Peru - Acknowledgments and Preface
Peru
The authors would like to acknowledge any contributions made by the
writers of the 1981 edition of Peru: A Country Study. The
authors and book editor of the present volume would also like to thank
one of those writers in particular, James D. Rudolph, for kindly
supplying the official 1989 Peru regionalization map, on which the
corresponding map in this volume is based.
The authors are grateful to individuals in various agencies of the
United States government, private institutions, and Peruvian diplomatic
offices, who gave their time, research materials, and special knowledge
to provide information and perspective. Thanks also go to Ralph K.
Benesch, who oversees the Country Studies--Area Handbook Program for the
Department of the Army. None of these individuals, however, is in any
way responsible for the work of the authors.
The book editor would like to thank members of the Federal Research
Division who contributed directly to the preparation of the manuscript.
These include Sandra W. Meditz, who reviewed all textual and graphic
materials, served as liaison with the sponsoring agency, and provided
numerous substantive and technical contributions; Marilyn L. Majeska,
who reviewed editing and managed production; Andrea T. Merrill, who
edited the tables; and Barbara Edgerton and Izella Watson, who did the
word processing. Thanks also go to Cissie Coy, who edited the chapters;
Beverly J. Wolpert, who performed the final prepublication editorial
review; and Joan C. Cook, who compiled the index. The Library of
Congress Printing and Processing Section performed the phototypesetting,
under the supervision of Peggy Pixley.
David P. Cabitto provided invaluable graphics support, including
preparation of several maps. He was assisted by Wayne Horne, who
prepared the cover artwork; Harriett R. Blood, who prepared the
topography and drainage map; and the firm of Greenhorne and O'Mara.
Deborah Anne Clement designed the illustrations on the title page of
each chapter.
Finally, the authors acknowledge the generosity of the individuals
and the public and private agencies who allowed their photographs to be
used in this study.
Like its predecessor, this study is an attempt to examine objectively
and concisely the dominant historical, social, economic, political, and
military aspects of contemporary Peru. Sources of information included
scholarly books, journals, monographs, official reports of governments
and international organizations, and numerous periodicals. To the extent
possible, place-names follow the system adopted by the United States
Board on Geographic Names. Measurements are given in the metric system.
Spanish surnames generally are composed of both the father's and
mother's family names, in that order, although there are numerous
variations. In the instance of Alan Garc�a P�rez, for example, Garc�a
is his patronymic and P�rez is his mother's maiden name. In informal
use, the matronymic is often dropped, a practice that usually has been
followed in this book, except in cases where the individual could easily
be confused with a relative or someone with the same patronymic.
The body of the text reflects information available as of November
1992. Certain other portions of the text, however, have been updated.
The Bibliography lists published sources thought to be particularly
helpful to the reader.
Peru
Peru - History
Peru
Pre-Inca Cultures
The first great conquest of Andean space began some 10,000 years ago
when the descendants of the original migrants who crossed the land
bridge over what is now the Bering Straits between the Asian and
American continents reached northern South America. Over the next
several millennia, hunter-gatherers fanned out from their bridgehead at
Panama to populate the whole of South America. By about 2500 B.C., small
villages inhabited by farmers and fishermen began to spring up in the
fertile river valleys of the north coast of Peru.
These ancient Peruvians lived in simple adobe houses, cultivated
potatoes and beans, fished in the nearby sea, and grew and wove cotton
for their clothing. The catalyst for the development of the more
advanced civilizations that followed was the introduction of a staple
annual crop--maize (corn), and the development of irrigation, both
dating from around the thirteenth century B.C. The stabilization of the
food supply and ensuing surplus formed the foundation for the
development of the great civilizations that rose and fell across the
Andes for more than a thousand years prior to the arrival of the
Europeans.
The Incas, of course, were only the most recent of these highly
developed native American cultures to evolve in the Andes. The earliest
central state to emerge in the northern highlands (that is, a state able
to control both highland and coastal areas) was the Kingdom of Chav�n,
which emerged in the northern highlands and prospered for some 500 years
between 950 B.C. and 450 B.C. Although it was originally thought by
Julio C. Tello, the father of Peruvian archaeology, to have been
"the womb of Andean civilization," it now appears to have had
Amazonic roots that may have led back to Mesoamerica.
