned
manufacturing firms was under way in the mid-1980s, but the government
faced labor opposition and other difficulties in selling these firms.
Foreign enterprises accounted for about 30 percent of capital
investment in the form of joint ventures with some twenty foreign
countries. Japan provided more than one-third of total foreign
investment, the United States more than one-seventh, and Taiwan less
than one-eighth. The general attitude of the people toward foreign firms
was favorable until the early 1970s. At that time, world commodities
prices collapsed, causing hardship in the country. This collapse was
popularly perceived as resulting from foreign involvement in the
economy. Students and liberal elements demanded that contracts with
foreign enterprises be reexamined and renegotiated. To placate these
groups, the government revoked the extensive offshore concession of the
foreign-owned Thailand Exploration and Mining Company (TEMCO).
In the late 1980s, Thailand was considering large-scale industrial
development plans, such as the Eastern Seaboard Development Program,
which included deep-sea port facilities, a natural gas-based
petrochemical complex, a soda ash project, a fertilizer plant, and an
integrated steel complex. The petrochemical industries complex was to be
developed southeast of Bangkok and was to include a plant to process
ethane and propane into ethylene and propylene. It was to be a public
and private joint-venture project costing an estimated US$600 million.
The site of the Eastern Seaboard Development Program was to be a
major center for industrial development that would extend from east of
Bangkok toward the Cambodian border. The site was chosen because of its
proximity to Bangkok, access to raw materials and labor supplies from
the Northeast, availability of an existing deep-sea port on the Gulf of
Thailand, and excellent road and communications infrastructure. One
objective of the program was to decentralize economic activities away
from Bangkok. The other goals were the development of a wide range of
industries, including agro-industries, around Si Racha-Laem Chabang and
the development of tourism in and around Pattaya, a popular beach resort
area. The total capital requirement for the project was estimated at
US$4.5 billion: about 66 percent for heavy industrial development; about
20 percent for infrastructure; 7 percent for housing, industrial
estates, and urban services; and the remainder for light industries.
Industrial Policy
The Thai industrial sector was under the supervision of seven
governmental agencies. The Ministry of Finance administered taxes and
duties and provided tax refunds on exports. It was involved in
large-scale industrial projects in the role of deciding on government
equity participation, arranging public foreign borrowing to support the
project, and extending protection through tariffs. The Board of
Investment provided investment incentives, and the Ministry of Commerce
controlled prices and international trade. The Ministry of Industry
issued factory licenses, drew up industrial regulations, and enforced
zoning laws. It also provided technical assistance, management training,
and financing for small- and medium-sized enterprises. The Industrial
Finance Corporation of Thailand lent long-term funds to medium- and
large-scale firms from credit given by the government. The Bank of
Thailand provided foreign exchange and rediscount facilities to selected
industries and exporters at concessionary terms. Finally, the National
Economic and Social Development Board established policy guidelines and
targets for the industrial sector. In 1982 the Industrial Restructuring
Committee was created to coordinate the various agencies and to
formulate detailed policy proposals in line with economic development
plans.
Import tariffs were the most important protective measure used for
the industrial sector. In the 1960s, the nominal tariff rates were low,
ranging from 25 to 30 percent. In the 1970s, the rate went up to a range
of 30 to 55 percent for consumer goods. By the end of 1978, nine import
categories had tariff rates above 90 percent, including alcoholic
beverages, shoes, perfume, cosmetics, and automobiles. In the early
1980s, the government attempted a more uniform tariff structure and
lower protectionism in conformity with the Fifth Economic Development
Plan. The adjustments included a reduction in tariffs to 60 percent on
270 categories of imported commodities; a change in tariffs to 30
percent for 1,970 items; and an increase in rate to 5 percent for those
nonessential items that had been exempted. Goods considered essential,
such as milk for infants or fibers used in textiles, remained exempted.
Other protective measures included price controls, which were quite
pervasive in the 1970s but were relaxed at the beginning of the 1980s,
except on petroleum products, white sugar, and sweetened condensed milk.
Quantitative restrictions on imports were increased in the early 1980s
to cover forty-six products. Regulations requiring a certain percentage
of domestic content in manufactured imports included 30 to 40 percent
for commercial vehicles, 45 percent for automobiles, and 70 percent for
motorcycles.
In order to encourage investment, the Board of Investment provided
incentives, such as guarantees against nationalization and price
controls, tax exemptions of up to 8 years, and tariff surcharges of up
to 50 percent to protect against competing imports. The basic objectives
of the board were to promote laborintensive industries, exports, and
regional decentralization of industry.
Thailand
Thailand - AGRICULTURE
Thailand
Much of the impressive economic growth recorded by Thailand in the
1970s and the early 1980s was owed to the steady expansion of the
agricultural sector. This sector provided adequate food for the rapidly
growing population and produced substantial surpluses of some
commodities for export.
The Thai farmer's ability to adapt to changing market conditions
contributed to the country's agricultural success, but even more
important was the availability of large areas of virgin land for
cultivation. Between 1950 and 1980, agricultural holdings nearly doubled
to an estimated 22 million hectares, of which about three-quarters were
farmed annually, and much of the rapidly growing population was absorbed
in the expansion. By the early 1980s, however, most of the arable land
had been occupied, except in the South, and continued growth of the
agricultural sector became increasingly dependent on the acceptance of
new technologies and the adoption of more intensive cultivation.
Observers feared that without these changes growing domestic
demand--both from increasing population and from rising
expectations--would seriously affect the nation's balance of payments
position through the reduction of exportable surpluses of vital major
foreign exchange earners, such as rice and sugar.
Agriculture--crops, livestock, forestry, and fisheries-- employed
about three-quarters of the labor force, and it was estimated that some
four-fifths of the total population was dependent on the sector for its
livelihood. During the mid-1980s, agriculture accounted for an average
of about 25 percent of GDP, and agricultural commodities accounted
annually for over 60 percent of the value of all exports.
The type of agriculture engaged in--whether cash crop, subsistence,
or a combination thereof--varied from region to region and within
regions. In the central plain, there were farmers whose sole activity
was the raising of such cash crops as maize, sugarcane, vegetables, and
fruit. In the rice bowl region of the central plain, farmers grew rice
for sale as a main crop. Elsewhere, rice was raised basically for
subsistence purposes, but many farmers also cultivated secondary crops
for the market. In areas without developed access roads and services,
such as parts of the upper Northeast, participation in the market
economy was limited. Farmers in these areas practiced subsistence
cultivation, selling only an occasional surplus locally.
Agriculture was dominated by smallholders, most of whom had either
outright title to the land or effective possession of it; tenancy was
significant only in parts of the central plain. In the early 1980s, the
average holding for the whole country was about 5.6 hectares, but
considerable size differences existed within different regions and
locales that related in part to terrain, soils, rainfall, and other
natural factors. In the North, where nearly a quarter of the nation's
more than 4.5 million agricultural households were located (1983
estimate), over half the land is mountainous. In the upper part of the
region, which is characterized by narrow valleys, average holdings were
only about 2.2 hectares. In the parts of this upper area that had
controlled irrigation, the typical farm only had slightly more than one
hectare. A farm on nonirrigated land consisted of about two hectares,
part of which was rain-fed paddy and part upland. The lower part of the
region had areas similar to those in the central plain. Farms were
considerably larger, the typical one having close to five hectares. Both
paddy and upland crops were grown, and maize had become an important
secondary cash crop for many farmers.
In the Northeast, the generally infertile soil required larger
holdings to meet subsistence needs. Over half the farms had between 2.4
and 7.2 hectares, and the typical farm had an area of about 4 hectares.
In the early 1980s, about 40 percent of the country's agricultural
households lived in this region. Holdings in the Center, which contained
about 20 percent of the nation's agricultural households, varied
considerably. Near Bangkok small farms producing market vegetables might
have little more than half a hectare, whereas commercial rice farms
outside the city averaged over ten hectares. The typical commercial rice
holding on the central plain, however, averaged somewhat over three
hectares, and all available land was under cultivation. In the upland to
the east of the plain, where maize was grown commercially, the typical
farm size was close to 6.5 hectares. Cassava was also grown in this area
on somewhat smaller farms, typically of about five hectares. West of the
plain, the uplands were devoted in part to sugarcane grown on holdings
usually of about three hectares. In the South, the rugged terrain made
about two-fifths of the region unsuitable for agriculture. The climate,
however, favored the cultivation of rubber trees, and the majority of
farms grew rubber as a cash crop along with subsistence rice. A typical
household had about three hectares: 1.5 hectares of rubber trees, small
areas of coconut or fruit trees, and the rest planted in rice. In the
three southernmost provinces holdings were smaller, averaging about two
hectares.
Land Use and Soils
Roughly two-fifths of Thailand is covered by mountains and hills, the
steepness of which generally precludes cultivation. Nevertheless,
perhaps as much as a tenth of this area might also be converted to
agricultural purposes once detailed information was obtained through
surveys. Estimates in the 1970s of overall land-use suitability
classified roughly 58 percent of mountainous and hilly regions as
cultivable (compared with 24 percent 2 decades earlier), of which about
19 percent was usable for paddy, 28 percent for upland crops, and 11
percent for both paddy and upland agriculture. Actual holdings of
agricultural land--not all of which was under cultivation at any one
time--were estimated in the mid-1970s to occupy about 43 percent of the
total land area.
Soils throughout most of the country are of low fertility, largely as
a result of leaching by heavy rainfall. Differences between the various
soil types are the result of differences in parent rock material,
variations in the amount of rainfall, length of wet and dry seasons,
type of vegetable cover, and other natural factors. In general, stony
and shallow soils characterize the hill and mountain terrain of the
North. Large portions of this mountainous area were traditionally used
by hill peoples for shifting
cultivation. The Lua (also called Lawa) and Karen
cultivated for short periods, then permitted the land to lie fallow for
long periods, which allowed forest regrowth and restoration of soil
fertility. As a result of population pressures,
however, other groups sometimes failed to follow this practice. The
principle crop of many hill peoples was upland rice; maize was an
important secondary crop. The Hmong, Lisu, and certain other hill
peoples cultivated the opium poppy as a cash crop , but this activity
had important implications for internal stability as well as major
international repercussions. Thai authorities, with
substantial international assistance, increased efforts in the 1980s to
redirect these people to other cash crops, including tobacco and coffee.
Many inhabitants of the lowlands in the North also practiced shifting
cultivation in hill areas lying not far above the valleys. The valleys
usually had better soils, some of fairly high or moderate fertility,
which were used mainly to grow irrigated rice. In places where
population pressures had developed, the higher areas were often turned
to shifting cultivation to supplement lowland production. The principal
crop was usually upland rice, although other crops were also grown.
Shallow sandy loams cover a large part of the Khorat Plateau. Their
generally low fertility partly explains the lower economic level of the
region. Soils along the main rivers are more fertile, and alluvial loams
of high fertility are found along the Mekong River. Lowland soils
covering about a fifth of the Northeast (some 3.5 million hectares) had
been converted to rice paddy.
The central plain rice-growing area and the delta of the Mae Nam
(river) Chao Phraya has clayey soils of high to moderate fertility.
Low-lying and flat, much of the area is flooded during the rainy season.
Higher areas on the edges of the plain are generally well-drained soils
of high to moderate fertility that are suitable for intensive
cultivation. These lands are used extensively for maize and sugarcane.
Among other highly useful soils are the well-drained clayey and loamy
soils in parts of the peninsula where rubber is grown.
Land Tenure
Traditionally, the king owned all the land, from which he made grants
to nobles, officials, and other free subjects. If left uncultivated for
three years, the land could be taken back by the crown, but otherwise it
could be passed on to heirs or mortgaged or sold. At the same time,
there was abundant unoccupied cultivable land that by tradition and
custom could be cleared and used by a farmer, who after three years of
continuous cultivation established informal rights. The concept of
individual ownership of the land was introduced during the reign of King
Chulalongkorn (Rama V, 1868-1910), and beginning in 1901 formal title
could be acquired.
The titling of land in the mid-1980s was based on a land code
promulgated in 1954. The 1954 code established eight hectares as the
maximum permissible holding except where the owner could manage a larger
holding by himself. This limitation was generally ignored, however, and
was rescinded four years later. A title deed (chanod tidin)
giving unrestricted ownership rights ordinarily was issued only after a
cadastral survey. At least two prior steps were required before the
prospective landholder could obtain a full title deed. Application was
first made to occupy and cultivate a piece of unused land, and a
temporary occupancy permit (bai chong--reserve license) that
carried no title rights was received. After 75 percent of the land had
been cultivated, the landholder could secure an exploitation testimonial
(nor sor). This gave him the right to occupy the land
permanently and to pass the property on to heirs; in effect it was an
assurance that a title deed eventually would be forthcoming.
Transferring the land through sale, however, was extremely difficult,
and the exploitation testimonial was not usually accepted by banks as
collateral. In the case of squatters, a special occupancy permit (sor
kor) could also be obtained, unless the land was in a permanent
reserved forest or was intended for public use. Satisfactory development
could then lead to the issuance of an exploitation testimonial and
ultimately a full title deed.
The issuance of title deeds, which proceeded at a relatively slow
pace in the early 1950s, quickened somewhat during the remainder of the
decade. By 1960 the total number of title deeds for agricultural land
had reached 1 million, although there were 3.4 million agricultural
households (this total included an unknown number of tenants'
households). The pressure for titles of various kinds increased during
the 1960s and 1970s as the number of farm holdings expanded rapidly. In
an effort to expedite the processing of title deeds, the Department of
Land of the Ministry of Interior resorted in the 1970s to the use of
aerial photography in lieu of land surveys.
In the 1980s, a substantial component of the nation's dominant
smallholder group nevertheless lacked full title to the land it worked.
By 1982 the total number of title deeds was 3.9 million. A 1976 estimate
placed the proportion of farm holdings having formal title at about 60
percent. The lack of full title by the remaining 40 percent created not
only a sense of insecurity for the landholder but also presented a
barrier to securing needed credit.
A major question in the mid-1980s concerned the legalization of farm
holdings outside recognized areas for land acquisition. An unknown but
substantial number of holdings had been established by squatters--many
of them hill people--in the reserve forests, which, according to the
central government, were not eligible for titling, although the de facto
possession of such holdings was recognized by local authorities.
Observers pointed out that in many cases of forest encroachment the
occupied land was incorrectly classified and in fact was suitable for
cultivation (some reclassification was reported in the late 1970s). It
also appeared that in the drafting of the country's land laws there was
an underlying assumption that agricultural land meant the lowlands; in
other words, the land in mountainous and hill areas was considered
nonagricultural. Thus, a large part of the North was not even included
in the land registration system, and the hill peoples of the region were
therefore unable to acquire legal title to the land they used.
Tenancy and Land Reform
Historically, agricultural tenancy nationwide appeared to have been
low except in the commercial rice-growing areas of the central plain and
in the North. This situation was the result of land reforms instituted
by King Chulalongkorn beginning in 1874, the great availability of free
land, the absence of population pressures, and the relatively small
amount of funds required by the individual farmer to start cultivating
rice. Together with customary practices that tended to limit the amount
of cultivable land that could be claimed, these factors resulted in a
national pattern of small independent farms. Of great significance to
this development was the law that the farmer had to cultivate his own
land; if it was more than he or his family could handle, the farmer had
to supervise cultivation of the excess. Four hectares were considered
the maximum tillable by one family, although with hired help up to about
eight hectares could be managed, the amount varying with soil
differences and climatic conditions.
Nineteenth-century legislation set a four-hectare limit on freely
acquirable agricultural land and acted as a major deterrent to the
accumulation of land into large estates. Nevertheless, large holdings
did exist as grants to nobles and officials under the sakdi
na system. Chulalongkorn's reforms played
an important part in the breakup of at least some large estates. In such
cases the law provided that the uncultivated land would revert to the
state after a period of three years. In the area around the capital,
however, where many larger holdings were located, land could be rented
out, and the landholdings therefore remained intact.
Statistical data on tenancy in the mid-twentieth century varied
considerably. A problem of classification concerning whether the fairly
numerous part owner-part tenant arrangements should be included with
owners or tenants also led to different conclusions. The part owner-part
tenant group consisted largely of farmers who owned small plots but also
worked as tenants on other larger farms.
In some areas, 95 percent of the farmers were reported to be deeply
in debt. According to the government censuses of agriculture in 1950 and
1963, the rates of full tenancy for the country as a whole were 6.6
percent and 4.1 percent, respectively. Rates varied significantly by
region. In 1963 the rate in the Center, the chief agricultural area
containing the rice-growing central plain, was 10.7 percent as compared
with 1.1 percent in the North. A special 1967-68 survey of the Center
determined the full tenancy rate to be 22.5 percent (part owners-part
tenants constituted an additional 15.8 percent). A 1973-74 survey of the
Center, as well as other regions, showed the full-tenancy rate in the
Center to be 12 percent (part owners-part tenants constituted another 28
percent). The remainder were full owners. Tenancy in the Center in areas
devoted completely to commercialized agriculture was very high, however,
especially in some districts near Bangkok where as many as 75 to 85
percent of the farmers were reported in the mid-1970s to be full
tenants. Lower, but still comparatively high, rates of tenancy were also
found in certain other districts of the plain.
The unusually high tenancy rates were attributed to several factors,
including the proximity to Bangkok of estates that were granted to the
ancestors of present-day holders under the sakdi na system;
large holdings received as remuneration for the digging of canals; and,
since the 1950s, acquisition of land as investment by individuals
residing mostly in Bangkok. Figures published in 1975 covering 4
provinces in the Bangkok area cited 119 estates ranging in size from 160
hectares to 1,600 hectares and comprising a total of more than 60,000
hectares. Another factor contributing to tenancy in the central plain
was the loss of holdings to creditors by farmers unable to repay loans.
A large proportion of the small leaseholds was reported to be owned by
storekeepers, local craftsmen, and other farmers.
The 1973-74 agricultural survey also provided data on tenancy in
other regions. In the North, the survey found that 4 percent of the
farmer operators were full tenants, 25 percent were part owners-part
tenants, and 69 percent were full owners. The southeastern provinces of
the North, where conditions resemble those of the central plain,
reportedly had a higher percentage of farmers renting some or all of
their land. In the Northeast, full tenants constituted only a negligible
proportion; 89 percent of farm operators were full owners, and 8 percent
were part owners-part tenants.
In the South, full tenants likewise were only a very small minority;
83 percent were full owners, and 16 percent were part owners-part
tenants. One reason given for the development of the part owner-part
tenant situation was the effect of Islamic inheritance laws, which in
theory divide the land equally among the children. In such cases, the
inherited holding might be inadequate to meet family needs, and
supplementary land would be rented. The part owned-part rented condition
was not in itself detrimental. There appeared to be many cases in which
additional land was rented solely because the farmer family believed it
would benefit financially by cultivating it.