Chav�n was probably more of a religious than political panAndean
phenomenon. It seems to have been a center for the missionary diffusion
of priests who transmitted a particular set of ideas, rituals, and art
style throughout what is now northcentral Peru. The apparent
headquarters for this religious cult in all likelihood was Chav�n de
Huantar in the Ancash highlands, whose elaborately carved stone masonry
buildings are among the oldest and most beautiful in South America. The
great, massive temple there, oriented to the cardinal points of the
solstice, was perceived by the people of Chav�n to be the center of the
world, the most holy and revered place of the Chav�n culture. This
concept of God and his elite tied to a geographical location at the
center of the cosmos--the idea of spatial mysticism--was fundamental to
Inca and pre-Inca beliefs.
After the decline of the Chav�n culture around the beginning of the
Christian millennium, a series of localized and specialized cultures
rose and fell, both on the coast and in the highlands, during the next
thousand years. On the coast, these included the Gallinazo, Mochica,
Paracas, Nazca, and Chim� civilizations. Although each had their
salient features, the Mochica and Chim� warrant special comment for
their notable achievements.
The Mochica occupied a 136-kilometer-long expanse of the coast from
the R�o Moche Valley and reached its apogee toward the end of the first
millennium A.D. They built an impressive irrigation system that
transformed kilometers of barren desert into fertile and abundant fields
capable of sustaining a population of over 50,000. Without benefit of
the wheel, the plough, or a developed writing system, the Mochica
nevertheless achieved a remarkable level of civilization, as witnessed
by their highly sophisticated ceramic pottery, lofty pyramids, and
clever metalwork. In 1987 near Sip�n, archaeologists unearthed an
extraordinary cache of Mochica artifacts from the tomb of a great
Mochica lord, including finely crafted gold and silver ornaments, large,
gilded copper figurines, and wonderfully decorated ceramic pottery.
Indeed, the Mochica artisans portrayed such a realistic and accurately
detailed depiction of themselves and their environment that we have a
remarkably authentic picture of their everyday life and work.
Whereas the Mochica were renowned for their realistic ceramic
pottery, the Chim� were the great city-builders of pre-Inca
civilization. As loose confederation of cities scattered along the coast
of northern Peru and southern Ecuador, the Chim� flourished from about
1150 to 1450. Their capital was at Chan Chan outside of modern-day
Trujillo. The largest pre-Hispanic city in South America at the time,
Chan Chan had 100,000 inhabitants. Its twenty square kilometers of
precisely symmetrical design was surrounded by a lush garden oasis
intricately irrigated from the R�o Moche several kilometers away. The
Chim� civilization lasted a comparatively short period of time,
however. Like other coastal states, its irrigation system, watered from
sources in the high Andes, was apparently vulnerable to cutoff or
diversion by expanding highland polities.
In the highlands, both the Tiwanaku (Tiahuanaco) culture, near Lake
Titicaca in Bolivia, and the Wari (Huari) culture, near the present-day
city of Ayacucho, developed large urban settlements and wide-ranging
state systems between A.D. 500 and A.D. 1000. Each exhibited many of the
aspects of the engineering ingenuity that later appeared with the Incas,
such as extensive road systems, store houses, and architectural styles.
Between A.D. 1000 and 1450, however, a period of fragmentation shattered
the previous unity achieved by the Tiwanaku-Wari stage. During this
period, scores of different ethnic-based groups of varying sizes dotted
the Andean landscape. In the central and southern Andes, for example,
the Chupachos of Hu�nuco numbered some 10,000, while the Lupacas on the
west bank of Lake Titicaca comprised over 100,000.