Unrest among tenants, who constituted a substantial portion of the
nation's poorer farmers, began to manifest itself in the early 1970s.
Tenant discontent centered chiefly on the amount of rent, but also of
great concern was the fact that use of the land was often based on a
verbal agreement that rarely exceeded one year and carried no guarantees
of renewal. In 1950 a land rent- control act covering part of the
central plain was passed but proved generally ineffective. The civilian
cabinet that succeeded to power in October 1973 promised rent and land
reform. Implementing action was not immediately forthcoming, however,
and farmer dissatisfaction mounted, finally erupting in demonstrations
in May and June 1974. In December of that year, the government passed a
rent reform law known as the Agricultural Land Rent Control Act of 1974,
providing for six-year, indefinitely renewable rental contracts. Rents
were to be payable once a year only, and procedures for determining the
amount were specified. Moreover, if a poor harvest occurred, the rent
was to be reduced, and none would be paid if the harvest were less than
one-third normal.
Associated with tenancy was the equally serious problem of landless
farmers, who by the early 1980s numbered an estimated 500,000 to
700,000. In January 1975, the civilian government, over strong
opposition, managed to get through the National Assembly a second reform
measure of potentially far-reaching effect. This was the Agricultural
Land Reform Act of 1975. The legislation called for the establishment of
the Agricultural Land Reform Office in the Ministry of Agriculture and
Cooperatives to serve as the implementing agency. Under the act,
landless and tenant farmers could be allocated up to eight hectares of
land that would be paid for on a long-term installment basis. The land
to be allocated was to come from purchases from private holders and from
forest and crown lands. Individual landowners were required to make
available to the program all but eight hectares of their holding. Under
certain circumstances, larger holdings could be retained, but such
holdings could be expropriated later if the provisions of the exception
were not met. Payment for the private land taken was to be 25 percent in
cash and the remainder in government bonds.
Implementation of land reform slowed after the coup of October 1976,
which ousted the civilian government, and the act's goals were
subsequently shifted. The government of Prime Minister Thanin
Kraivichien, installed as head of a military regime in October 1976,
announced that a land reform program covering 1.6 million hectares and
taking place over a period of four years would be carried out. Prime
Minister Kriangsak Chomanand, who succeeded to office in November 1977
after still another military coup, modified this goal to a more
realistic one of 1.3 million hectares over five years. By early 1979,
almost eighty areas throughout the country had been designated Land
Reform Areas under the program. At the same time, although tenancy
remained a major issue, a somewhat different concept of reform seemed to
have emerged, based on the belief that the most pressing problem was to
improve the situation of the large numbers of illegal squatters in the
forests. The Land Reform Areas included some areas of high tenancy, but
the new goal of helping forest squatters appeared easier to promote than
land acquisition by the Agricultural Land Reform Office in the
high-tenancy areas of the central plain. There it was strongly opposed
by large landowners, including wealthy aristocrats, businessmen, and
senior military officers.
The program as projected included furnishing legal titles to
squatters and providing them with needed infrastructure and credit. The
areas brought under the program were to be organized into
self-sufficient cooperatives. Implementation of a given project was
expected to take about two years, including about a year and a half to
get the basic infrastructure well under way and to provide titles. The
latter would permit the landholder to pass on the land to heirs but
would not confer the right to sell it to private parties. The title,
however, could be used as collateral for credit. According to government
sources, by 1978 some 320,000 hectares consisting mainly of public land
had been distributed, and another 160,000 hectares were ready to be
apportioned.
<"68.htm">
Irrigation
<"69.htm">
Crops
<"70.htm">
Livestock and Poultry
<"71.htm">Fisheries
Thailand
Thailand - Irrigation
Thailand
Thai farmers traditionally relied on rain and flood water for crops,
but the amount needed for rice cultivation was not always received. By
the mid-1800s, a number of canals had been constructed in the central
plain to carry floodwaters from the Chao Phraya, and in the latter half
of the century other canals were dug. The canals did not form a
controlled irrigation system, however, but simply a distribution net,
and whether additional water could be made available depended on the
level of the rivers. Records covering almost a hundred years to 1930
showed that in about one-third of the years water from the rivers was
insufficient, resulting in considerable crop losses. In 1902 the
government contracted with a Dutch expert to develop a controlled
irrigation plan for the entire country but failed to take further
action. Droughts in 1910 and 1911 led to renewed interest and the hiring
of a British irrigation specialist. Nevertheless, the first irrigation
project was not completed until 1922.
By 1938 about 440,000 hectares had been irrigated. Supply problems
held up projects during World War II, but work resumed with renewed
vigor in the late 1940s. By 1950 the irrigated area totaled nearly
650,000 hectares. In 1950 Thailand secured the first of a series of
loans from the World
Bank for the construction of the vital Chainant
Diversion Dam on the Chao Phraya and a number of major canals. By 1960
over 1.5 million hectares had been irrigated, almost entirely in the
Center and in the North.
Systematic development of the irrigation system began with the First
Economic Development Plan (1961-66) and was continued in later plans.
New assistance from the World Bank included financing of the important
multipurpose Phumiphon (Bhumibol) Dam (completed in 1964) on the Mae Nam
Ping and the Sirikit Dam (completed in 1973) on the Mae Nam Nan. These
dams, both of which have associated hydroelectric power-generating
facilities, impound water at two large reservoir locations in the Chao
Phraya Basin. Other World Bank-financed projects were also carried out
in this basin during the 1970s, and by the end of the decade nearly 1.3
million hectares had controlled water flow in the rainy season, and
about 450,000 hectares had it in the dry season.
The Chao Phraya Basin's natural features, as well as its size, made
it the most important area for irrigation development. The topography
and water systems of the Northeast, by contrast, were not well suited to
large-scale irrigation projects (except on the Mekong River, which would
involve major resettlement problems). Controlled irrigation potentially
could encompass about 10 percent of the Northeast's 3.5 million hectares
of paddy. Beginning in the 1960s, the Royal Irrigation Department,
founded in 1904 and largely responsible for development and maintenance
of the country's main irrigation systems, constructed 6 large and about
200 small dams in the region. The associated irrigation system contained
design defects, and in the mid-1970s improvement was undertaken with
World Bank assistance. Part of the irrigable area was receiving water in
the early 1980s, but completion of necessary additional work was not
anticipated before the late 1980s, at which time about 160,000 hectares
would have irrigation throughout the year.
Irrigation work also began in the 1960s in the Mae Nam Mae Klong
Basin, which contained nearly 400,000 irrigable hectares of paddy.
Regulated wet-season irrigation was furnished during the 1970s for
roughly 175,000 hectares. A multiple dam completed in the late 1970s and
a distribution system under way in the 1980s was expected to provide
adequate water for double cropping on over 250,000 hectares. Small
irrigation projects also were started in the 1960s in the South, on the
east coast where more than 500,000 of the region's 600,000 hectares of
paddy were located. About 75,000 hectares had supplementary wet-season
water, and work under way in the 1980s in the Mae Nam Pattani Basin was
expected eventually to serve about 52,000 hectares.
Thailand
Thailand - Crops
Thailand
Climatic and soil conditions permit the cultivation of a wide range
of crops, not only tropical varieties but also many originating in
semitropical and temperate zones. Until the late 1950s, however, the
major emphasis in agriculture was on rice and, secondarily, on rubber,
which together accounted for over half the value of all commodity
exports. Other crops regularly grown included maize, cassava, potatoes,
yams, beans, sugarcane, fruit, cotton, and various oilseeds, but all
were supplementary and intended basically for domestic use.
Historically, Thailand's independent status had kept it from being
saddled with a colonial plantation economy, in which two or three
principal crops were produced for world markets or for the imperial
power. Agricultural production, however, had been strongly influenced by
the West after the Bowring Treaty of 1855 with Britain, which resulted
in crop diversification. Accordingly, when new market conditions--
increased world demand, higher prices, and developing domestic
industry--arose during the 1960s and 1970s, Thailand's independent small
farmers responded by expanding substantially the output of many
secondary crops. The flexibility of the Thai farmer was evidenced by an
unprecedented shift from rice production to other crops by a
considerable number of households. In other cases, many farmers
continued to produce rice for subsistence purposes while expanding their
activities to grow market-oriented upland crops. In the mid-1980s, major
export crops included not only rice and rubber but also maize, cassava,
sugarcane, mung beans, tobacco, and sorghum. Other important crops in
which major production increases also had been made were pineapples,
peanuts, cashew nuts, soybeans, bananas, sesame, coconuts, cotton,
kapok, and castor beans.
Rice
Rice, the nation's major crop, was grown by about threequarters of
all farm households in the early 1980s. Two main types were cultivated:
dry, or upland, rice, grown predominantly in the North and Northeast;
and wet rice, grown in irrigated fields throughout the central plain and
in the South. About half the 1986 production of 19 million tons was
grown in the central plain and major valleys in the North; another
two-fifths was produced in the Northeast; and about 6 percent came from
the South, which was a rice deficient area. Roughly 8.5 million hectares
were devoted to rice production in the early 1980s, about 40 percent
more than in the early 1960s. The rice yield was highest in the Center,
averaging about 1.9 tons per hectare, which was about a third of the
yield per hectare in Taiwan and South Korea.
Low productivity was attributed in part to longstanding government
policies aimed at keeping consumer rice prices low. The so-called rice
premium (in fact an export tax) and occasional quantitative export
controls were claimed by opponents to have discouraged production
expansion by reducing profitability. Although perhaps a valid argument
for commercial rice farming, the policies probably had a minimal effect
on the large number of subsistence farmers in the Northeast and North,
who produced small, if any, surpluses and whose dry rice was not usually
exported. Perhaps more significant was the apparent loss of paddy
fertility in the North and Northeast because of poor soil management and
the extension in those regions of the growth of lower yield upland rice.
Rubber
In 1901 British planters introduced rubber trees into the Malay
Peninsula, where the soils and climatic conditions were highly suited to
rubber cultivation. In Thailand early government restrictions on foreign
investment led to development of the industry by local smallholders,
usually subsistence rice farmers who were able to start rubber tree
stands on the relatively abundant free land in the area. Land under
rubber cultivation expanded rapidly in the 1930s, consisting mainly of
smallholdings controlled by Chinese, Thai, and Thai Malays rather than
large, European-owned plantations, as in other Asian countries. Thailand
had about 1.6 million hectares in rubber in the mid-1970s, of which
about 10 percent were located in an area along the Gulf of Thailand
southeast of Bangkok. Of the 500,000 holdings in the early 1980s, about
150,000 were under 2.5 hectares in size, and another 300,000 were under
10 hectares. The remaining larger holdings were operated more as
expanded smallholdings than as plantations. Production was increasing in
the early 1980s and had reached about 830,000 tons in 1987. An extensive
replanting program, in which old tree stock was replaced with new
high-yield varieties, had reportedly been carried out in about half the
planted area by the mid-1980s, significantly increasing the potential
for expanded production.
Maize
Maize was believed to have been introduced by Spanish or Portuguese
traders in the sixteenth century. Export interest and profitability led
to increased maize cultivation after World War II and the introduction
of the so-called Guatemala strain in 1951. Output rose rapidly
thereafter to almost 600,000 tons in 1961, over 1 million tons in 1965,
and 2.3 million tons in 1971. A record 5 million tons were produced in
1985. Fertilizer use was limited, however, and there was concern that
yields would gradually decline. The grain was grown throughout Thailand,
but the uplands around the central plain were especially suitable.
Weather conditions usually permitted commercial growers to produce two
crops a year.
Cassava
Cassava, a root crop from which tapioca is made, was introduced in
about 1935. The tubers may also be boiled and eaten as a vegetable or
ground into flour. An important food in many tropical subsistence
economies, cassava had never been significant in Thailand in the past
because of the abundance of rice. Cassava developed into an important
export item in the 1950s, and production continued through the 1970s and
1980s as external demand increased. Thai output of cassava root in 1984
was more than 19 million tons, second only to Brazil in world
production. The main growing areas were Chon Buri and Rayong provinces,
southeast of Bangkok, but substantial quantities were also grown in
parts of the Northeast. In 1986 Thailand signed a 4-year tapioca trade
agreement with the EEC calling for export of 21 million tons of tapioca
during the 1987-91 period.
Other Crops
Sugarcane has long been widely grown. Some commercialization was
reported by the mid-nineteenth century, but the crop became of major
importance only after World War II. In the early 1950s, production
averaged 1.6 million tons annually, and in the late 1950s
self-sufficiency in sugar was attained. In 1960 Thailand became a net
exporter of sugar. Rising world prices led Thailand's market-responsive
farmers to expand cropped areas in the 1970s. In 1976 sugarcane
production reached a record 26.1 million tons, and sugar output totaled
2.2 million tons, the latter amount being considerably in excess of
international and domestic demands. Drought in 1977 greatly reduced
output and seriously affected many small growers. Declining world prices
after 1975, drought, and lower producer prices in 1978 led many farmers
to shift to alternate crops. In 1986 about 24 million tons of sugarcane
were produced.
Productivity was low compared with other major sugarcane-growing
countries (about fifty-three tons of sugarcane per hectare against
Taiwan's seventy tons and Indonesia's eighty tons in the mid-1970s).
Introduction of new varieties and improved cultivation and cropping
practices were needed to raise output levels. The principal
sugarcane-growing areas were in and around Kanchanaburi Province and in
Chon Buri Province in the Center. Sugarcane was also grown in the
Northeast and in the North around Chiang Mai, Lampang, and Uttaradit.
Kenaf, a coarse fiber similar to jute but of somewhat lesser quality,
is native to the country and has long been grown for local use in making
sacks, cord, and twine. Commercial cultivation began in the Northeast in
the 1950s, and production was largely concentrated in the central and
eastern parts of the region in 1980. World shortages created by the
Indo-Pakistani War of 1965 temporarily stimulated Thai production of
jute, as did shortages resulting from the 1971 civil war in Pakistan.
The recovery of jute cultivation in Bangladesh (formerly East Pakistan)
and broad swings in producer prices led many Thai farmers in the late
1970s to replace kenaf with cassava, which commanded a higher return.
The 1984 kenaf crop was estimated at about 200,000 tons, compared with
an average annual output of over 400,000 tons in the previous decade.
Increased world demand, however, was expected to encourage a revival in
planting.
Tobacco, an important foreign exchange earner, had long been grown by
farmers for personal and local use. Virginia flue-cured tobacco had been
produced commercially since the 1930s, but export began only in 1956.
Some burley and oriental (Turkish) tobacco was also grown. United
Nations sanctions against Rhodesia beginning in the mid-1960s opened new
markets, and production of Virginia tobacco rose from 13,700 tons in
1967 to more than 50,000 tons in 1981. About half of the commercial
tobacco was grown in the North and another quarter in the Northeast.
Tobacco growers were licensed, and a large number operated under the
aegis of the state-owned Thai Tobacco Monopoly.
Pineapples, exported chiefly as canned fruit and juice in the early
1980s, were grown solely as a supplementary crop for local use until the
first pineapple cannery was opened in 1967. A shortage of fruit led
several canneries to establish large pineapple plantations (ranging up
to more than 3,000 hectares--in sharp contrast to the smallholding
character of most Thai agriculture), which supplied about 40 percent of
cannery needs in the late 1970s. The industry grew dramatically, and by
the early 1980s Thailand was one of the world's largest exporters of
pineapples, producing about 1.6 million tons in 1984.
Production and export of coffee expanded rapidly after Thailand
became a member of the International Coffee Organization in 1981.
Exports of coffee beans, most of which were grown in the South, reached
20,600 tons in 1985.
Thailand
Thailand - Livestock and Poultry
Thailand
Animal husbandry accounted for about 13 percent of the gross value of
agricultural production in the early 1980s. Water buffalo and cattle
remained the chief draft animals for cultivation, although tractors were
playing an increasing role in some areas, as in the maize-growing
regions of the central plain. Buffalo, predominantly of the swamp type
well suited to paddy culture, were estimated at between 5.5 and 7.2
million. Able to flourish on coarse fodder and roughage indigestible by
other livestock, buffalo were found in all farming areas; even very
small paddy farmers usually had at least one animal. After maturing,
buffalo were used as draft animals for five or six years, or until too
old to work, when they were slaughtered and sold for meat. Cattle,
numbering between 4.9 and 5.5 million, were used mainly for upland
plowing and hauling carts. About 70 percent of all farms had cattle.
Although 30 percent of farms had three or more head, there were few
herds of more than 10 animals. Cattle also were slaughtered for meat
once their usefulness had ended.
Pigs were an important source of meat, and there were about 5 million
in the early 1980s. Most farmers raised one or two, and an estimated
150,000 families were engaged in commercial pig raising. Weather
conditions were generally unsuitable for using horses except in the
North, where the common variety was the so-called Yunnan pony mainly
valued as a pack animal. Tame elephants remained important to the forest
industry in the 1980s, especially in harvesting teak, where the use of
mechanical equipment was economically prohibitive because of the wide
dispersal of individual trees.
Livestock reproduction rates were low because most animals were bred
only when it did not interfere with work. In addition, debilitating
diseases, including foot-and-mouth disease, were endemic to all regions
except the South. These diseases retarded expansion of the national herd
of livestock, which was reported to be growing at only about 2.5 percent
annually in the early 1980s. Shortages of meat in Bangkok in the early
1970s led to student demonstrations and the establishment of export
quotas in early 1974 (in early 1979 the quotas were 35,000 head of
cattle and 15,000 of buffalo annually). Several commercial dairy herds
and smallholder dairy cooperatives furnished some milk for sale. Demand
for fresh milk and dairy products had grown, especially in Bangkok.
Almost all smallholders raised some chickens and ducks for eggs and
meat. The commercial production of chickens grew dramatically in the
1970s, and nearly 65,000 tons of frozen chickens were exported in 1986,
of which 95 percent went to Japan. A considerable number of commercial
operations had flocks of over 20,000. Select breeding stock was used,
and modern operational practices were followed. Commercial duck farms
were almost entirely Chinese operated.
Thailand
Thailand - Fisheries
Thailand
In the 1980s, the fisheries sector was of major importance to the
economy as an earner of foreign exchange, marine products accounting for
about 10 percent of total exports in 1986. Fish also accounted for about
three-fifths of the protein in the national diet and an even higher
proportion among the poorer rural population. Until the early 1960s, the
country had been a net importer of fish. This situation completely
changed with the introduction of trawl fishing, which resulted in a
dramatic rise in the marine catch from 146,000 tons in 1960 to 1 million
tons in 1968 and 2.1 million tons in 1985. Thailand became the third
largest marine fishing nation in Asia after Japan and China. Of
Thailand's 40,000 fishing vessels, nearly 20,000 were deep-sea trawlers,
many with modern communication and navigation equipment and
refrigeration facilities.