Peru
Peru - The Incas
Peru
The Incas of Cusco (Cuzco) originally represented one of these small
and relatively minor ethnic groups, the Quechuas. Gradually, as early as
the thirteenth century, they began to expand and incorporate their
neighbors. Inca expansion was slow until about the middle of the
fifteenth century, when the pace of conquest began to accelerate,
particularly under the rule of the great emperor Pachacuti Inca Yupanqui
(1438-71). Historian John Hemming describes Pachacuti as "one of
those protean figures, like Alexander or Napoleon, who combine a mania
for conquest with the ability to impose his will on every facet of
government." Under his rule and that of his son, Topa Inca Yupanqui
(1471-93), the Incas came to control upwards of a third of South
America, with a population of 9 to 16 million inhabitants under their
rule. Pachacuti also promulgated a comprehensive code of laws to govern
his far-flung empire, called Tawantinsuyu, while consolidating his
absolute temporal and spiritual authority as the God of the Sun who
ruled from a magnificently rebuilt Cusco.
Although displaying distinctly hierarchical and despotic features,
Incan rule also exhibited an unusual measure of flexibility and
paternalism. The basic local unit of society was the ayllu, which formed an endogamous nucleus of kinship groups who
possessed collectively a specific, although often disconnected,
territory. In the ayllu, grazing land was held in common
(private property did not exist), whereas arable land was parceled out
to families in proportion to their size. Since self-sufficiency was the
ideal of Andean society, family units claimed parcels of land in
different ecological niches in the rugged Andean terrain. In this way,
they achieved what anthropologists have called "vertical
complementarity," that is, the ability to produce a wide variety of
crops--such as maize, potatoes, and quinoa (a protein-rich grain)--at
different altitudes for household consumption.
The principle of complementarity also applied to Andean social
relations, as each family head had the right to ask relations, allies,
or neighbors for help in cultivating his plot. In return, he was
obligated to offer them food and chicha (a fermented corn
alcoholic beverage), and to help them on their own plots when asked.
Mutual aid formed the ideological and material bedrock of all Andean
social and productive relations. This system of reciprocal exchange
existed at every level of Andean social organization: members of the ayllus,
curacas (local lords) with their subordinate ayllus,
and the Inca himself with all his subjects.
Ayllus often formed parts of larger dual organizations with
upper and lower divisions called moieties, and then still
larger units, until they comprised the entire ethnic group. As it
expanded, the Inca state became, historian Nathan Wachtel writes,
"the pinnacle of this immense structure of interlocking units. It
imposed a political and military apparatus on all of these ethnic
groups, while continuing to rely on the hierarchy of curacas,
who declared their loyalty to the Inca and ruled in his name." In
this sense, the Incas established a system of indirect rule that enabled
the incorporated ethnic groups to maintain their distinctiveness and
self-awareness within a larger imperial system.
All Inca people collectively worked the lands of the Inca, who served
as representative of the God of the Sun--the central god and religion of
the empire. In return, they received food, as well as chicha
and coca leaves (which were chewed and used for religious rites and for
medicinal purposes); or they made cloth and clothing for tribute, using
the Inca flocks; or they regularly performed mita, or service for public works, such as roads and
buildings, or for military purposes that enabled the development of the
state. The Inca people also maintained the royal family and bureaucracy,
centered in Cusco. In return for these services, the Inca allocated land
and redistributed part of the tribute received--such as food, cloth, and
clothes--to the communities, often in the form of welfare. Tribute was
stored in centrally located warehouses to be dispensed during periods of
shortages caused by famine, war, or natural disaster. In the absence of
a market economy, Inca redistribution of tribute served as the primary
means of exchange. The principles of reciprocity and redistribution,
then, formed the organizing ideas that governed all relations in the
Inca empire from community to state.
One of the more remarkable elements of the Inca empire was the mitmaq
system. Before the Incas, these were colonies of settlers sent out from
the ayllus to climatically different Andean terrains to
cultivate crops that would vary and enrich the community diet.
Anthropologist John V. Murra dubbed these unique Andean island colonies
"vertical archipelagos," which the Incas adapted and applied
on a large scale to carve out vast new areas of cultivation. The Incas
also expanded the original Andean concept of mitmaq as a
vehicle for developing complementary sources of food to craft
specialization and military expansion. In the latter instance, Inca mitmaq
were used to establish permanent garrisons to maintain control and order
on the expanding Inca frontier. What "began as a means of
complementing productive access to a variety of ecological tiers had
become," in the words of Murra, "an onerous means of political
control" under the Incas.
By the late fifteenth century and early sixteenth century, the Inca
Empire had reached its maximum size. Such powerful states as the coastal
Chim� Kingdom were defeated and incorporated into the empire, although
the Chim�s spoke a language, Yunga, that was entirely distinct from the
Incas' Quechua. But as the limits of the central Andean culture area
were reached in present-day Chile and Argentina, as well as in the
Amazon forests, the Incas encountered serious resistance, and those
territories were never thoroughly subjugated.
At the outset, the Incas shared with most of their ethnic neighbors
the same basic technology: weaving, pottery, metallurgy, architecture,
construction engineering, and irrigation agriculture. During their
period of dominance, little was added to this inventory of skills, other
than the size of the population they ruled and the degree and efficiency
of control they attained. The latter, however, constituted a rather
remarkable accomplishment, particularly because it was achieved without
benefit of either the wheel or a formal system of writing. Instead of
writing, the Incas used the intricate and highly accurate khipu
(knot-tying) system of recordkeeping . Imperial achievements were the
more extraordinary considering the relative brevity of the period during
which the empire was built (perhaps four generations) and the formidable
geographic obstacles of the Andean landscape.
Viewed from the present-day perspective of Peruvian underdevelopment,
one cannot help but admire a system that managed to bring under
cultivation four times the amount of arable land as today. Achievements
such as these caused some twentieth-century Peruvian scholars of the
indigenous peoples, known as indigenistas (Indigenists), such
as Hildebrando Castro Pozo and Luis Eduardo Valc�rcel, to idealize the
Inca past and to overlook the hierarchical nature and totalitarian
mechanisms of social and political control erected during their Incan
heyday. To other intellectuals, however, from Jos� Carlos Mari�tegui
to Luis Guillermo Lumbreras, the path to development has continued to
call for some sort of return to the country's pre-Columbian past of
communal values, autochthonous technology, and genius for production and
organization.
By the time that the Spaniards arrived in 1532, the empire extended
some 1,860 kilometers along the Andean spine--north to southern Colombia
and south to northern Chile, between the Pacific Ocean in the west and
the Amazonian rain forest in the east. Some five years before the
Spanish invasion, this vast empire was rocked by a civil war that,
combined with diseases imported by the Spaniards, would ultimately
weaken its ability to confront the European invaders. The premature
death by measles of the reigning Sapa Inca, Huayna C�pac (1493-1524),
opened the way for a dynastic struggle between the emperor's two sons,
Hu�scar (from Cusco) and the illegitimate Atahualpa (from Quito), who
each had inherited half the empire. After a five-year civil war
(1528-32), Atahualpa (1532-33) emerged victorious and is said to have
tortured and put to death more than 300 members of Hu�scar's family.
This divisive and debilitating internecine conflict left the Incas
particularly vulnerable just as Francisco Pizarro and his small force of
adventurers came marching up into the Sierra.
Peru
Peru - Pizarro and the Conquistadors
Peru
While the Inca empire flourished, Spain was beginning to rise to
prominence in the Western world. The political union of the several
independent realms in the Iberian Peninsula and the final expulsion of
the Moors after 700 years of intermittent warfare had instilled in
Spaniards a sense of destiny and a militant religious zeal. The
encounter with the New World by Crist�bal Col�n (Christopher Columbus)
in 1492 offered an outlet for the material, military, and religious
ambitions of the newly united nation.
Francisco Pizarro, a hollow-cheeked, thinly beared Extremaduran of
modest hidalgo (lesser nobility) birth, was not only typical of the
arriviste Spanish conquistadors who came to America, but also one of the
most spectacularly successful. Having participated in the indigenous
wars and slave raids on Hispa�iola, Spain's first outpost in the New
World, the tough, shrewd, and audacious Spaniard was with Vasco Nu�ez
de Balboa when he first glimpsed the Pacific Ocean in 1513 and was a
leader in the conquest of Nicaragua (1522). He later found his way to
Panama, where he became a wealthy encomendero and leading citizen. Beginning in 1524, Pizarro proceeded
to mount several expeditions, financed mainly from his own capital, from
Panama south along the west coast of South America.