By 1980 large-scale fishing operations, based largely in urban areas,
were responsible for 88 percent of Thailand's annual catch. The fishing
industry was the economic backbone of many Thai coastal cities. The
increase in the catch of shrimp was particularly notable, and shrimp
exports became a major source of foreign exchange earnings. By about
1972 maximum exploitation of demersal (bottom-dwelling) and pelagic
(open-sea) fish appeared to have been reached in the Gulf of Thailand
and in the Andaman Sea. In the early 1980s, production remained
relatively static, and there was growing concern that these areas were
being overfished.
Government control of fishing was limited. The use of certain kinds
of fishing gear within three kilometers of the coast was banned, but
there appeared to be no restriction on trawl net-mesh size, and
undersized commercial food fish were being caught and dumped in with
trash fish in the production of fishmeal. Moreover, during the 1970s
neighboring Cambodia claimed territorial waters extending to 200
nautical miles from its coast. This reduced the area in the Gulf of
Thailand available to Thai fishermen and increased the intensity of
fishing off the coast of Thailand. Similar claims by Burma had also
restricted Thai fishing in the Andaman Sea.
Inland fisheries, which included both freshwater and brackish water
fish, officially reported annual catches of about 160,000 tons in the
early 1980s. The actual catch--principally freshwater fish from flooded
rice paddies, swamps, irrigation and drainage ditches, canals,
reservoirs, rivers, lakes, and ponds--was estimated to be much higher.
It was believed, however, to be declining as population growth resulted
in overfishing and as increasing water pollution from industrial waste,
insecticides, and siltation caused by forest destruction took its toll.
The most promising course for maintenance of fisheries production at
the level attained in the 1970s, or for increasing output, was the
expansion of aquaculture, including the culture of fish, shrimp, and
various mollusks, such as mussels, oysters, and clams. According to the
Department of Fisheries, about 4.5 million hectares of inland water
areas, mostly rice paddy fields, were suitable for aquaculture. Another
1.3 million hectares, including estuaries, mangrove swamps, and tidal
flats, were also usable.
Thailand
Thailand - FORESTRY
Thailand
An aerial photographic survey conducted in 1961 showed forests to
cover about 54 percent (or if swamp and scrub areas are included, 56
percent) of Thailand. In the succeeding two decades, this area was
substantially reduced as a rapidly growing population pushed into the
forests seeking new land for agricultural use. Increasing prices for
certain upland crops, especially in the 1970s, also acted as a strong
incentive for conversion of forests to cultivated lands. By the
mid-1980s, the expansion of the cultivated area had resulted in a
decrease in the amount of forestland to less than 30 percent.
Except for a few small, privately owned, coastal mangrove areas, all
forestland was the property of the state. Roughly 32 percent of the 1961
forest area, largely in the North and Northeast, had been designated
permanent reserved forest through the end of the 1960s. Government plans
called for additions in subsequent years to raise the total to about 51
percent. Clearing or cutting of timber or settling in such land was
possible only with an official permit. Many of the stream valleys in
these reserve areas, however, were highly suitable for agricultural use.
Traditionally, farmers had been able to occupy unreserved public land on
a free basis, restrictions in such cases relating only to the cutting of
certain timber tree species, which remained the property of the state.
As population growth increased the demand for land, farmers in the 1970s
also moved into the reserved forests with little or no effective
hindrance from government agencies. This situation was generally
nonreversible, and observers anticipated that eventually most such
holdings suitable for cultivation would be legalized under the
agricultural land reform program.
Areas of forest usable for permanent cultivation still existed in the
early 1980s, mostly in the South. In other regions there were
logged-over areas and scrubland (at times included with forestland),
part of which could be used for agriculture. Extant forest areas--minus
potentially cultivable land--were still considered sufficient to meet
domestic timber and other wood requirements and also to provide a
surplus of forest products for export. Foreign and Thai forestry
specialists were agreed that for this situation to continue, positive
steps would have to be taken, including an adequate program of
reforestation, prevention of illicit cutting and the use of steep forest
slopes for cultivation purposes, and active promotion of more efficient
forest exploitation practices. In the early 1970s, the Food and
Agriculture Organization recommended a reforestation program of 1
million hectares. The government later approved a plan to replant
120,000 hectares.
Major exploitation of the highly valuable teak wood for exportation
was begun by European interests in the late 1800s, and by 1895
indiscriminate cutting had largely exhausted the more easily workable
stands. About this time, the government established a system of control
that included leases and cutting cycles (a teak tree takes from 80 to
150 years to mature fully, depending on local soils and weather). By
1909, when controls were further tightened, almost all of the industry
was in European hands, mainly British but also Danish and French. During
World War II, a Thai company took over all concessions, and although a
few were returned to foreign control for a period after the war, the
government's long-term goal of full Thai operation was attained in the
late 1950s.
Although modern logging equipment was in widespread use, difficult
terrain and lack of roads in many areas necessitated the use of
elephants in logging operations. In 1982 there were 12,000 working
elephants in Thailand, including those trained at the Royal Forestry
Department's Young Elephant Training Center.
The exploitation of Thailand's forests was the responsibility of the
Royal Forestry Department. Through the Forest Industry Organization, a
state-owned enterprise, the government controlled nearly all extraction
of mature teak. However, illegal felling of teak continued to be a
serious problem in the 1980s, although the extent of the cutting was
uncertain. A decade earlier, estimates had placed illegal cutting at
from one-third to an amount greater than legal cutting. Some idea of the
magnitude of the situation was evident in a 1973 report of the Royal
Forestry Department, which cited some 7,600 incidents of illegal teak
felling. The department was not only unable to patrol adequately all
forest areas but authorities also failed to act against illegal logging
operations connected with politically influential individuals and
families.
Major damage to permanent forest areas also occurred, especially in
the 1970s and 1980s, through occupation of hillside forestland that was
not suitable for cultivation. This practice was carried on throughout
the country and resulted not only in destruction of forests but also in
erosion and damage to watersheds. Notable forest destruction occurred
over time in the North because of shifting cultivation practiced mainly
by the hill peoples of the region. Of the roughly 70 percent of this
region classified as forests, well over a quarter was being used for
such cultivation in the late 1960s, according to a government report.
The amount grew tremendously during the 1970s as the population of the
hill peoples increased. In addition, many landless Thai were reported to
have migrated to the area, and others who were farming agricultural land
in the valleys also were practicing shifting cultivation on the hills
and mountainsides to supplement production. According to some sources,
forested lands in the Northeast declined from about 60 percent in 1956
to less than 20 percent two decades later.
Although teak had been a major long-term source of foreign exchange
earnings, the output by volume of timber from other commercially
valuable species was far greater. Thailand had a large number of such
species, of which the most commonly exported one was yang,
related to the so-called Philippine mahoganies. Others were of great
value domestically, supplying the country's general requirements for
timber and wood products of various sorts. In the 1980s, however, the
forests failed to meet the demand for raw materials for paper and paper
products, and these were being imported in growing quantities. Only
limited stands of pine existed, and development of a domestic pulp and
paper industry appeared to depend on the establishment of suitable
forest plantations.
Thailand
Thailand - MINING
Thailand
Thailand's mineral reserves had not been well assessed in the 1980s.
Mining and quarrying accounted for only a small share of GDP, in 1986
amounting to about 2 percent of the total in real terms. About thirty
minerals were exploited commercially, but many were of minor
significance. Tin, tungsten, fluorite, and precious stones were
important foreign exchange earners in the early 1980s and so, to a
lesser extent, was antimony. Minerals of substantial value to the
domestic economy included lignite, gypsum, salt (which was also
exported), iron ore, lead, manganese, limestone, and marble.
Tin was the leading mineral. The existence of tin in the area of
present-day Thailand was known at least by the thirteenth century, when
it was alloyed with copper in casting bronze images of the Buddha. In
the 1980s, major workings were located in the southern peninsula,
although deposits were also found and worked in several other parts of
the country. The ore was obtained from onshore alluvial deposits,
weathered and disintegrated formations, river beds, and offshore
deposits along the seacoasts.
Production of tin concentrates averaged over 29,000 tons annually in
the early 1970s, dropped to about 22,000 tons in the mid-1970s, and then
rose to 46,000 tons in 1980. By 1985 tin production had dropped to about
23,000 tons as a result of export controls imposed by the International
Tin Council and the indefinite closing of a major offshore mining
company. The actual output of concentrates in the 1980s was believed to
have been at least 10 percent higher than officially reported. The
additional quantity represented tin concentrates smuggled from the
country to escape payment of both business taxes and the statutory
royalty deducted from the price paid to the seller by the
foreign-controlled Thailand Smelting and Refining Company (THAISARCO).
The export of tin ore and concentrates was banned by the government
after THAISARCO began smelting tin in 1965 at a newly constructed plant
on Phuket Island. Most of the smuggled concentrates originally went to
Penang, but this trade had been largely halted by the Malaysian
authorities; in the 1980s, the illegal ore was sent to Singapore for
smelting.
Since the mid-1970s, the tin-mining industry has generated a large
amount of political controversy, social unrest, and illegal activity
that continued into the mid-1980s. Onshore mining operations were
carried on mostly by small miners who were predominantly Thai. Offshore
operations included a number of large dredges owned by both Thai
enterprises and foreign firms, as well as thousands of suction boats.
Both kinds of operations were supposed to be registered with local
provincial authorities. The tin fields had attracted large numbers of
the unemployed or persons seeking fortunes, however, who mined
illegally. Reports of a new tin strike brought thousands of individuals
to the area, resulting in such attendant social problems as claim
jumping, forged registration certificates, frequent violence, and the
like. In 1975 the government-owned Offshore Mining Organization (OMO)
was set up to replace large offshore oil concessions owned by foreign
corporations and ousted Thai government leaders. A substantial amount of
illegal dredging was also reported in the OMO concession area, whose
size and restrictions of exploitation to subconcessionaires had created
strong resentment among independent small operators, even though the OMO
had given concession rights to a considerable number of them. In late
1979, a group of nonconcession-holding small dredgers pressed the
provincial authorities of the area to urge the central government to
revoke all restrictions on mining in the OMO holdings. The overall
magnitude of illegal operations appeared in the early 1980s to be beyond
the ability of the local authorities to control. Official action,
moreover, was often deterred by public sympathy for the poor person
struggling to eke out a living.
Thus, illegal mining was an important source of employment in the
southern peninsula and, in conjunction with related illegal operations,
created numerous ancillary jobs. From the national viewpoint, however, a
great loss of natural wealth occurred because of haphazard and
inefficient exploitation. Onshore miners, legal and illegal, tended to
take out only the readily accessible richer ore, leaving varying amounts
of lower grade ore that, mined separately, was uneconomic. Large numbers
of small dredges sent divers down to find rich spots that were sucked
up, avoiding large nearby areas containing ore that was costly to mine.
Many of the dredges also had poor separation equipment, and considerable
quantities of ore were lost in the tailings. Because of potential
political problems, decisive action by the central government (or
provincial governments) to resolve this problem did not appear imminent
in the late 1980s.
Thailand is a rich source of sapphire, ruby, zircon, garnet, beryl,
quartz, and jadeite, and in 1986 gems and jewelry were a large export
item in terms of value. Significant deposits of rubies were located in
Chanthaburi and Trat provinces in the southern part of the Center, and
deposits of sapphire were found in Kanchanaburi Province. Stones were
also imported from Sri Lanka, Australia, Africa, and South America for
cutting and setting into jewelry. By the mid-1980s, Thailand had become
one of the world's major gemcutting centers, and the craftsmanship of
Thai gemcutters was widely recognized.
Tungsten, an important source of foreign exchange earnings beginning
in the early 1970s, was found in the mountains in the North and in the
Bilauktaung Range along the Burmese border. In 1970 a major find of the
tungsten mineral wolframite was made in Nakhon Si Thammarat Province in
the South. Antimony, also an important export, was found in many parts
of the country. Mining was carried on almost entirely by small
operators, but in the mid-1970s cumulative annual production was about 6
percent of total world output. Fluorite, one of Thailand's principal
exports, was mined mainly in the North in Chiang Mai and Lamphun
provinces, where large reserves existed. Relatively large deposits of
rock salt of approximately 97 percent purity underlay areas in the
Northeast. Reserves were estimated to be at least 2 billion tons.
Although having great future export potential, the lack of an adequate
transportation infrastructure posed a major problem for exploitation of
the rock salt reserves.
Offering a hopeful promise of a new source of foreign exchange
earnings and savings on imports in the 1980s was the long-delayed
development of zinc mining and refining. This involved exploitation of a
large ore deposit, estimated at 3.5 million tons of 25 percent content,
at Mae Sot in Tak Province near the Burmese border. A zinc smelter
constructed by a ThaiBelgian consortium began operation in 1984.
Thailand
Thailand - ENERGY
Thailand
Historically, the population has had adequate supplies of fuel in the
form of wood charcoal, which was usually available for the taking from
nearby forests and thickets. Until the midtwentieth century, the chief
energy source for the country's limited industry was wood, supplemented
by rice husks and bagasse (the dry pulp remaining from sugarcane after
the juice is extracted). Even into the 1960s, wood was a major source of
fuel for the railroads. Electricity, which was used for power beginning
in 1887 with the establishment of the Siam Electric Company, was
generated as late as the early 1950s largely by steam produced through
burning rice husks. Other natural energy sources existed, although they
were underexploited, in the large hydroelectric potential of the Chao
Phraya and to a lesser extent of the Mae Klong and other smaller rivers.
There were also deposits of lignite, which was used to fuel a number of
power plants. Since 1950 small oil deposits have been found and
exploited in the North. Oil shales have also been discovered, but
exploitation remained economically unfeasible in 1980. The greatest
potential for domestic hydrocarbon production in the late 1980s
consisted of large natural gas deposits, which had been discovered in
the 1970s in the Gulf of Thailand.
Electric Power
As industry revived and began to expand after World War II, the need
for electricity grew. The supply was limited and unreliable, and some
industrial firms and businesses installed their own generators, mostly
fueled by imported oil. In 1958 the Metropolitan Electricity Authority
(MEA) was established to generate and supply power to Bangkok and
adjacent provinces. A year earlier the government had also set up the
Yanhee Electricity Authority (renamed in 1969 the Electricity Generating
Authority of Thailand--EGAT) to promote development of hydroelectric
power. The first hydroelectric generating facility was the Phumiphon
Dam. Completed in 1964 on the Mae Nam Ping, it had an installed capacity
of 420 megawatts in 1979 and a potential of 560 megawatts.
Escalating power demand led to construction of a major oil-fired
plant, the North Bangkok Power Station, which went into operation in
1961. Installed capacity from 1968 totaled 237 megawatts. The capital
area became adequately supplied with the construction of a new oil-fired
plant in Bangkok. The South Bangkok Thermal Power Plant started up in
late 1970 with a 200- megawatt capacity; by 1977 this was increased to
1,300 megawatts. The country's second major hydroelectric plant, at the
Sirikit Dam (potential generating capacity of 500 megawatts) on the Mae
Nam Nan, a major tributary of the Chao Phraya, started generation with
an installed capacity of 375 megawatts in 1974. A third large
hydroelectric facility, part of a multipurpose irrigation, flood
control, and power project at Ban Pho on the Mae Nam Mae Klong northwest
of Kanchanaburi, was completed in the 1980s with an initial capacity of
360 megawatts and an estimated potential of 720 megawatts.
Generating capacity to other parts of Thailand was on a much smaller
and regionally unequal scale. Increased oil prices in the 1970s
stimulated a new interest in lignite, and a lignite-fueled plant
installed at Mae Mo, the site of a major lignite deposit, was producing
825 megawatts by 1987. Lignite reserves were estimated to be 865 million
tons in 1985.
In the South a lignite-fired plant at Krabi with an installed
capacity of sixty megawatts commenced generation in 1964. A major
purpose of this plant was to furnish power for tin mines in the area and
the tin smelter on Phuket Island, in addition to meeting local needs. In
1968 additional generating capacity was installed on Phuket through a
ten- megawatt-capacity diesel plant, and between 1971 and 1977 three gas
turbine units totaling forty-five megawatts were installed on Hat Yai.
In the late 1970s, three additional gas turbine units having a combined
capacity of fortyfive megawatts were also located at Surat Thani.
Development of power facilities in the Northeast received little
attention until the mid-1960s, at which time the region had an estimated
generating capacity provided by small diesel units of perhaps one
megawatt. By the early 1970s, however, four hydroelectric plants had
been installed at dams in different parts of the region, with an
installed capacity of ninety-five megawatts. New gas turbines furnished
an additional thirty megawatts, and diesel units produced an additional
four megawatts.
In 1987 the power sector was composed of three governmentowned
enterprises: EGAT, under the Office of the Prime Minister, was the
national power production agency; MEA, under the Ministry of Interior
had responsibility for power distribution in Bangkok and the provinces
immediately around the city; and the Provincial Electricity Authority
(PEA), also under the Ministry of Interior, distributed power throughout
the rest of the country. There were also a number of privately held
distribution franchises that bought power from PEA or EGAT. Some
privately owned industries also generated their own power. Installed
generating capacity in 1986 was 7,570 megawatts, of which 70 percent was
thermal and 30 percent hydropower. In 1985 industry used nearly 50
percent of the 20 million megawatt-hours of energy consumed. Residential
consumption was 25 percent, commercial establishments used 25 percent,
and street lighting and miscellaneous uses accounted for less than 1
percent. By the end of 1986, nearly 43,000 villages of the more than
48,000 throughout the country had been supplied with power. It was
projected that 95 percent of all villages would have electricity by 1991
and essentially all villages by 1999.
Petroleum and Natural Gas
Oil was discovered near Fang in the far north of the country in the
early 1950s, but by the late 1970s the principal field was reported
close to depletion. Onshore deposits were believed to exist in other
parts of the country, and several foreign firms had exploration
concessions in the 1980s. Exploration in the 1970s in the Gulf of
Thailand uncovered oil in limited quantities. Oil shales were found at
Mae Sot in Tak Province in the North. Surveys in the mid-1970s indicated
a reserve of about 2.5 billion tons. A smaller deposit, estimated at
about 15 million tons, existed in Lamphun Province, also in the North.
Surveys in the Northeast from the mid-1970s showed the existence of
about 2.5 billion tons of oil shale in that region. Although 4 million
barrels of petroleum were produced in 1983, extensive commercial
exploitation still seemed remote because of comparatively high
production costs.