After several failures, Pizarro arrived in northern Peru late in 1531
with a small force of about 180 men and 30 horses. The conquistadors
were excited by tales of the Incas' great wealth and bent on repeating
the pattern of conquest and plunder that was becoming practically
routine elsewhere in the New World. The Incas never seemed to appreciate
the threat they faced. To them, of course, the Spaniards seemed the
exotics. "To our Indian eyes," wrote Felipe Guam�n Poma de
Ayala, the author of Nueva cr�nica y buen gobierno (New
Chronicle and Good Government), "the Spaniards looked as if they
were shrouded like corpses. Their faces were covered with wool, leaving
only the eyes visible, and the caps which they wore resembled little red
pots on top of their heads."
On November 15, 1532, Pizarro arrived in Cajamarca, the Inca's summer
residence located in the Andean highlands of northern Peru, and insisted
on an audience with Atahualpa. Guam�n Poma says the Spaniards demanded
that the Inca renounce his gods and accept a treaty with Spain. He
refused. "The Spaniards began to fire their muskets and charged
upon the Indians, killing them like ants. At the sound of the explosions
and the jingle of bells on the horses' harnesses, the shock of arms and
the whole amazing novelty of their attackers' appearance, the Indians
were terrorstricken . They were desperate to escape from being trampled
by the horses, and in their headlong flight a lot of them were crushed
to death." Guam�n Poma adds that countless "Indians" but
only five Spaniards were killed, "and these few casualties were not
caused by the Indians, who had at no time dared to attack the formidable
strangers." According to other accounts, the only Spanish casualty
was Pizarro, who received a hand wound while trying to protect
Atahualpa.
Pizarro's overwhelming victory at Cajamarca in which he not only
captured Atahualpa, but devastated the Inca's army, estimated at between
5,000 and 6,000 warriors, dealt a paralyzing and demoralizing blow to
the empire, already weakened by civil war. The superior military
technology of the Spaniards--cavalry, cannon, and above all Toledo
steel--had proved unbeatable against a force, however large, armed only
with stone-age battle axes, slings, and cotton-padded armor. Atahualpa's
capture not only deprived the empire of leadership at a crucial moment,
but the hopes of his recently defeated opponents, the supporters of Hu�scar,
were revived by the prospect of an alliance with a powerful new Andean
power contender, the Spaniards.
Atahualpa now sought to gain his freedom by offering the Spaniards a
treasure in gold and silver. Over the next few months, a fabulous cache
of Incan treasure--some eleven tons of gold objects alone--was delivered
to Cajamarca from all corners of the empire. Pizarro distributed the
loot to his "men of Cajamarca," creating instant
"millionaires," but also slighting Diego de Almagro, his
partner who arrived later with reinforcements. This sowed the seeds for
a bitter factional dispute that soon would throw Peru into a bloody
civil war and cost both men their lives. Once enriched by the Incas'
gold, Pizarro, seeing no further use for Atahualpa, reneged on his
agreement and executed the Inca--by garroting rather than hanging--after
Atahualpa agreed to be baptized as a Christian.
Peru
Peru - Consolidation of Control
Peru
With Atahualpa dead, the Spaniards proceeded to march on Cusco. On
the way, they dealt another decisive blow, aided by native American
allies from the pro-Hu�scar faction, to the still formidable remnants
of Atahualpa's army. Then on November 15, 1533, exactly a year after
arriving at Cajamarca, Pizarro, reinforced with an army of 5,000 native
American auxiliaries, captured the imperial city and placed Manco C�pac
II, kin of Hu�scar and his faction, on the Inca throne as a Spanish
puppet.
Further consolidation of Spanish power in Peru, however, was slowed
during the next few years by both indigenous resistance and internal
divisions among the victorious Spaniards. The native population, even
those who had allied initially with the invaders against the Incas, had
second thoughts about the arrival of the newcomers. They originally
believed that the Spaniards simply represented one more in a long line
of Andean power-contenders with whom to ally or accommodate. The
continuing violent and rapacious behavior of many Spaniards, however, as
well as the harsh overall effects of the new colonial order, caused many
to alter this assessment. This change led Manco C�pac II to balk at his
subservient role as a Spanish puppet and to rise in rebellion in 1536.