In the early 1980s, petroleum products provided about 68 percent of
the annual energy requirement. The country was highly dependent on
petroleum imports, and increasing world petroleum prices had a serious
impact on the country's balance of payments. In 1980 there were three
large, privately operated, oil refineries having a combined design
capacity of 165,000 barrels per day (bpd); government sources estimated
maximum capacity at 188,000 bpd. The Thailand Oil Refining Company
(TORC) started operations in the mid-1960s with a capacity of 42,000
bpd. This was expanded to 65,000 bpd in 1971 under an agreement whereby
the entire operation was to become the property of the Thai government
in 1981. A second fully integrated plant was government owned but was
leased for operation to the private Summit Industrial Corporation; the
lease was due to expire in 1990. This plant had a design capacity of
65,000 bpd. A third plant was owned and operated by Esso Standard of
Thailand and could handle 35,000 bpd. A very small 1,000 bpd plant was
operated in the far north by the Ministry of Defense to refine domestic
oil produced in the area.
Natural gas was found by international firms in offshore concessions
in the Gulf of Thailand in the mid-1970s, and subsequent explorations
determined that large quantities were recoverable, sufficient to alter
favorably Thailand's energy position. By 1979 two major gas fields had
been generally delineated, one located approximately 425 kilometers
south of a proposed pipeline terminal east of Sattahip at the upper end
of the gulf, the other 170 kilometers farther south. Proven recoverable
reserves in the first field were estimated at nearly 1.6 trillion cubic
feet and probable recoverable reserves at 220 billion cubic feet. In the
second field, proven recoverable reserves were 1.3 trillion cubic feet
and probable reserves 4.5 trillion cubic feet. Two smaller fields about
365 kilometers south of the terminal site were estimated to have about
500 billion cubic feet of recoverable reserves. The country's total
proven reserves of natural gas were estimated at 8.5 trillion cubic feet
in 1984. Thailand's production of natural gas in 1987 was 162.3 billion
cubic feet.
In late 1979, the World Bank approved a loan of US$107 million to the
Petroleum Authority of Thailand, a state enterprise, to assist in the
first-phase exploitation of the discoveries. A submarine pipeline was
built from the terminal near Mapthaphut to a production platform at the
major field 425 kilometers south in the gulf. When completed in the
early 1980s, it was the world's longest submarine pipeline. Additional
pipelines were built to transport the gas overland, initially to the
South Bangkok Thermal Power Plant and later to a new thermal power plant
at Bang Pakong southeast of Bangkok, built in the early 1980s under
EGAT's 1978-85 power generation development plan. Gas was also
distributed to industrial users along the pipeline route.
Thailand
Thailand - Government
Thailand
THE RELATIVE STABILITY of the Thai political system in the 1980s may
prove to be a political watershed in modern Thai history. This
stability, which resulted after several decades of spasmodic
experimentation with democracy, could be attributed to the growing
support of the monarchy and the traditionally dominant
military-bureaucratic elite for parliamentary democracy. Evidently an
increasing number of educated Thai had come to believe that a
"Thai-style democracy" headed by the king and a parliament
representing the people through political parties was preferable to
excessively authoritarian rule under military strongmen. The future of
parliamentary democracy was not a certainty, however, as many Thai
continued to believe that democratic rule was not the most effective
option in times of incompetent national leadership, prolonged civil and
political disorder, or external threat to independence.
Under the Constitution of 1978, Thailand has a British-style cabinet
form of government with King Bhumibol Adulyadej (Rama IX, 1946- )
reigning as constitutional monarch and Prime Minister Prem Tinsulanonda
heading the government. Unlike the British prime minister, however, Prem
was not a leader of or even a member of any political party in the
nation's parliament, the National Assembly, nor did he run for election
in the July 1986 election that led to the formation of his four-party
coalition government. This was his fifth cabinet and seventh year in
office--no mean accomplishment in a country that had witnessed numerous
coups, countercoups, and attempted coups during its sporadic experiments
with parliamentary government since 1932.
Unlike many of his predecessors, Prem became prime minister in March
1980 not by a coup, the traditional route to power, but by consensus
among key politicians. At that time he was the commander in chief of the
Royal Thai Army, a post that was long considered to be the most powerful
in the country. With little dissent from any quarter, he succeeded
Kriangsak Chomanand, who had resigned as prime minister amid mounting
economic and political tensions. A group of disgruntled officers,
popularly known as "the Young Turks," attempted coups against
Prem in 1981 and 1985. These attempts, however, had no disruptive effect
on political stability.
Despite these failed coups, in 1987 the military as a whole continued
to play a major role in Thai politics. Increasingly, this role was
tempered as so-called "enlightened" officers realized that a
coup was no longer acceptable to the public and that the military could
bring its influence to bear politically by working within the
constitutional system. The military continued to believe, nonetheless,
that politics and government were too important to be left entirely in
the hands of civilian politicians, whom they tended to disdain as
corrupt, divisive, and inefficient.
Barring early dissolution or resignation of his cabinet, Prem's
mandate was scheduled to lapse in July 1990. Who would succeed him and,
more important, how it would happen were the key questions because of
their far-reaching implications for parliamentary democracy in Thailand.
A related question concerned the future role of the monarchy and whether
or not it would continue to command the reverence and loyalty of all
segments of society and maintain its powerful symbolism as the sole
conferrer of political legitimacy.
In the 1980s, a growing number of Thai favored a constitutional
amendment requiring that only an elected member commanding a
parliamentary majority could become prime minister. Citing Prem as an
example, others argued that, even in the absence of a constitutional
amendment, orderly succession was possible if a nationally reputable
figure were acceptable to a majority of the country's political leaders.
In any case, many observers agreed that, rather than imitating a foreign
political model, Thailand should develop the political system best
suited to the kingdom's particular needs and circumstances. The quest
for a so-called "Thai-style democracy" was still under way in
1987, although the form and process of such a democracy remained largely
undefined.
During the 1980s, Thailand pursued three major foreign policy
objectives: safeguarding national security, diversifying and expanding
markets for Thai exports, and establishing cordial relations with all
nations. On the whole, Thailand conducted what it called
"omni-directional foreign policy," and it did so in a highly
pragmatic and flexible manner. Relations with such major powers as the
United States, China, and Japan were increasingly cordial, and relations
with the Soviet Union were correct. The Thai were suspicious of Soviet
intentions because Moscow was perceived to be aiding and abetting
Vietnam, Laos, and Cambodia. Beginning in the mid-1970s, Indochina had
come to be viewed as the major threat to Thailand's security. The
normalization of relations with these Indochinese neighbors remained the
principal unresolved issue for Bangkok, which continued to address the
problem directly as well as indirectly through a regional forum called
the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN).
<"76.htm">The Constitution
<"77.htm">
THE CENTRAL GOVERNMENT
<"78.htm">
LOCAL GOVERNMENT
<"79.htm">
CIVIL SERVICE
<"80.htm">
THE MEDIA
<"81.htm">
POLITICAL DEVELOPMENTS, 1980-87
<"82.htm">
POLITICAL PARTIES
<"83.htm">
FOREIGN AFFAIRS
Thailand
Thailand - The Constitution
Thailand
The Constitution, promulgated on December 22, 1978, is the country's
twelfth such document since 1932, when Thailand, then called Siam, first
became a constitutional monarchy. Thailand's numerous constitutions
resulted, in part, from various coup leaders revoking an old
constitution and announcing an interim one in order to legitimize their
takeover until a permanent constitution could be promulgated. Political
maneuvers aimed at amending constitutional provisions have often shed
light on the interplay of Thai political forces and the personalities
and issues involved.
The Constitution provides for a parliamentary form of government with
the king as titular head of state. In theory, the monarch exercises
popularly derived power through the National Assembly, the Council of
Ministers, and the courts. In reality, power is wielded by the prime
minister--the head of government-- who chairs the Council of Ministers,
or cabinet.
The Constitution includes a long chapter on the rights and liberties
of the people, in which are guaranteed due process of law; sanctity of
the family; rights of property and inheritance; freedom from forced
labor, except by law in times of national emergencies or armed
hostilities; and the inviolability of the person and private
communications. Censorship is banned except by law for the purpose of
"public order or good morals, public safety, or for maintaining the
security of the state." Also guaranteed are freedom of the press,
freedom of speech, freedom of religious worship, and the right of
peaceful assembly; freedom of residence and movement within the kingdom;
the right to organize voluntary associations; the right to establish a
political party and engage in political activities within a democratic
framework; and the right to petition against public institutions. These
rights and liberties, however, are not to be used against the interest
of "the Nation, religion, the King, and the Constitution."
Affairs of state must conform to a set of principles, which, among
other things, obligate the state to maintain the monarchy, provide
compulsory and free education, and promote public understanding of and
belief in a democratic form of government with the king as its head. The
state is also directed to ensure that the people enjoy the right of
self-government as prescribed by law. Other directive principles urge
the state to encourage private economic initiatives, raise the economic
and social status of the citizenry to the level of "comfortable
livelihood," and secure either landownership or land use rights for
all farmers by means of land reform or other appropriate measures. The
state is also called upon to promote culture, environmental protection,
planned parenthood, and public health.
The power of the state, exercised through a centralized form of
government, is divided into legislative, executive, and judicial
categories. The state revolves around the king, the bicameral
legislature, the cabinet, the judiciary, the local government, and the
Constitutional Tribunal.
The Constitution may be amended by motions introduced either by the
cabinet or by one-third of the members of the lower house of the
National Assembly; in the latter case, a motion must be in accordance
with a resolution adopted by the political party to which the proponents
of the amendment belong. This provision is designed to encourage
responsible party politics by prohibiting motions by members acting in
defiance of party discipline. An amendment bill is deliberated in three
readings and must be approved by more than one-half of the total members
of both houses.
The interpretation of the Constitution is under the jurisdiction of
both the National Assembly and the Constitutional Tribunal. Except for
matters reserved for the Constitutional Tribunal, questions relating to
the power and duty of the legislature are resolved by the assembly
sitting in joint session. The tribunal is responsible for deciding the
legality of a bill passed by the National Assembly. If at least
one-fifth of the National Assembly members object to a given bill before
it is given royal assent, they may request the president of either
chamber to refer the disputed bill to the tribunal for adjudication. The
prime minister also may raise an objection to the tribunal directly.
Decisions by the Constitutional Tribunal are final and cannot be
appealed.
Thailand
Thailand - THE CENTRAL GOVERNMENT
Thailand
In the 1980s, the governmental system remained unitary, with all
important decisions emanating from the traditionally powerful
bureaucratic elite in Bangkok. Composed of senior members of the civil
and military wings of the bureaucracy, this elite dominated the
governmental process from the national level down to the district level.
In this process, the Ministry of Interior continued to play a key role
as the administrative framework of the state, resisting reforms and
changes.
The King
The Constitution stipulates that the king is "enthroned in a
position of revered worship" and is not to be exposed "to any
sort of accusation or action." As ceremonial head of state, the
monarch is endowed with a formal power of assent and appointment, is
above partisan affairs, and does not involve himself in the
decision-making process of the government. In the 1980s, King Bhumibol
Adulyadej remained the nation's most respected figure because he was
popularly perceived to be the embodiment of religion, culture, and
history. He ensured political stability and unity by lending legitimacy
to important government actions and, in potentially destabilizing
situations, as during the abortive coups in 1981 and 1985, by discreetly
signaling his support of the incumbent government.
In discharging his formal duties, the king was assisted by the Privy
Council, whose president and not more than fourteen members were royal
appointees. These members could not hold other public offices, belong to
political parties, or show loyalty to any partisan organization. Also
assisting the king were the Office of His Majesty's Principal Private
Secretary and the Bureau of the Royal Household, agencies responsible
for organizing ceremonial functions and administering the finances and
logistics of the royal palace.
The mode of succession was set forth in the Palace Law on Succession.
In the absence of a crown prince, or if the crown prince declined
succession, a princess could succeed, subject to parliamentary approval.
When the throne became vacant, an heir was to be appointed by the Privy
Council. Until the heir formally ascended the throne, the president of
the Privy Council would act as regent. Prince Vajiralongkorn, the only
son of King Bhumibol and Queen Sirikit, was designated as heir on
December 28, 1972, at the age of twenty.
National Assembly
In the 1980s, the bicameral parliament, unable to successfully
challenge the tradition of bureaucratic dominance over state affairs,
was overshadowed by the executive branch. The National Assembly
continued to be an instrument of cabinet rule, with its legislative
agenda issuing for the most part from the executive branch.
Under the Constitution, the National Assembly was structured to
accommodate both the military and civilian bureaucratic elite and the
electorate. The influence of the traditionally powerful bureaucracy was
channeled through the Senate, whose members were nominated by the prime
minister for pro forma appointment by the king. Up to 85 percent of the
Senate membership in the late 1980s was drawn from the armed forces and
the police. The intent of this arrangement was to encourage the military
to play its traditional political role through the upper house rather
than through a coup or countercoup.
Senators served a term of six years, and one-third of them were
retired every two years. Retirees could be reappointed for an unlimited
number of terms. A senator was required to be at least thirty-five years
of age, a Thai citizen by birth, and not a member of any political
party. Other membership qualifications were broadly phrased, including
the requirement that appointees have "knowledge and experience in
various branches of learning or affairs which will be useful to the
administration of the state."
House of Representatives members represented the populace. They were
elected for a four-year term by direct suffrage and secret ballot at the
ratio of a member to each 150,000 inhabitants. Each province (changwat),
regardless of population, was entitled to at least one seat. A
constituency with a population in excess of 75,000 also qualified for a
seat. A candidate had to be at least twenty-five years of age, a Thai
citizen by birth, and a member of a political party. As a rule, an
election had to be held within sixty days from the expiration of the
four-year term of the lower house. When the House was dissolved by royal
decree (on the recommendation of the prime minister), a new election was
required within ninety days.
The two chambers conducted their business separately under their
respective presidents (speakers) and vice presidents, who were chosen
from among the membership. Under the Constitution, the president of the
Senate was automatically the speaker of the National Assembly and in
that capacity was empowered to play a strategic role in the selection of
the prime minister.
In the 1980s, lower house members demanded that their president,
rather than the president of the upper house, have a decisive role in
the process of selecting the prime minister. This policy was necessary,
they said, because the House of Representatives, not the
military-dominated Senate, collectively represented the will of the
electorate. A bill to amend the Constitution to make the lower house
speaker the president of the National Assembly was introduced in 1986
but failed to pass.
In 1987 the customary role of the Senate as a major vehicle for the
power of the bureaucracy and a counterweight to the elective lower house
remained little changed, even though its stature seemed to have
diminished somewhat after April 1983. At that time, certain senatorial
powers granted under temporary clauses of the Constitution expired
despite the army's efforts to have these clauses extended. Under these
clauses, the Senate had had the power to deliberate jointly with the
lower chamber on annual appropriation bills, on "an important bill
relating to the security of the Kingdom, the Throne, or the national
economy," and the power to vote on no-confidence motions. The army
and its political allies in parliament failed to have the clauses
extended because of factious squabbles. If they had succeeded, the
military's political power would have been enhanced greatly.
The lapse of the transitory provisions, however, did not affect the
Senate's power to address such matters as the appointment of a regent,
the royal succession, reconsideration of a bill vetoed by the prime
minister, constitutional interpretation, a declaration of war, the
ratification of treaties, the appointment of members of the
Constitutional Tribunal, and constitutional amendments. In joint
sessions senators also could render their opinion on any aspect of
affairs of state to the prime minister when requested to do so by the
latter. Such opinion was advisory and nonbinding.
Bills could be introduced only by the Council of Ministers or the
members of the House of Representatives. Major legislation originated
mostly in the cabinet, but only the lower house, with the prior
endorsement of the prime minister, could initiate an appropriations
bill. An ordinary bill had to be sponsored by a political party and
endorsed by at least twenty party members. Bills were passed by a
majority, the quorum being not less than one-half of the total members
of either house in which the bills originated.
A bill passed by the House was sent to the Senate. The Senate was
required to act on an ordinary bill within ninety days and on an
appropriations bill within sixty days. If the Senate failed to act in
either case, the bill was considered to have been consented to by the
Senate, unless the lower chamber had extended the time. Disagreements
between the two houses were resolved by a joint committee. When the
dispute pertained to an appropriations bill and the lower house voted to
reaffirm the bill it had originally passed, the prime minister was
required to present the bill to the king for his assent and
promulgation. At that point, the prime minister could exercise his
important legislative role. He might advise the king to approve or veto
the bill; in the latter event, the National Assembly needed two-thirds
of its total membership to override the royal objections (actually the
prime minister's objections).
Members of the assembly, who had parliamentary immunity, could
question formally a cabinet minister or the prime minister on any
appropriate issue except one in which executive privilege was involved.
A motion of no-confidence against either an individual minister or the
cabinet en masse could be initiated only by members of the lower house.
Such a motion required an affirmative vote of at least one-half of the
lower house membership. Senators could not take part in no-confidence
debates.
Council of Ministers
The cabinet, the center of Thai political power, consisted of
forty-four members, including the prime minister, deputy prime
ministers, ministers, and deputy ministers. Individually and
collectively the members were accountable to the House of
Representatives and had to retain its confidence. The cabinet was
required to resign en masse if a no-confidence motion against it was
passed by the House. The four-party coalition cabinet formed in August
1986 had no civil servants or active-duty military officers. Under the
Constitution, cabinet members were not allowed to hold political posts
as part of an effort to strengthen the political party system.
Under the customary rules of parliamentary government, Thailand could
have a prime minister whose party or electoral alliance had earned the
mandate of this office outright by winning a majority of seats in the
House of Representatives. Whether or not anyone would command a majority
in the next election was uncertain, given the highly fragmented
political party system. In any case, a public opinion survey conducted
in March 1987 by the Social Research Institute of Chulalongkorn
University showed that 91 percent of those interviewed in Bangkok
favored an elected prime minister. For a requirement that the prime
minister be elected, however, the Constitution would have to be amended.
In 1987 the Royal Command appointing the prime minister had to be
countersigned by the president of the National Assembly, the leader of
the military-dominated Senate, who had the power to block the
installation of anyone unacceptable to the military establishment. Until
the basic law is revised, the selection of the prime minister will
continue to be determined by behind-the-scenes power brokers, including
the military (especially the army), the monarchy, and leaders of various
political parties representing business groups.
The prime minister held the real powers of appointment and removal,
which he exercised in the name of the king. He countersigned royal
decrees and wielded a wide range of executive powers, including the
power to declare a national emergency to ensure "national or public
safety or national economic security or to avert public calamity."
The legality of an emergency decree had to be validated by the next
session of the National Assembly. The prime minister could also proclaim
or lift martial law, declare war with the advice and consent of
parliament, and conclude peace treaties, armistices, and other
treaties--all in the king's name.
As of mid-1987, the executive branch had thirteen ministerial
portfolios: agriculture and cooperatives; commerce; communications;
defense; education; finance; foreign affairs; industry; interior;
justice; public health; science, technology, and energy; and university
affairs. The heads of these ministries (except for justice; science,
technology, and energy; and university affairs) were aided by one or
more cabinet-rank deputy ministers. Each ministry was divided into
departments, divisions, and sections. Traditionally, the ministries of
defense, interior, and finance were regarded as the most desirable by
aspiring politicians and generals. In the 1980s, the ministries of
agriculture and cooperatives, industry, and communications grew in
stature as the economic value of resources steadily increased.
In 1987 the Office of the Prime Minister continued to be the nerve
center of the government. With the assistance of several cabinet-rank
ministers attached to the office and of the Secretariat of the Prime
Minister, this office monitored, coordinated, and supervised the
activities of all government agencies and state enterprises. The
secretariat was headed by a cabinet-rank secretary general, who
supervised the work of sixteen agencies attached to the prime minister's
office. Among these agencies were the Bureau of the Budget, the National
Security Council, the Department of Central Intelligence, the Civil
Service Commission, and the National Economic and Social Development
Board. In August 1986, the secretary general was also placed in charge
of a new unit called the National Operations Center established in the
Office of the Prime Minister to provide essential data for efficient
decision making. Specifically, the task of the National Operations
Center was to handle crisis management, cope with threats to internal
and external security, and keep the prime minister informed of public
sentiment throughout the country.
Outside the regular administrative structure, but subject to its
control and supervision, approximately sixty-eight state enterprises
were engaged as of 1987 in commercial and economic activities of major
importance. In these enterprises, the government was either the sole
owner or the dominant partner. Managed by senior civil servants, retired
military officers, or politicians, the state enterprises permitted a
major government role in virtually every facet of the economic life of
the country. In fiscal year ( FY) 1986, their total budget was 9 percent
more than the total budget of the government and accounted for 65
percent of external public debt. The inefficiency of these enterprises
continued to affect the government's fiscal stability. Privatization of
the enterprises was listed as one of the ten major programs of the
country's Sixth Economic Development Plan, for 1987-91.
Judiciary
The legal system remained an amalgam of the traditional and the
modern. In several southern provinces, for example, Islamic law and
custom were applicable to matrimonial and inheritance matters among the
Muslims. A large part of the modern legal system was made up of
criminal, civil, and commercial codes adopted from the British and other
European legal systems with some modifications borrowed from India,
Japan, China, and the United States. Also, an extensive body of
administrative law consisted of royal decrees, executive orders, and
ministerial regulations.
The judiciary provided for three levels of courts: the courts of
first instance, the Court of Appeal, and the Supreme Court. The courts
came under two separate jurisdictions. The Ministry of Justice appointed
and supervised the administrative personnel of the courts and instituted
reform in judicial procedures; the Judicial Service Commission, which
was responsible for the independence of the courts, appointed, promoted,
and removed judges. As a rule, judges retired at age sixty, but their
service could be extended to age sixty-five.
The country was divided into nine judicial regions, which were
coextensive with the nine administrative regions (phag), in
contrast to the four geographic regions (North, Northeast, Center, and
South). At the base of the judiciary system were the courts of first
instance, most of which were formally known as provincial courts with
unlimited civil and criminal jurisdiction. Petty civil and criminal
offenses were handled by magistrates' courts, which were designed to
relieve the increasing burden on provincial courts. Offenses committed
by Thai citizens on the high seas and outside the country were tried
before the Criminal Court in Bangkok. Labor disputes were adjudicated by
the Central Labor Court established in Bangkok in 1980. Offenses by
persons under eighteen years of age were referred to the Central
Juvenile Court and its counterparts in several regional centers.
The Court of Appeal in Bangkok heard cases from all lower courts
(except the Central Labor Court) relating to civil, juvenile, criminal,
and bankruptcy matters. At least two judges were required to sit at each
hearing. Cases of exceptional importance had to be heard by plenary
sessions of the court. The appellate court could reverse, revise, or
remand lower court decisions on questions of both law and fact.
The Supreme Court, which was the highest court of appeal, also had
original jurisdiction over election disputes. Although decisions of the
court were final, in criminal cases the king could grant clemency. A
dispute over court jurisdiction was settled by the Constitutional
Tribunal.
Thailand
Thailand - LOCAL GOVERNMENT
Thailand
Local government comprised both regular territorial administrative
units and self-governing bodies. Local autonomy was limited, however, by
the high degree of centralization of power. The Ministry of Interior
controlled the policy, personnel, and finances of the local units at the
provincial and district levels. Field officials from the ministry as
well as other central ministries constituted the majority of
administrators at local levels.
In 1987 there were seventy-three provinces (changwat),
including the metropolitan area of Bangkok, which had provincial status.
The provinces were grouped into nine regions for administrative
purposes. As of 1984 (the latest year for which information was
available in 1987), the provinces were divided into 642 districts (amphoe),
78 subdistricts (king amphoe), 7,236 communes (tambon),
55,746 villages (muban), 123 municipalities (tesaban),
and 729 sanitation districts (sukhaphiban).
The province was under a governor (phuwarachakan), who was
assisted by one or more deputy governors, an assistant governor, and
officials from various central ministries, which, except for the
Ministry of Foreign Affairs, maintained field staffs in the provinces
and districts. The governor supervised the overall administration of the
province, maintained law and order, and coordinated the work of
ministerial field staffs. These field officials carried out the policies
and programs of their respective ministries as line administrators and
also served as technical advisers to the governor. Although these
officials were responsible to the governor in theory, in practice they
reported to their own ministries in Bangkok and maintained communication
with other province-level and district-level field staffs.
The governor also was responsible for district and municipal
administration, presiding over a provincial council composed of senior
officials from the central ministries. The council, which served in an
advisory capacity, met once a month to transmit central government
directives to the district administrators. Apart from the council, an
elected provincial assembly exercised limited legislative oversight over
provincial affairs.
District administration was under the charge of a district officer (nai
amphor), who was appointed by the minister of interior and reported
to the provincial governor. Larger districts could be divided into two
or more subdistricts, each under an assistant district officer. The
district or the subdistrict was usually the only point of contact
between the central authority and the populace; the central government
had no appointed civil service officials below this level.
The district officer's duties as overseer of the laws and policies of
the central government were extensive. He supervised the collection of
taxes, kept basic registers and vital statistics, registered
schoolchildren and aliens, administered local elections at the commune
and village levels, and coordinated the activities of field officials
from Bangkok. Additionally, the district officer convened monthly
meetings of the headmen of the communes and villages to inform them of
government policies and instruct them on the implementation of these
policies. As the chief magistrate of the district, he also was
responsible for arbitration in land disputes; many villagers referred
these disputes to the district officer rather than to a regular court.
The commune was the next level below the district. An average of nine
contiguous, natural villages were grouped into one commune, whose
residents elected a headman (kamnan) from among the village
headmen (phuyaibun) within the commune. The commune chief was
not a regular government official, but because of his semiofficial
status, he was confirmed in office by the provincial governor. He also
was entitled to wear an official uniform and receive a monthly stipend.
Assisted by a small locally recruited staff, the kamnan
recorded vital statistics, helped the district officer collect taxes,
supervised the work of village headmen, and submitted periodic reports
to the district officer.
Below the commune level was the village government. Each village
elected a headman, who generally served as the middleman between
villagers and the district administration. The headman's other duties
included attending meetings at the district headquarters, keeping
village records, arbitrating minor civil disputes, and serving as
village peace officer. Generally the headman served five years or longer
and received a monthly stipend. In the 1980s, the importance of a
village headman seemed to be declining as the authority of the central
government expanded steadily through the provincial and local
administrations.
Municipalities in Thailand included Bangkok, seventy-two cities
serving as provincial capitals, and some large district towns. According
to the 1980 census, municipalities had a combined population of 7.6
million, or about 17 percent of the national total. The municipalities
consisted of communes, towns, and cities, depending on population.
Municipal residents elected mayors and twelve to twenty-four municipal
assemblymen; the assemblymen chose two to four councillors from among
their number, who together with the mayors made up executive councils.
In theory, the municipal authorities were self-governing, but in
practice municipal government was an administrative arm of the central
and provincial authorities. The Ministry of Interior had effective
control over municipal affairs through the provincial administration,
which had the authority to dissolve municipal assemblies and executive
councils. Moreover, such key officials as the municipal clerk and
section chiefs were recruited, assigned, and retired by the ministry,
which also had the power to control and supervise the fiscal affairs of
the perennially deficit-ridden municipalities.
Until 1985 Bangkok's governor and assemblymen were appointed by the
central government. In November of that year, however, for the first
time an election was held as part of the constitutionally mandated
effort to nurture local selfgovernment . Chamlong Srimuang, a former
major general running as an independent, won the governorship by a
landslide.
At the next lower level of local government, every district had at
least one sanitation district committee, usually in the district
capital. This committee's purpose was to provide services such as refuse
collection, water and sewage facilities, recreation, and road
maintenance. The committee was run by exofficio members headed by the
district officer. Like municipalities, the sanitation districts were
financially and administratively dependent on the government, notably
the district administration.
Thailand
Thailand - CIVIL SERVICE
Thailand
A civil service career continued in 1987 to be widely regarded as a
desirable route to financial security, social status, and power. As a
result, despite the universal complaint about the inadequacy of
government salaries, and despite many well-paid jobs becoming available
in the commercial and industrial sectors, the civil service continued to
attract many of the most promising young men and women.
Personnel administration was in theory centralized under the Civil
Service Commission, which reported to the prime minister. In actuality
the commission's functions were limited to standardization, general
guidance, coordination, and record keeping. Recruitment, assignment,
promotion, and discipline were handled by each ministry and other public
entities. After 1975 government service was divided into eleven position
classifications. The top five grades (seven through eleven) were
"special grade officers"--the elite of the civilian wing of
the bureaucracy. Entry level for college graduates was grade two, and,
for those with master's degrees, grade three. Ordinarily, the district
officer was either grade five or six, and the district section head was
grade three. The provincial governor, deputy governors, and assistant
governors were special grade officials, as were mid- to top-level
managerial officers of the central ministries. Provincial section chiefs
were grade four.
An informative study by Thai political scientist Likhit Dhiravegin
revealed that as of 1977 the Ministry of Interior had the largest bloc
of special and first grade officials (29 percent and 26 percent,
respectively) because of its role as the backbone of the country's
far-flung administrative system. This study indicated that the
administrative service continued to be elitist, dominated by families of
government officials and businessmen. In 1977, although these families
accounted for only 10 percent (1 percent and 9 percent, respectively) of
the national population, they claimed 41 percent and 33 percent,
respectively, of the special grade category and 31 percent and 27
percent, respectively, of the first grade category. This meant that
these families produced a combined total of 74 percent of the special
grade officers and 58 percent of the first grade functionaries.
Geographically, a strong bias favored the Center (including Bangkok),
which had 32 percent of the total population but had 68 percent and 63
percent, respectively, of the special and first grade officers assigned
there; Bangkok alone had 39 percent and 33 percent of these two
categories. In terms of male-female ratio, of the special grade and
first grade officers, only 11 percent and 23 percent, respectively, were
women. Many of the female officers were in the ministries of university
affairs, education, and public health. Likhit pointed out that,
insignificant as it might seem, the number of women in managerial
positions was impressively high when compared with other Asian
countries.
In terms of education, about 93 percent and 77 percent of the civil
servants in the special and first grade categories, respectively, had
college educations, which compared favorably with other Asian countries
such as Japan, the Republic of Korea (South Korea), Singapore, and
Burma. The Likhit study also showed that 33 percent and 20 percent of
the elite categories had foreign training, the United States accounting
for 71 percent and 78 percent and Britain for 11 percent and 9 percent.
The BritishUnited States connection was attributable to Thailand's close
relationship with Britain before World War II and with the United States
since that time.
According to the Likhit study, foreign influence was least evident in
the ministries of interior, justice, and public health--ministries that
had the largest number of locally trained civil service officials at the
elite level. Most of the locally trained senior judges, public
prosecutors, lawyers, district officers, and provincial governors were
graduates of Thammasat University. In the 1980s, several other Thai
universities were expected to have an increased share of graduates
applying for government service.
Civil service promotion was based on merit, but many observers
believed that favoritism was an important factor in career advancement.
A civil servant normally retired at age sixty. In 1980, however, the law
was changed to permit extension of tenure up to age sixty-five in cases
of extreme necessity for the benefit of the country.
Thailand
Thailand - THE MEDIA
Thailand
In the mid-1980s, the media played an important role as the principal
source of domestic and foreign news and, to a lesser degree, as a source
of public entertainment. All major daily newspapers were privately
owned, but radio and television stations were controlled by the
government and operated as commercial enterprises. Newspapers were
generally regarded as more credible than the government-controlled
broadcast media.
Mass media were under the broad supervision of the Public Relations
Department in the Office of the Prime Minister. This department served
as the principal source of news and information about the government and
its policies. It issued daily news bulletins on domestic and foreign
affairs for use by the print and electronic media. News bulletins were
also issued by other government agencies, including the Thai News
Agency, established in 1976 under the Mass Communications Organization
of Thailand, a state enterprise under the Office of the Prime Minister.
The Thai News Agency concentrated mostly on domestic affairs; foreign
news was gathered from international wire services, which maintained
offices or representatives in Bangkok.
The Constitution guarantees freedom of the press, which may not be
curbed except by law "for the purpose of maintaining the security
of state or safeguarding the liberties, dignity or reputation of other
persons or maintaining public order or good morals or preventing
deterioration of the mind or health of the public." Most observers
agreed that the Thai press enjoyed considerable freedom. Nevertheless,
in the 1980s editorial writers and reporters continued to exercise
self-censorship, mindful that there were unwritten but real government
constraints, especially on coverage relating to the monarchy, government
affairs, internal security matters, and Thailand's international image.
The existing statutes gave broad powers to the director general of the
Thailand National Police Department, including the authority to revoke
or suspend the license of an offending publication. The severity of
penalties varied, depending on the political climate and the sensitivity
of an issue. In 1987 a new press bill was pending before the National
Assembly, the intent of which was to give the press as much autonomy as
possible except in time of war or in a state of emergency, in which case
the press officer would be allowed to exercise censorship.
Daily newspapers were concentrated heavily in Bangkok, where at least
65 percent of the adults read a daily paper, compared with about 10
percent in rural areas. Newspapers were generally independent, and many
were financially solvent, deriving their income from sales and
advertising. The government was forbidden by law to subsidize private
newspapers. Foreign ownership of newspapers was also banned as a
safeguard against undue foreign or subversive influence.
In the 1980s, Thai journalistic standards improved steadily, as
reflected in the print media's growing emphasis on political and
economic issues, as well as on major foreign news events. This could be
attributed to the emergence of a more discriminating readership. On the
negative side, sensationalist coverage and insufficient professional
training continued to mar the reputation of the Thai press.
There were about 150 newspapers, including 30 dailies in Bangkok and
120 provincial papers in 1985. Some Bangkok dailies were considered to
be national newspapers because of their countrywide distribution. Most
provincial papers appeared every two, five, seven, or ten days. In
Bangkok twenty-one dailies appeared in Thai, six in Chinese, and three
in English. Of an estimated daily circulation of 1.6 million for all
Bangkok dailies in 1985, Thai Rath (800,000 circulation) and
the Daily News (400,000 circulation) together claimed about 75
percent of the total circulation. These two newspapers reportedly were
popular among white-collar groups. The most successful among the
remaining newspapers were Ban Muang, Matichon, Siam
Rath, and Naew Na. The English-language dailies were the Bangkok
Post, The Nation, and the Bangkok World, which
were popular among the well-educated and influential members of Thai
society and were regarded by many as more reliable than the Thai
dailies. Some of the editorial positions on the Bangkok Post
and the Bangkok World were held by foreigners, mostly British; The
Nation, on the other hand, was almost entirely staffed by Thai and
tended to view the world from a Thai perspective.
Unlike the English-language dailies, whose circulation was increasing
in the early 1980s, Chinese-language dailies were declining in
readership. Their total circulation was probably around 70,000. Two
leading Chinese-language dailies were Sing Sian Yit Pao and Tong
Hua Yit Pao. These dailies were noted for responsible coverage of
domestic and international affairs, but they refrained from taking
strong stands on local political questions.
All aspects of radio and television broadcasting, such as operating
hours, content, programs, advertising, and technical requirements, were
set by the Broadcasting Directing Board, which was under the Office of
the Prime Minister and headed by a deputy prime minister. In 1987 the
country had 275 national and local radio stations. The Public Relations
Department, under the Office of the Prime Minister, was responsible for
Radio Thailand and the National Broadcasting Services of Thailand (NBT).
NBT was the official government broadcasting station, which transmitted
local and international news mandatorily broadcast on all stations. News
was also broadcast daily in nine foreign languages over Radio Thailand's
World Service. Radio stations were run also as commercial enterprises by
such government agencies as the Mass Communications Organization of
Thailand; units of the army, the navy, and the air force; the police;
the ministries of communications and education; and several state
universities. In 1985 there were 7.7 million radio sets in use.
As a major official channel of communication, all television stations
avoided controversial viewpoints and independent political comment in
their programming. The Army Signal Corps and the Mass Communications
Organization of Thailand directly operated television channels 5 and 9.
Two other channels were operated under license by private groups, the
Bangkok Entertainment Company, which ran Channel 3, and the Bangkok
Television Company, in charge of Channel 7. Channel 11 was operated by
the government primarily as an educational station.
By 1980 television had become the dominant news medium among urban
Thai. Household television set ownership (about 3.3 million sets in
1984) was as widespread as radio in all urban areas of the country. As
of 1984, television exceeded radio ownership in the Center and South and
was about even with radio ownership in the North and the Northeast. Nine
out of ten Bangkok households had at least one television set. Ownership
of color television was also widespread among urban Thai in the South
(58 percent), Bangkok (54 percent), the Northeast (49 percent), the
central plain (47 percent), and the North (43 percent).
Thailand
Thailand - POLITICAL DEVELOPMENTS, 1980-87
Thailand
In 1987 Thailand was stable under Prime Minister Prem's eighth
consecutive year of administration, even though his leadership was
criticized for alleged indecisiveness and weakness. The country had not
experienced a successful military coup since October 1977, and in 1987
few politically or economically destabilizing issues existed. As in past
decades, the military continued to be influential in the political
process. Significantly, however, "one of the most surprising
aspects of recent Thai politics," as American political scientist
Ansil Ramsay noted, "is that political change has occurred within a
parliamentary framework instead of through military coups."
In January 1980, while dismissing as obsolete the flurry of seasonal
rumors of an imminent coup, then-Prime Minister Kriangsak declared that
"our military officers who are pursuing a democratic course"
would never allow it to happen. He did not, however, rule out a coup if
there were good reason, but only as a last resort. He also made the
point that he would step down if there was a majority political party
run by trustworthy and efficient political party executives.
At the end of February, Kriangsak stepped down, not, however, because
there was a party he could trust. Rather, the factious military was
unable to give the former army commander in chief the unified support he
needed at the time to weather a political storm brought on by economic
troubles. Predictably, he was succeeded by Prem, the army commander in
chief at the time, making Kriangsak the first ex-military prime minister
ever to give up power voluntarily. Prem survived two attempted coups and provided years
of stability, which the country needed for the institutionalization of a
political process based on the party system. The development of party
politics was still under way in 1987, albeit with occasional setbacks.
Although Prem initially ruled through a coalition cabinet of three
parties--the Democrat (Prachathipat) Party, the Social Action (Kit
Sangkhom) Party, and the Chart Thai (Thai Nation) Party--his real
political base was the armed forces, the traditional source and
guarantor of political power. In 1980, as from the early 1970s, the military
was divided into several cliques. One of the more influential cliques
called itself "the Young Military Officers Group," popularly
nicknamed "the Young Turks." The influential members of this
group belonged to Class Seven (1960 graduates) of the elite
Chulachomkhlao Royal Military Academy. Their aim was to enhance military
professionalism as well as to ensure a decisive role for the military in
the Thai political process. In 1980 their support was key to Prem's
ascension to the prime ministership. In April 1981, however, they turned
against Prem, who at that time was still army commander in chief.
Apparently the Young Turks believed that Prem had betrayed their trust
by consorting with political opportunists and party politicians in his
coalition government and, worse yet, by taking sides with rival military
cliques opposed to the Young Turks. For two days, the Young Turks
controlled the capital city, but they failed to win the monarch's tacit
consent, which had been crucial to the traditional legitimization of a
coup. Thirty-eight coup plotters- -including their leaders, Colonel
Manoon Rupekahorn and Colonel Prachak Sawangchit--were dismissed from
the army. After the abortive coup, General Arthit Kamlangek, who was
credited with a key role in thwarting the attempt, was promoted to
commander of the First Army Region; traditionally, this post was
regarded as the most strategic one in the making of coups and
countercoups. It was also noticeable that Class Five (1958
graduates) of the military academy, the Young Turks' chief rival
faction, were promoted to some key army posts.
In August 1981, Prem relinquished his post as army commander in chief
but continued to head his second coalition cabinet. This coalition was
formed in March 1981, after a cabinet crisis brought on by the
withdrawal of the Social Action Party from the ruling coalition. The
second coalition comprised the Chart Thai Party, the Democrat Party, and
the United Democracy (Saha Prachathipatai) Party, the latter a loose
alliance of minor parties. In December 1981, this cabinet was
reorganized to make room for the Social Action Party, which decided to
return to Prem's third cabinet.
Another notable development of the year was Kriangsak's entry into
partisan politics when he won a parliamentary by-election in August. For
this purpose, he founded the National Democracy (Chart Prachathipatai)
Party in June. Thus, he became the first former army commander in chief
and prime minister to enter party politics through the so-called front
door--the parliamentary route. Because of his background and experience,
Kriangsak was often mentioned as an alternative to Prem.
Another frequently mentioned alternative was General Arthit, a palace
favorite, whose rapid rise to the post of commander in chief of the army
in October 1982 was unprecedented. To some Thai observers, outspoken
Arthit was "the strongman of the future," destined to become
the next prime minister.
It was not unusual for a Thai general to air his views publicly on
socioeconomic or political issues, and such utterances were often
considered important. As political scientist John L.S. Girling noted,
"The power and authority of the military-bureaucratic regime, which
had been so long in existence, depended not so much on the physical
means of coercion that it possessed . . . as in the acceptance
by extrabureaucratic elements of the inevitability of that power and
their inability to challenge it."
In the 1980s, the military dominance in politics, however, seemed to
be undergoing some change, partly because the officer corps was not as
cohesive as it had been previously and hence was less able to impose its
will. For example, the lack of unity among the officers and their allies
in the Senate and the political parties was largely to blame for the
failure to amend the Constitution in 1983. Factionalism continued unabated, particularly
between members of Class Seven and of Class Five of the Chulachomkhlao
Royal Military Academy. The relative influence of these factions was
reflected in the annual reshuffle of the military high command-- the
traditional barometer of real political power--announced each year in
September. By 1983 the Class Five faction, sometimes known as the
"democratic soldiers" group, seemed to be particularly
influential.
Another factor bearing on the military's changing political role was
the generals' own growing perception that a coup was undemocratic, if
not uncivilized. As a result, an increasing number of generals and
colonels in retirement chose to involve themselves in party politics. In
the election held on April 18, 1983, for example, the Chart Thai Party
captured 73 of 324 seats in the House of Representatives--nearly twice
its 1979 total. Led by Major General (retired) Pramarn Adireksan,
this party had a large number of retired military officers. After the
election, the Chart Thai Party emerged as the top party in parliament
with 108 seats by absorbing independents and other minor party members.
Nonetheless, it was not included in Prem's fourth coalition cabinet.
This exclusion reportedly was because of the party's aggressive
postelection maneuvers for what it claimed as the moral right to form a
new government. Such aggressiveness antagonized other parties, which
wanted Prem for another term as their consensus prime minister. Prem's
fourth coalition consisted of four parties: Social Action Party,
Democrat Party, Prachakorn Thai (Thai People) Party, and National
Democracy Party.
The political situation was volatile during 1984, with rumors of a
coup, a cabinet reorganization, and a rift between Prem and Arthit--two
of the most frequently mentioned political actors. Arthit continued to
project a forceful image with his confrontational approach, a sharp
contrast to Prem's low-keyed, conciliatory approach. Also serving as the
supreme commander of the armed forces beginning in September 1983,
Arthit at times challenged the propriety of important government
policies. In November, for example, he made a televised condemnation of
the government's policy of devaluation. Also in 1984, apparently with
Arthit's blessing, some active-duty and retired army officers pressed
for constitutional amendments aimed at enhancing their political
influence through the Senate and the cabinet. A showdown between
Arthit's camp and Prem's ruling coalition seemed imminent. Arthit backed
off, however, urging the army officers to abandon, at least for the
time, the drive for amendments. It appeared that the monarchy played a
key role in defusing the tension. In this context, Thai political
scientist Juree Vichit- Vadakan commented that the monarchy was
"likely to be the single most important force capable of holding
the country together during times of chaos and crisis and of assuring
the viability of a democratic process in Thailand. With a clear
commitment of the monarchy to a constitutional government, democracy
Thai style ultimately may have a chance to take root."
In 1985 Thailand survived another military challenge to its
constitutional government in the form of an abortive coup, again led by
Manoon, the Young Turks colonel who had engineered the unsuccessful coup
in 1981. On September 9, a small band of army and air force officers
with several hundred men and twenty-two tanks made a vain predawn bid
for power. The coup collapsed after ten hours, but not before seven
persons were killed and scores wounded. Manoon was allowed to go into
exile as part of a deal to avert further bloodshed. Among those detained
for complicity were Kriangsak, Prem's predecessor and leader of the
National Democracy Party; the former army commander in chief and supreme
commander of the armed forces, General Sern Na Nakorn; the former deputy
army commander in chief, General Yos Thephasdin na Ayutthaya; the former
deputy supreme commander of the armed forces, Air Chief Marshal Krasae
Intharathat; and the still- serving deputy supreme commander of the
armed forces Air Chief Marshal Arun Prompthep.
The facts surrounding the affair were still unclear as of mid-1987,
but observers generally suggested two reasons for the failure of the
coup. One was factiousness in the military. The other was the perceived
obsolescence of a coup, a view shared by a widening circle of military
officers, senior civil servants, businessmen, financiers,
industrialists, white-collar executives, intellectuals, and,
significantly, by the king as well. According to this perception,
popular demand for participation and representation, whetted by the
advent of industrialization in Thailand, could be better accommodated by
a parliamentary government than by an authoritarian and narrowly based
military regime. Despite the absence of a successful coup since 1977,
however, few informed Thai seemed to believe that the country was on a
steady course toward fuller democratic rule. Thai political scientist
Likhit Dhiravegin observed in December 1986, "[If] one probes
deeper, one would get a feeling that despite the existence of the
elected assembly and a Cabinet consisting of civilians, the final say on
who should be the prime minister still rests mainly with the
military."
In partisan politics, the Democrat Party, the oldest and the best
organized party, fared well. Of the seven seats at stake in five
by-elections held in 1985, the Democrats won five, four of them in
Bangkok, where they also captured thirty-eight seats in the election for
the fifty-four-member city council. One of the winning Democrats was
General Harn Linanond, a former commander of the Fourth Army Region who
quit the army in 1984 in a dispute with General Arthit. In 1985 Harn,
who was deputy leader of the Democrat Party, and his party colleagues
opposed a one-year extension of service for Arthit, who was due for
retirement in September 1985. The army had reportedly ordered its
personnel in Bangkok to vote for former Lieutenant General Vitoon
Yasawas, Harn's rival, running on the Social Action Party ticket.
Tensions between the army and the Democrat Party also surfaced in
Thailand's first gubernatorial election for Bangkok in November 1985.
This contest was won handily by former Major General Chamlong Srimuang,
a devout Buddhist, former chief aide to Prem and former leader of the
Class Seven military academy graduates. Chamlong ran as an independent
but was strongly supported by Arthit, who publicly urged his
subordinates and their families to vote against any party that had an
antimilitary orientation. His urging was directed particularly against
the Democrat Party. Arthit's support would have made little difference
in the outcome of the contest because of Chamlong's immense personal
appeal to nearly every segment of the Bangkok electorate.
The eventful year of 1986 augured well for the future of party
politics. Prem's coalition overcame a minor cabinet crisis, reined in
outspoken Arthit, held the third parliamentary election since 1979, and
improved the climate for professionalization of the military. At the
root of the cabinet crisis was endemic factional strife within the
Social Action Party, the senior partner in Prem's four-party coalition.
This problem necessitated a cabinet reorganization in January and, worse
still, caused the coalition government an embarrassing parliamentary
defeat on a routine legislative bill. Facing the certainty of a major
parliamentary fight over a motion of no-confidence against his
government, Prem consulted King Bhumibol and dissolved the House of
Representatives, with an election slated for July 27--eleven months
ahead of schedule. The political arena was explosive at that juncture,
as a result of mounting tension between the two competing poles of
power--Prem and Arthit. Relations between them had become steadily
strained since Arthit's public assault on the government's fiscal and
monetary policies in November 1984.
Another complicating factor was Arthit's decision to set up the
army's "election-monitoring center" in connection with the
forthcoming election, an action some Thai criticized as an unwarranted
foray into politics. Still another complication was active lobbying by
Arthit's loyalists to have the army commander in chief's term extended
another year to September 1987. If these loyalists had had their way,
the extension would have enabled them to influence political realignment
to their advantage in 1987--after Prem's four-year mandate expired in
April. A new election, to be held within sixty days from mid-April,
would have been held while the army was still under Arthit's direction.
On March 24, 1986, the government announced that Arthit would be
retired as scheduled on September 1. Then on May 27, the government
stunned the nation by dismissing the army commander in chief and
replacing him with General Chaovalit Yongchaiyut, a Prem loyalist. Prior
to that, no army commander in chief had been fired before the expiration
of his term. This unprecedented action came amid the flurry of rumors
that Arthit was involved in behind-the-scenes maneuvers to undermine
Prem's chances for another premiership after the July election. Arthit,
whose largely ceremonial post as supreme commander of the armed forces
until September 1986 was not affected by the dismissal order, denied any
role in such maneuvers.
Chaovalit quickly set the tone of his army leadership by promising to
keep the military out of politics, by dissolving the army's election
watchdog center, and by pledging military neutrality in the election.
Later in August, the army announced that twenty-eight of the
thirty-eight Young Turks officers cashiered in the wake of the abortive
coup in 1981 had been reinstated to active service; Colonel Manoon
officially remained a fugitive from prosecution. The reinstatement,
though mostly to nonsensitive noncommand positions, was widely welcomed
as an important step toward restoring unity in the army and improving
the prospect for military professionalism. In the annual September
reshuffle of senior military officials, Chaovalit strengthened his power
base by appointing Class Five graduates of the military academy to key
senior commands.
The July 1986 election involved the participation of 3,810 candidates
representing 16 parties. Candidates of the outgoing coalition parties
campaigned, generally avoiding any association with Prem. The contest
literally was wide open; no single party was expected to win an
electoral mandate outright in the newly enlarged 347-seat House of
Representatives. As in 1983, Prem declined to run in this election,
citing the "need to maintain my neutrality and to let the election
be held . . . free from any factor that may sway the people."
Nevertheless, because he might again be picked as the compromise choice
of major parties to lead the postelection government, the issue of an
elected or nonelected prime minister became a focus of campaign debate.
Regardless of partisanship, however, nearly all agreed that the
austerity measures that had been initiated by the outgoing government
should be scuttled as a major step toward accelerating economic recovery
and boosting rural incomes. Evidently Bangkok's powerful banking and
business families, who had suffered as a result of such measures since
late 1984, effectively brought their influence to bear on many
candidates. The army did not intervene, but Chaovalit warned that the
military would not stand idly by if the postelection government failed
the people's trust.
Predictably, no party emerged with a majority, although the Democrat
Party captured the largest bloc of seats with 100, which was 44 more
than it had in 1983. Most observers agreed that a coalition led by the
Democrat Party would stand little chance of survival; the party had
nowhere near a majority and, moreover, was traditionally the most
outspoken critic of military involvement in politics. Thus, despite the
lack of any ground swell for a nonelected prime minister, Prem again
emerged as the compromise leader most acceptable to the army, the
palace, and the major political parties.
The new coalition cabinet Prem unveiled in August consisted of four
parties, with a combined strength of 232 seats distributed among the
Democrat Party (100), the Chart Thai Party (63), the Social Action Party
(51), and the Rassadorn (People) Party (18). These four were among the
seven parties that initially agreed to support Prem; the remaining three
not in the coalition were the Prachakorn Thai Party (24), the Ruam Thai
(Thai Unity) Party (19), and the Community Action (Kit Prachakhorn)
Party (15). The three parties later formed an opposition bloc with
several other minor parties. The United Democracy Party, which commanded
thirty-eight seats, agreed to support the opposition bloc in voting
against the government on an issue-by-issue basis.
In September 1986, the fifty-four-year-old army commander in chief,
Chaovalit, pledged his support for "the parliamentary
government," adding that there would be "no more coups"
as long as he was in charge of the army. Earlier, he had expressed an
intention to retire in 1988 (reaffirmed in July 1987); if he did not, he
could remain in his post until official retirement in 1992, or 1993 with
a one-year extension of service.
On April 22, 1987, the Prem administration faced a no- confidence
debate in parliament, the second one since October 1986. Eighty-four
opposition members sponsored the no-confidence motion against the entire
cabinet. However, amid allegations of bribery and rumors of a coup or a
parliamentary dissolution, the censure bid failed. Fifteen of the
sponsors, under heavy outside pressure, withdrew their names on the day
the debate was scheduled to take place, leaving the motion one vote shy
of the minimum seventy votes. Opposition leaders vowed to resubmit
another no-confidence motion later.
Thailand
Thailand - POLITICAL PARTIES
Thailand
In the late 1980s, the Thai political party system continued to
evolve, albeit spasmodically. It was at a delicate stage of transition
from its past status as an adjunct to the bureaucratic establishment to
a more substantial role as a channel for popular representation and a
provider of top political executives.
The concept of party politics dated back to the early 1930s, but its
impact was generally insignificant, having been overshadowed by the
military-bureaucratic elite. The struggle for power was nearly always
settled by coup, and the pluralistic demands of the society were
accommodated through either bureaucratic channels or patron-client
connections. For decades political parties had an uncertain status. When
they existed, they did so at the sufferance of generals, who abolished
or revived them at will. Parties were unable to maintain continuity, nor
could they develop a mass base. Part of the problem was the bad image of
partisan politics, which the politicians brought on themselves through
their unscrupulous pursuit of self-interest.
Party politics received a major impetus from the student uprising of
October 1973. Forty-two parties participated in the 1975
parliamentary election, and thirty-nine participated the following year.
The freewheeling partisan politics during the so-called democratic
period of 1973-76 ended in the coup of October 1976. Kriangsak, the army
commander in chief, appointed a civilian-led government, but the Thanin
Kraivichien regime turned out to be overly repressive and was overthrown
in 1977. Assuming the office of prime minister himself, Kriangsak
permitted the resumption of party politics banned by Thanin. Of the 39
parties that took part in the April 1979 election, 7 parties captured
about 70 percent of the 301 contested seats.
As a result of the confusion stemming from the proliferation of minor
parties, a new political parties act was passed in July 1981. The act,
which became effective in 1983, specified that to participate in an
election, a party must have a minimum of 5,000 members spread throughout
the country's four geographical regions. In each region, at least five
provinces must have members, the minimum per province being fifty. The
membership requirement was designed to foster the development of
mass-based parties catering to broad national interests rather than
narrow, sectional interests. Another provision of the act stipulated
that a party must put up candidates for at least half the total lower
house seats, or 174 seats. As a result, in the 1983 and 1986 elections,
the number of participating parties was reduced to fourteen and sixteen,
respectively. In order to satisfy the legal requirements, some parties
fielded candidates recruited from among recent college graduates.
In the 1980s, the country's multiparty system continued to suffer
from traditional long-standing problems. These included organizational
frailty and lack of discipline, endemic factionalism, the emphasis on
personalities over issues, and the politicians' penchant for vote-buying
and influence-peddling. Parties were formed, as before, by well-known or
wealthy individuals to promote their own personal, familial, parochial,
or regional interests. Observers expressed concern that failure to
improve the party system could result in a return to authoritarian
military rule.
The perception that political parties and politicians were unworthy
of trust was widespread in 1987. However, a coup was ruled out by
Chaovalit, the new army commander in chief, even though he publicly
castigated politicians as venal and hypocritical. In February he
asserted that political parties, the Constitution, and elections alone
would not make for a genuine democracy in Thailand, where, he argued,
the party system and elections were controlled by a wealthy few who used
the trappings of democracy for their own benefit. Appearing before a
parliamentary committee in April 1987, Chaovalit maintained that to
build a real Thai-style democracy with the king as head of state, the
ever-widening income disparity must be narrowed first and that at the
same time political parties and all government entities including the
military "must join hands and walk ahead together."
The major Thai parties, which Chaovalit had criticized, were mostly
right-of-center. Their numerical representation in the House of
Representatives varied considerably from one election to another. Of the
four ruling coalition parties in 1987, the Democrat Party was considered
to be somewhat liberal, despite its beginning in 1946 as a conservative,
monarchist party. Seni Pramoj, prime minister in 1946 and again in 1976,
led the party from its inception until 1979. In 1974 the party suffered
major fragmentation and lost some key figures, including Kukrit, Seni's
brother, who formed the Social Action Party that year. In the 1979
election, the Democrats suffered a major setback but rebounded in 1983.
Over the years, this party consistently opposed military involvement in
politics and actively sought to broaden its base of support across all
social segments and geographical regions. In recent years, particularly
after July 1986, the Democrats were racked by internal strife. Their
leader Bhichai Rattakul, deputy prime minister in Prem's coalition, was
reconfirmed in a factional showdown in January 1987. Afterward, retired
Lieutenant Colonel Sanan Khachornprasart was named secretary general, in
place of Veera Musikapong, whose faction had been backed by wealthy
Bangkok businessman Chalermphan Srivikorn.
The Chart Thai Party, sometimes called the "generals'
party," was founded in 1974 by a group of retired generals and was
led until July 1986 by Pramarn Adireksan, retired major general and
former president of the Association of Thai Industries and the Thai
Textile Association. Aggressively anticommunist, Chart Thai was backed
by a number of prominent industrialists. After the July 1986 election,
it was led by retired General Chatichai Choonhaven, whose relationship
with Prem was friendly.
The Social Action Party, a 1974 offshoot of the Democrat Party, was
led by Thai statesman Kukrit Pramoj until he stepped down in December
1985. The party was led thereafter by the former deputy party leader and
minister of foreign affairs, Siddhi Savetsila, a retired air chief
marshal. More than any other party, the Social Action Party was
identified with a free enterprise economy. In the 1986 election, the
party suffered a severe loss, brought on in no small part by its own
internal strife. In May 1986, a splinter faction led by
seventy-four-year- old Boontheng Thongsawasdi formed the United
Democracy Party with financial support from big business--amid a spate
of rumors that General Arthit was also among the party's behind-the
scenes backers. In the July 1986 election and afterward, the United
Democracy Party was outspokenly critical of the Prem administration.
The Rassadorn Party, the fourth member of the ruling coalition, was
formed only a few months before the July 1986 election; until May 1986
it was known as the National Union (Sahachat) Party. Its leader was
Thienchai Sirisamphan, retired deputy army commander in chief. Rassadorn
came to be known as a pak taharn (military party) because its
key party posts were held by retired generals. Its entry into partisan
politics was welcomed by many for providing a constructive channel for
military involvement in parliamentary government.
The exclusion of the United Democracy Party from the fifth coalition
government was predictable in light of its anti-Prem stance. However, it
probably came as a surprise to Samak Sundaravej, leader of the
Prachakorn Thai Party formed in 1978, that his right-wing and monarchist
group was not invited to join the coalition. Before the election, master
orator Samak stated that the new postelection government should continue
its strong military ties and should once again be led by outgoing Prem.
In so doing, he rejected the suggestion that Kukrit Pramoj, who had
retired from party politics altogether in May 1986, should head the new
postelection regime.
The Ruam Thai Party and the Community Action Party, both formed in
1986, were also among the seven parties supporting Prem for continued
premiership; but they, too, were left out of the coalition. The leader
of the Ruam Thai Party, Narong Wongwan, was a former member of the
Social Action Party and outgoing minister of agriculture and
cooperatives. The Community Action Party was led by its founder Boonchu
Rojanasathien, one-time deputy prime minister in charge of economic
affairs, ex-deputy leader of the Social Action Party, and former
president of the Bangkok Bank.
The remaining seven parties with one or more elected House of
Representatives members formed the "Group of Nineteen," so
named because of their combined total of nineteen members. These parties
agreed in August 1986 to join with other noncoalition parties to form a
united front in an attempt to ensure efficient and systematic monitoring
of the government. In a crucial showdown over a no-confidence motion
against the Prem government in April 1987, however, the opposition bloc
suffered a major political embarrassment because of the last-minute
defection from the censure debate by fifteen of its members. Boonchu,
chief strategist of the five-member opposition leadership team, expelled
five members from his Community Action Party for their action.
Thailand
Thailand - FOREIGN AFFAIRS
Thailand
Diplomacy has served Thailand well, enabling the kingdom to manage
its foreign affairs flexibly and relatively unencumbered by intrusions
of major foreign powers. Remarkably adaptive to shifts in international
currents, Thailand has almost always aligned itself with the dominant
power in the region in its effort to ensure security, increase trade,
and preserve national independence. In the 1980s, its primary concern
was to normalize relations with Cambodia and Laos--relations that were
complicated by the Vietnamese military presence in these countries.
Background
Since World War II, no single factor has shaped the style and
substance of Thai foreign relations more than the establishment of a
communist-run government in China in 1949. The communist triumph aroused
a Thai fear of southward Chinese expansion, in which the economically
powerful and ethnocentrist Chinese minority in Bangkok might serve as a
potential fifth column. Chinese intervention in Korea in 1950 and
growing evidence of clandestine communist Chinese roles in local
insurgencies in Southeast Asia reinforced Thai resolve to act in concert
with other anticommunist nations. The formal installation of a communist
administration in Hanoi after the decisive defeat of the French at Dien
Bien Phu in May 1954 set the stage for Thailand's signing of the Manila
Pact, a collective security agreement, in September 1954. The resulting
Southeast Asia Treaty Organization (SEATO), as the regional body was
formally called, had as its members Australia, Britain, France, New
Zealand, Pakistan, the Philippines, Thailand, and the United States.
SEATO headquarters was in Bangkok.
Nevertheless, Thailand viewed the effectiveness of collective
security with some degree of skepticism. On March 6, 1962, in an attempt
to allay Thai apprehensions, the United States and Thailand reached a
new understanding under what came to be known as the Rusk-Thanat
agreement (named after then-Secretary of State Dean Rusk and
then-Minister of Foreign Affairs Thanat Khoman). Under the agreement,
the United States pledged that, in the event of aggression it would help
Thailand unilaterally without prior agreement of all other parties to
the Manila Pact.
During the 1960s, Thailand maintained close economic and security
ties with the United States, while at the same time striving to foster
regional cooperation with its noncommunist neighbors. Its assumption was
that regional solidarity and national security were mutually reinforcing
and would provide an effective deterrence to communism. In 1961 Thailand
joined Malaya (since 1963, Malaysia) and the Philippines in launching
the Association of Southeast Asia as a nonmilitary, nonpolitical vehicle
for consultation and mutual assistance in economic, cultural,
scientific, and administrative matters.
In 1967 the Association of Southeast Asia was replaced by a broader
regional group, the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN),
comprising Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, and
Thailand. The members agreed to cooperate in food production, industry
and commerce, civil aviation, shipping, tourism, communications,
meteorology, science and technology, and Southeast Asian studies.
Consultation and cooperation were to take place through an annual
ministerial conference held in each of the five ASEAN countries in
alphabetical rotation. As a result of the formation of the regional
organization, consultation between Thailand and the other ASEAN
countries on external problems increased greatly in the 1970s.
The Thai response to the external uncertainties of the 1970s was a
graphic demonstration of the flexibility of its foreign policy. The
external catalyst was an apparent shift in American strategic thinking
with regard to China and the Vietnam conflict. The shift was sensed in
Bangkok in the late 1960s--in March 1968, when President Lyndon B.
Johnson expressed his intention to seek a negotiated peace in Vietnam
and again in July 1969, when President Richard M. Nixon told Thai
leaders in Bangkok of his intention to lower the future American
military profile in Asia without undertaking any new security
obligations. At that time, Nixon reaffirmed the United States resolve to
"honor its present commitments in Southeast Asia" and to
continue its support of Thai efforts in the areas of security and
economic development. Not surprisingly, in 1968, before the "Nixon
Doctrine" was proclaimed in 1969, Thailand hinted at its desire to
open channels of communication with China, the Democratic People's
Republic of Korea (North Korea), and the Democratic Republic of Vietnam
(North Vietnam). These channels were considered necessary by the Thai in
order to solve difficulties and achieve peaceful coexistence. In late
1970, a government committee was set up to explore the possibility of
normalizing relations with China.
After 1971, as the United States and China moved toward
reconciliation and detente, Thai soul-searching began in earnest. In
1972 Thailand sent sports teams to China, and in 1973 Thailand made
overtures to Hanoi for a dialogue shortly after the United States and
North Vietnam signed a cease-fire agreement. In 1974 a Thai delegation
conferred with Chinese premier Zhou Enlai in Beijing on measures to
improve bilateral relations. At that time Zhou was reported to have
assured the Thai delegation that China would stop aiding communist
insurgents in Thailand, while underlining his concern over increasing
Soviet influence in Southeast Asia. In December 1974, the Thai
government lifted a fifteen-year ban on trade with China. In March 1975,
a month before Saigon fell, Thailand announced its decision to recognize
and normalize diplomatic relations with China.
In the wake of communist takeovers in Phnom Penh and Saigon in April
1975, Thailand moved expeditiously to realign its foreign policy.
Thailand's security ties with the United States-- the pillar of
Bangkok's foreign relations for nearly three decades--were downplayed as
part of accentuating a policy of friendship with all nations. In July
1975, the Thai revoked a military accord with the United States under
which American troops had been allowed on Thai soil. Thailand also
agreed with the Philippines in principle that SEATO, having outlived its
usefulness, should be phased out as early as possible. The crowning
moment of the policy of readjustment came in July 1975, when Thailand
and China signed a formal agreement on establishing diplomatic
relations. Noteworthy was the absence of a Chinese demand for the prior
removal of American troops from Thailand, in striking contrast to
Hanoi's insistence that Thailand should first renounce its policy of
"collusion" with the United States before any reconciliation
could take place.
The normalization of relations with its Indochinese neighbors became
pressing as refugees from Laos, Cambodia, and Vietnam streamed across
the Thai frontier, straining Thai resources and raising tensions in the
border regions. Relations with Laos, bound to Thailand by a shared
history, religion, ethnicity, culture, and language, were tense. Much of
the problem centered on Laotian Meo tribespeople who had taken refuge in
Thailand after the communist-led Pathet Lao forces gained control of
Vientiane in May 1975. For years the Meo and some Thai irregular troops
had waged clandestine operations against the Pathet Lao forces,
reportedly with the knowledge and cooperation of the government of
Thailand. After intermittent clashes on the Mekong River, Thailand in
November 1975 closed the frontier with Laos, causing hardship in
Vientiane; this action prevented oil, food, and other essential goods
from reaching Laos through Thai territory, the historical transit route
to the landlocked country. Tension eased somewhat after January 1976,
when the border was reopened following Thai recognition of the new
Laotian regime. In August 1976, the two countries signed an agreement on
the transport of Laotian goods through Thailand in exchange for Thai air
routes over Laos to Vietnam and Hong Kong. Nonetheless, recurring border
incidents led to a temporary Thai economic blockade of Laos in late
1977. By the end of the year, Laotian refugees accounted for 73,000 of
about 95,000 Indochinese refugees encamped in Thailand.
In April 1975, Thailand was the first country in Southeast Asia to
recognize the new regime of the communist Khmer
Rouge in Phnom Penh. In October the two countries
agreed in principle to resume diplomatic and economic relations; the
agreement was formalized in June 1976, when they also agreed to erect
border markers in poorly defined border areas.
Meanwhile, the withdrawal of all American troops from Thailand by
July 1976 paved the way for the Thai-Vietnamese agreement in August on
normalizing relations. In January 1978, Bangkok and Hanoi signed an
accord on trade and economic and technical cooperation, agreeing also to
exchange ambassadors, reopen aviation links, resolve all problems
through negotiations, and consult on the question of delimiting sea
boundaries. Progress toward improved relations with the Indochinese
states came to an abrupt halt, however, after Vietnam invaded Cambodia
in December 1978, and in January 1979 installed in Phnom Penh a new
communist regime friendly to Hanoi.
This invasion not only provoked a Chinese attack on Vietnam in
February 1979 but also posed a threat to Thailand's security. Bangkok
could no longer rely on Cambodia as a buffer against Vietnamese power.
Bangkok was forced to assume the role of a frontline state against a
resurgent communist Vietnam, which had 300,000 troops in Cambodia and
Laos. The Thai government began increasing its defense capabilities.
While visiting Washington in February 1979, Prime Minister Kriangsak
asked for and received reassurances of military support from the United
States. His government also launched a major diplomatic offensive to
press for the withdrawal of all Vietnamese forces from Cambodia and for
continued international recognition of Democratic Kampuchea under Pol
Pot's Khmer Rouge regime. As part of that offensive, Kriangsak also
journeyed to Moscow in March 1979--the first visit ever by a Thai prime
minister--to explain the Thai position on the Cambodian question and to
reassure the Soviets that Thailand's anti-Vietnamese position was
neither anti-Soviet nor pro-Chinese. Such reassurances were believed to
be necessary in view of Vietnamese accusations that Thailand
collaborated with China and the United States in aiding and abetting the
Khmer Rouge forces against the Heng Samrin regime.
The Thai offensive, backed by Bangkok's ASEAN partners, was rewarded
in a United Nations (UN) General Assembly resolution adopted in November
1979. The resolution called for immediate withdrawal of all foreign
forces from Cambodia, asked all nations to refrain from interfering in,
or staging acts of aggression against, Cambodia, and called on the UN
secretary general to explore the possibility of an international
conference on Cambodia.
Foreign Relations since 1980
In the 1980s, the Cambodian-Vietnamese question was a principal
concern of Thai foreign policy makers, who found common cause with
countries that also opposed the Vietnamese occupation of Cambodia.
Security once again became an important consideration in the
determination of Bangkok's foreign policy.
In 1979 the ASEAN members were apparently divided over the
Cambodian-Vietnamese situation. Indonesia and Malaysia were reportedly
more conciliatory toward Hanoi than Thailand and Singapore, viewing
China rather than Vietnam as the principal threat to regional stability.
Indonesia and Malaysia wanted a strong and stable Vietnam as a potential
ally, or at least as a buffer, against Chinese expansionism. They were
inclined to tolerate to a degree the Vietnamese presence in Cambodia and
to recognize the Heng Samrin regime, provided that some Vietnamese
troops were withdrawn from Cambodia and the political base of the regime
was reconstituted more broadly.
The ASEAN differences were turned aside in June 1980, when Vietnamese
troops crossed the border into Thailand. The incursion, which coincided
with an annual ASEAN ministerial conference in Kuala Lumpur, was
contrary to earlier Vietnamese assurances that they would not encroach
on Thai territory. The ASEAN foreign ministers strongly condemned the
incursion as "an act of aggression" and reaffirmed their
undivided support for the UN resolution of November 1979. They also
reaffirmed their recognition of the deposed government of Democratic
Kampuchea-- their rationale being that to recognize the Heng Samrin
regime would be tantamount to rewarding Vietnamese aggression in
Cambodia. At the first UN-sponsored international conference on Cambodia
held in New York in July 1981, Thailand and its ASEAN allies played a
key role in seeking a political settlement of the Cambodian question.
The conference was attended by delegates from seventy-nine countries and
observers from fifteen others, but it was boycotted by Vietnam, Laos,
the Soviet Union and its allies, and some nonaligned nations. The
conference adopted a resolution that, among other things, called for a
cease-fire by all armed Cambodian factions, the withdrawal of all
foreign troops under the supervision of a UN observer group, the
restoration of Cambodian independence, the establishment of a nonaligned
and neutral Cambodia, and the establishment of an ad hoc committee
comprising Japan, Malaysia, Nigeria, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Sudan, and
Thailand to advise the UN secretary general on ways to implement the
resolution.
Relations between Thailand and China improved steadily in the 1980s,
with Beijing sharing Bangkok's opposition to Vietnamese military
occupation of Cambodia and affirming its support for the Thai and ASEAN
stance on the Cambodian question. China sought to reassure Bangkok of
its withdrawal of support for the Communist Party of Thailand and
offered military assistance to Thailand in the event the latter was
attacked by Vietnam. In the mid-1980s, Chinese arms and supplies for the
Khmer Rouge resistance forces reportedly were being shipped through Thai
territory. In 1985 a telephone hotline was established between Thailand
and China in an effort to coordinate their activities in the event of a
major Vietnamese incursion into Thailand. Cordiality in Thai-Chinese
relations was evident in a military assistance agreement signed in
Beijing in May 1987. This agreement allowed Thailand to purchase, on
concessional terms, Chinese tanks, antiaircraft guns, missiles,
ammunition, and armored personnel carriers.
Despite some friction over trade issues, Thai relations with the
United States were very close, especially from 1979 onward. The United
States reassured its commitment to Thai security under the Rusk-Thanat
agreement of 1962 as well as the Manila Pact of 1954. In addition to
backing the ASEAN position on Cambodia, Washington steadily increased
its security assistance to Thailand and also took part in a series of
annual bilateral military exercises. Spurred by Vietnamese incursions in
1985 and the arrival in Vietnam of Soviet-piloted MiG-23s, Thailand
decided to buy twelve F-16 fighter-bombers from General Dynamics in the
United States. Moreover, under an accord reached in October 1985, the
two countries began to set up a war reserve weapons stockpile on Thai
soil, making Thailand the first country without a United States military
base to have such a stockpile. The stockpile, subject to approval by the
United States Congress, was to be used only in a
"nation-threatening emergency" or to repulse possible armed
invasion by Soviet-supported Vietnamese and other forces from Cambodia.
Trade was an irritant in Thai-American relations, but many observers
agreed that the trade problems would not likely affect the long-standing
friendship and cooperation between the two countries. The United States
was a major trading partner and by 1985 had become the largest and most
important export market for Thai goods. Thailand enjoyed a trade surplus
with the United States, which grew from a modest US$100 million in 1983
to about US$1 billion in 1986. Meanwhile, there was growing Thai
criticism that the United States had become protectionist in trade
relations with Thailand. By 1987, however, many informed Thai had come
to believe that problems in Thai-American trade relations would be
temporary.
In 1987 Thailand continued to express its desire for mutually
beneficial relations with the Soviet Union and to affirm its neutrality
in the Sino-Soviet rivalry. Relations with Moscow, however, were merely
correct, if not cool, as a result of Thai apprehension over Soviet
intentions toward Southeast Asia in general and Vietnam in particular.
Thai concern was prompted by Moscow's military aid to Vietnam and its
continued support of Hanoi's involvement in Cambodia. During his visit
to Moscow in May 1987, Minister of Foreign Affairs Siddhi Savetsila of
Thailand told his Soviet counterpart that Cambodia was "the test
case" of Soviet intentions toward Asia and the Pacific region. He
urged the Soviet Union to use its "immense influence and
prestige" to bring about a quick and durable settlement of the
Cambodian question. Such settlement, according to Siddhi, entailed an
early withdrawal of some 140,000 Vietnamese troops from Cambodia,
Cambodian exercise of the right of self- determination, and the
formation of a neutral and nonaligned Cambodia posing no threat to its
neighbors. At the end of the May visit, a protocol was signed
establishing a Thai-Soviet trade commission.
As Thailand and Japan celebrated the centennial of their relationship
in 1987, Japan continued to be Thailand's principal trading partner and
largest foreign investor. The generally cordial relations between
the two countries--dating back to 1887, when Japan was the first country
to set up a foreign embassy in Bangkok--were marred in the 1970s and
1980s by a continuous imbalance of trade. In 1984 Thailand's trade
deficit with Japan accounted for 62 percent of its total trade deficit
for the year, up from 46 percent in the previous year. Japan's economic
dominance was much criticized as exploitive and, in late 1984, was the
target of a campaign against Japanese goods launched by university
students. The Thai government stated that such a campaign offered little
or no solution to the deficit problem. Thailand's preferred solution was
for Japan to open its market to Thai products, increase its aid and
loans to Thailand, set up export-oriented industries in Thailand, and
enhance economic cooperation through more active transfers of
technology. In 1986 Thailand's trade deficit with Japan decreased 32
percent from the 1984 figure.
In 1987 a major foreign policy goal for Thailand was the restoration
of its traditionally cordial ties with Laos, strained since 1975, when
Bangkok came to perceive Laos as a client state of Vietnam. In 1979
Thailand and Laos agreed to improve their relations by promoting
bilateral trade and allowing free access to the Mekong River by border
residents. Nonetheless, relations between Bangkok and Vientiane
continued to be tense, marred by frequent shooting incidents on the
Mekong. In 1981 Thailand banned 273 "strategic" commodities
from export or transshipment to Laos. In mid-1984 armed clashes occurred
over the status of three remote border villages. Laos raised this issue
in the UN Security Council, rejecting Thailand's proposal to determine
the territoriality of the villages through a joint or neutral survey
team. Meanwhile, one important economic link continued to be unaffected
by political or security matters: Laos sold electricity to Thailand,
earning as much as 75 percent of its annual foreign exchange from this
transaction.
On the initiative of Laos, the two sides met in November 1986 to
reaffirm their commitment to the 1979 accord on neighborly relations. At
about the same time, Thailand began to relax its trade embargo, thereby
decreasing the number of banned items to sixty-one. Apparently, this
action was taken under pressure from Thai businessmen, whose exports to
Laos had dropped sharply from 81 percent of the total imports of Laos in
1980 to 26 percent in 1984. Thai exports to Laos increased in 1985 and
1986, but the future of economic links between the two countries was
uncertain. With Soviet assistance, the Laotians planned to complete by
1988 a major highway from Savannakhet across Laos to the Vietnamese port
of Danang, thus lessening the traditional dependence of Laos on Thailand
for access to the sea for foreign trade.
In March 1987, the two sides met again to discuss matters of mutual
concern but made no progress. Although 40,000 to 60,000 Vietnamese
troops were still present on Laotian soil, Laos continued to accuse
Thailand of harboring its historic ambition to dominate the region.
Moreover, Vientiane accused Bangkok of being in collusion with the
United States in engaging in unfriendly acts to destabilize the Laotian
government. The alleged acts, along with Thai occupation of the three
"Lao villages," were stated by Vientiane to be the main
barriers to improvement of Laotian-Thai relations. For its part,
Thailand charged that Laos was aiding the Pak Mai (New Party), a small,
pro-Vietnamese, Thai communist insurgent group that had split from the
Chinese-backed Communist Party of Thailand in 1979. Furthermore,
Thailand accused Laos of turning a blind eye to heroin production inside
Laos and of refusing to cooperate in the suppression of narcotics
trafficking between Laos and Thailand. In March 1987, the Bangkok
Post lamented in an editorial, "It is strange but true that
the country with which Thailand has just about everything to share
except ideology should happen to be one of the hardest to deal
with."
Nevertheless, Thailand was committed to solving its problems with the
neighboring states of Indochina--Cambodia, Laos, and Vietnam. The Thai
flexibility in foreign policy that had enabled the country to avoid
conquest or colonization by foreign powers included a dedication to
maintaining good relations with all nations, great and small. Given this
commitment and adaptability, it was likely that Thailand, perhaps in
concert with its ASEAN partners, would soon reach a mutually agreeable
accommodation with its Indochinese neighbors.
Thailand
Thailand - Bibliography
Thailand
Akin, Rabibhadana. The Organization of Thai Society in the
Early Bangkok Period, 1782-1873. (Southeast Asia
Program, Data Paper, No. 74.) Ithaca: Department of Asian
Studies, Cornell University, 1969.
Allen, Richard. A Short Introduction to the History and
Politics of Southeast Asia. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1970.
Alsop, Joseph. "Rewriting Human History," Washington
Post, September 8, 1975, A26.
Asian Development Bank. Southeast Asia's Economy in the
1970s. New York: Praeger, 1971.
Bastin, John, and Harry J. Benda. A History of Modern
Southeast Asia: Colonialism, Nationalism, and
Decolonization. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey:
Prentice-Hall, 1968.
Batson, Benjamin A. (ed.). Siam's Political Future: Documents
from the End of the Absolute Monarchy. (Southeast Asia
Program, Data Paper, No. 96.) Ithaca: Department of Asian
Studies, Cornell University, 1974.
Benda, Harry J., and John Larkin, with Sidney L. Mayer. The
World of Southeast Asia: Selected Historical Readings.
New York: Harper and Row, 1967.
Benedict, Ruth F. Thai Culture and Behavior. (Southeast
Asia Program, Data Paper, No. 4.) Ithaca: Department of
Asian Studies, Cornell University, 1952.
Berrigan, Darrell. "Thailand: New Cast, Same Play,"
Reporter, No. 17, November 28, 1957, 12-14.
------. "Thailand: Phibun Tries Prachathipatai,"
Reporter, No. 14, June 14, 1956, 30-34.
Bowie, Theodore (ed.). The Arts of Thailand.
Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1960.
Bowring, John. The Kingdom and the People of Siam. (2
Vols.) London: John W. Parker, 1857.
Briggs, Lawrence P. "The Appearance and Historical Usage of the
Terms Tai, Thai, Siamese, and Lao," Journal of the
American Oriental Society, 69, April-June 1949, 60-73.
Bruce, Helen. Nine Temples of Bangkok. Bangkok: Progress
Books, 1960.
Buchanan, Keith. The Southeast Asian World: An Introductory
Essay. Garden City, New York: Anchor Books, Doubleday,
1968.
Bunnag, Tej. The Provincial Administration of Siam,
1892-1915: The Ministry of Interior under Prince
Ranajubhab. Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press,
1977.
Cadet, J.M. The Ramakien: The Thai Epic. Tokyo: Kodansha
International, 1970.
Cady, John F. Southeast Asia: Its Historical
Development. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1964.
Chandran Mohandas Jeshurun. The Contest for Siam 1889-1902: A
Study in Diplomatic Rivalry. Kuala Lumpur: Penerbit
University Kebangsaan Malaysia, 1977.
Charnvit Kasetsiri. The Rise of Ayudhya: A History of Siam in
the Fourteenth and Fifteenth Centuries. Kuala Lumpur:
Oxford University Press, 1976.
Chatthip Nartsupha, and Suthy Prasartset (eds.).
Socio-Economic Institutions and Cultural Change in Siam,
1851-1910: A Documentary Survey. (Southeast Asian
Perspectives Series, No. 4.) Singapore: Institute of
Southeast Asian Studies, 1977.
Chula Chakrabongse. Lords of Life: The Paternal Monarchy of
Bangkok, 1782-1932. New York: Taplinger, 1960.
Coed�s, Georges. The Indianized States of Southeast
Asia. Honolulu: East-West Center Press, 1968.
------. The Making of South East Asia. Berkeley and Los
Angeles: University of California Press, 1969.
Conze, Edward. The Buddhist Wisdom Books. London: Allen
and Unwin, 1958.
Crozier, Brian. South-East Asia in Turmoil.
Harmondsworth, Middlesex, United Kingdom: Penguin, 1968.
Darling, Frank C. "Marshal Sarit and Absolutist Rule in Thai-
land," Pacific Affairs [Vancouver], 33, December
1960, 347-60.
------. "Modern Politics in Thailand," Review of
Politics, 24, April 1962, 163-82.
------. Thailand and the United States. Washington:
Public Affairs Press, 1965.
------. "Thailand in 1977: The Search for Stability and
Progress," Asian Survey, 18, No. 2, February 1978,
153-63.
Dhani Nivat. "The Old Siamese Conception of the Monarchy,"
Journal of the Siam Society [Bangkok], 36, 1947,
91-106.
Direk, Jayanama. Siam and World War II. Bangkok: Social
Science Association of Thailand Press, n.d.
Donner, Wolf. The Five Faces of Thailand: An Economic
Geography. (Institute of Asian Affairs, Hamburg.) New
York: St. Martin's Press, 1978.
Engel, David M. Law and Kingship in Thailand During the Reign
of King Chulalongkorn. Ann Arbor: University of
Michigan Center for South and Southeast Asian Studies, 1975.
Fifield, Russell H. The Diplomacy of Southeast Asia:
1945-1958. New York: Harper and Row, 1958.
Frederic, Louis. The Art of Southeast Asia: Temples and
Sculpture. New York: Abrams, 1965.
Girling, John L.S. Thailand: Society and Politics.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1981.
Graham, Walter A. Siam. (2 Vols, 2d ed.) London:
Alexander Moring, 1924.
Hall. D.G.E. A History of South-East Asia. (2d ed.)
London: Macmillan, 1964.
Hanks, Lucien M. "Merit and Power in the Thai Social Order,"
American Anthropologist, 64, No. 6, December 1962,
1247-61.
Hearn, Robert (ed.). A Guide to Research Materials on
Thailand and Laos. Auburn, New York: Asia Library
Services, 1977.
Heine-Geldern, Robert G. Conceptions of State and Kingship in
Southeast Asia. (Southeast Asia Program, Data Paper,
No. 18.) Ithaca: Department of Asian Studies, Cornell
University, 1956.
Higham, Charles, and Amphan Kijngam. "Ban-Chiang and Northeast
Thailand--Palaeoenvironment and Economy," Journal of
Archaelogical Science, 6, No. 3, September 1979,
211-34.
Ho Kwon Ping. "Thailand's Broken Ricebowl," Far Eastern
Economic Review [Hong Kong], 102, No. 48, December 1,
1978, 40-46.
Ingram, James C. Economic Change in Thailand, 1850-1970.
Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1971.
Insor, D. Thailand: A Political, Social, and Economic
Analysis. New York: Praeger, 1963.
Ishii, Yoneo (ed.). Thailand: A Rice-Growing Society.
(Monographs of the Center for Southeast Asian Studies, Kyoto
University.) Honolulu: University Press of Hawaii, 1978.
Jones, Robert R. Thai Titles and Ranks: Including a
Translation of Traditions of Royal Lineage in Siam by King
Chulalongkorn. (Southeast Asia Program, Data Paper, No.
81.) Ithaca: Department of Asian Studies, Cornell
University, 1971.
Keyes, Charles F. Thailand: Buddhist Kingdom as Modern
Nation-State. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1987.
Kirk, Donald. Wider War: The Struggle for Cambodia, Thailand,
and Laos. New York: Praeger, 1971.
Kunstadter, Peter (ed.). Southeast Asian Tribes, Minorities,
and Nations. (2 Vols.) Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1967.
Lebar, Frank M., et al. Ethnic Groups of Mainland Southeast
Asia. New Haven, Connecticut: Human Relations Area
Files Press, 1964.
Lent, John A. (ed.). The Asian Newspapers' Reluctant
Revolution. Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1971.
Lester, Robert C. Theravada Buddhism in Southeast Asia.
Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1973.
McAlister, John T. (ed.). Southeast Asia: The Politics of
National Integration. New York: Random House, 1973.
Malalasekera, G.P. "Theravada Buddhism." Pages 161-94 in Ismail
R. al Faruqi (ed.), Historical Atlas of the Religions of
the World. New York: Macmillan, 1974.
Martin, James V., Jr. "Thai-American Relations in World War II,"
Journal of Asian Studies, 22, No. 4, August 1963,
451-67.
Mills, Lennox A. Southeast Asia: Illusion and Reality in
Politics and Economics. Minneapolis: University of
Minnesota Press, 1964.
Moffat, Abbot Low. Mongkut: The King of Siam. Ithaca:
Cornell University Press, 1961.
Morrison, Charles E., and Astri Suhrke. Strategies of
Survival: The Foreign Policy Dilemmas of Smaller Asian
States. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1979.
Moseley, George V.H. The Consolidation of the South China
Frontier. (Center for Chinese Studies, University of
California.) Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of
California Press, 1973.
Murti, T.R.V. The Central Philosophy of Buddhism.
London: Allen and Unwin, 1955.
Niksch, Larry A. "Thailand in 1981: the Prem Government Feels the
Heat," Asian Survey, 22, No. 2, February 1982, 191-
99.
Panikkar, K.M. Asia and Western Dominance. New York:
Collier Books, 1969.
Peterson, Alec. "Britain and Siam: The Latest Phase," Pacific
Affairs [Vancouver], 19, December 1946, 364-372.
Punyaratabandhu-Bhakdi, Suchitra. "Thailand in 1982: General
Arthit Takes Center Stage." Asian Survey, 23, No.
2, February 1983, 172-77.
------. "Thailand in 1983: Democracy, Thai Style." Asian
Survey, 24, no. 2, February 1984, 187-94.
Ramsay, Ansil. "Thailand 1978: Kriangsak--the Thai Who Binds."
Asian Survey, 19, no. 2, February 1979, 104-14.
Rawson, Phillip. The Art of Southeast Asia. London:
Thames and Hudson, 1967.
Riggs, Fred W. Thailand: The Modernization of a Bureaucratic
Polity. Honolulu: East-West Center Press, 1966.
Robinson, Warren C. "Economic Policy and Population Change in
Thailand," World Development [Oxford], 6, Nos. 11-
12, 1978, 1261-69.
Salmony, Alfred. Sculpture in Siam. New York: Harker Art
Books, 1972.
Sarasin, Viraphol. Sino-Siamese Trade, 1652-1853.
Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1977.
Seidenfaden, Eric. The Thai Peoples, I: The Origins and
Habitats of the Thai Peoples with a Sketch of Their Material
and Spiritual Culture. Bangkok: Siam Society, 1958.
Shaplen, Robert. Time Out of Hand: Revolution and Reaction in
Southeast Asia. New York: Harper and Row, 1969.
Sharp, Lauriston, and Lucien M. Hanks. Bang Chan: Social
History of a Rural Community in Thailand. Ithaca:
Cornell University Press, 1978.
Siffin, William J. The Thai Bureaucracy: Institutional Change
and Development. Honolulu: East-West Center Press,
1966.
Silpa, Bhirasri. Thai Architecture and Painting. (4th
ed.). Bangkok: National Culture Institute, 1956.
Skinner, George William. Chinese Society in Thailand: An
Analytical History. Ithaca: Cornell University Press,
1957.
Skinner, George William, and A. Thomas Kirsch (eds.). Change
and Persistence in Thai Society: Essays in Honor of
Lauriston Sharp. Ithaca: Cornell University Press,
1975.
Smith, Bardwell L. (ed.). Religion and Legitimation of Power
in Thailand, Laos, and Burma. (South and Southeast Asia
Studies.) Chambersburg, Pennsylvania: Anima Books, 1978.
Smith, Harold E. Historical and Cultural Dictionary of
Thailand. (Historical and Cultural Dictionaries of
Asia, No. 6.) Metuchen, New Jersey: Scarecrow Press, 1976.
Solheim, Wilhelm G. "New Light on a Forgotten Past," National
Geographic Magazine, 139, No. 3, March 1971, 330-39.
Steinberg, David Joel (ed.). In Search of Southeast Asia: A
Modern History. New York: Praeger, 1971.
Tarling, Nicholas. A Concise History of Southeast Asia.
New York: Praeger, 1966.
Textor, Robert B. "Cultural Futures for Thailand: An Ethnographic
Enquiry," Futures, 10, October 1978, 347-60.
Thak Chaloemtiarana. "Reflections on the Sarit Regime and the
Process of Political Change in Thailand: Some Conceptual and
Theoretical Reassessments," Southeast Asian
Studies, 16, No. 3, December 1978, 400-10.
Thamsook Numnonda. Thailand and the Japanese Presence, 1941-
45. (Research Notes and Discussions Series, No. 6.)
Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, October
1977.
Thompson, Virginia. "Government Instability in Siam," Far
Eastern Survey, 27, 1948, 185-89.
Trumbull, Robert. The Scrutable East: A Correspondent's
Report on Southeast Asia. New York: David McKay, 1964.
Van Roy, Edward. Economic Systems of Northern Thailand:
Structure and Change. Ithaca: Cornell University Press,
1971.
Vella, Walter F. Chaiyo: King Vajiravudh and the Development
of Thai Nationalism. Honolulu: University Press of
Hawaii, 1978.
------. The Impact of the West on Government in
Thailand. (University of California Publications in
Political Science, 4, No. 3.) Berkeley and Los Angeles:
University of California Press, 1955.
------. Siam under Rama III, 1824-1851. (Monographs of
the Association for Asian Studies, No. 4.) Locust Valley,
New York: Augustin, 1957.
Von Der Mehden, Fred R. South-East Asia 1930-1970: The Legacy
of Colonialism and Nationalism. New York: Norton, 1974.
Wales, Horace Geoffrey Quaritch. Ancient Siamese Government
and Administration. London: Bernard Quaritch, 1934.
------. Siamese State Ceremonies. London: Bernard
Quaritch, 1931.
Warren, William. "Out of Thai Soil an Archeological Upheaval,"
ASIA, 4, No. 3, September-October 1981, 26-28, 52-
54.
Wenk, Klaus. The Restoration of Thailand under Rama I,
1782-1809. (Association for Asian Studies Monographs
and Papers, No. 24.) Tucson: University of Arizona Press,
1968.
Werner, Jayne, et al. "October 1976: The Coup in Thailand,"
Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars, 9, No. 3,
July-September 1977, 2-51.
Wilson, David A. "The Military in Thai Politics." Pages 326-39 in
Robert O. Tilman (ed.), Man, State, and Society in
Contemporary Southeast Asia. New York: Praeger, 1969.
------. Politics in Thailand. Ithaca: Cornell University
Press, 1962.
------. "Thailand." Pages 3-72 in George McTurnan Kahin (ed.),
Governments and Politics in Southeast Asia. (2d
ed., Southeast Asia Program, Cornell University.) Ithaca:
Cornell University Press, 1964.
Wyatt, David K. The Politics of Reform in Thailand: Education
in the Reign of King Chulalongkorn. (Yale Southeast
Asia Studies, Cultural Report Series, No. 4.) New Haven:
Yale University Press, 1969.
------. Thailand: A Short History. New Haven: Yale
University Press, 1984.
Young, Gordon. The Hill Tribes of Northern Thailand. New
York: AMS Press, 1982.
Thailand