Ultimately unable to defeat the Spaniards, Manco retreated to Vilcabamba
in the remote Andean interior where he established an independent Inca
kingdom, replete with a miniature royal court, that held out until 1572.
Native American resistance took another form during the 1560s with
the millenarian religious revival in Huamanga known as Taki Onqoy
(literally "dancing sickness"), which preached the total
rejection of Spanish religion and customs. Converts to the sect
expressed their conversion and spiritual rebirth by a sudden seizure in
which they would shake and dance uncontrollably, often falling and
writhing on the ground. The leaders of Taki Onqoy claimed that they were
messengers from the native gods and preached that a pan-Andean alliance
of native gods would destroy the Christians by unleashing disease and
other calamities against them. An adherent to the sect declared at an
official inquiry in 1564 that "the world has turned about, and this
time God and the Spaniards [will be] defeated and all the Spaniards
killed and their cities drowned; and the sea will rise and overwhelm
them, so that there will remain no memory of them."
To further complicate matters for the conquerors, a fierce dispute
broke out among the followers of Pizarro and those of Diego de Almagro.
Having fallen out over the original division of spoils at Cajamarca,
Almagro and his followers challenged Pizarro's control of Cusco after
returning from an abortive conquest expedition to Chile in 1537.
Captured by Pizarro's forces at the Battle of Salinas in 1538, Almagro
was executed, but his supporters, who continued to plot under his son,
Diego, gained a measure of revenge by assassinating Pizarro in 1541.
As the civil turmoil continued, the Spanish crown intervened to try
to bring the dispute to an end, but in the process touched off a
dangerous revolt among the colonists by decreeing the end of the encomienda
system in 1542. The encomienda was a much abused
prerogative to extract labor and tribute from the indigenous peoples in
return for the responsibility to protect and Christianize them. It had
originally been granted as a reward to the conquistadors and their
families during the conquest and ensuing colonization, and was regarded
as sacrosanct by the grantees, or encomenderos, who numbered
about 500 out of a total Spanish population of 2,000 in 1536. However,
to the crown it raised the specter of a potentially privileged,
neofeudal elite emerging in the Andes to challenge crown authority.
The crown's efforts to enforce the New Laws (Nuevos Leyes) of 1542
alienated the colonists, who rallied around the figure of Gonzalo
Pizarro, the late Francisco's brother. Gonzalo managed to kill the
intemperate Viceroy Don Blasco N��ez de la Vela, who, on his arrival,
had foolishly tried to enforce the New Laws. In 1544 Pizarro assumed de
facto authority over Peru. His arbitrary and brutal rule, however,
caused opposition among the colonists, so that when another royal
representative, Pedro de la Gasca, arrived in Peru to restore crown
authority, he succeeded in organizing a pro-royalist force that defeated
and executed Pizarro in 1548. With Gonzalo's death, the crown finally
succeeded, despite subsequent intermittent revolts, in ending the civil
war and exerting crown control over Spanish Peru.
It would take another two decades, however, to finally quell native
American resistance. Sensing the danger of the Taki Onqoy heresy, the
Spanish authorities moved quickly and energetically, through a
church-sponsored anti-idolatry campaign, to suppress it before it had a
chance to spread. Its leaders were seized, beaten, fined, or expelled
from their communities. At the same time, a new campaign was mounted
against the last Inca holdout at Vilcabamba, which was finally captured
in 1572. With it, the last reigning Inca, T�pac Amaru, was tried and
beheaded by the Spaniards in a public ceremony in Cusco, thereby putting
an end to the events of the conquest that had begun so dramatically four
decades earlier at Cajamarca.
Peru
Peru - THE COLONIAL PERIOD
Peru
Demographic Collapse
Throughout the Americas, the impact of the Spanish conquest and
subsequent colonization was to bring about a cataclysmic demographic
collapse of the indigenous population. The Andes would be no exception.
Even before the appearance of Francisco Pizarro on the Peruvian coast,
the lethal diseases that had been introduced into the Americas with the
arrival of the Spaniards-- smallpox, malaria, measles, typhus,
influenza, and even the common cold--had spread to South America and
begun to wreak havoc throughout Tawantinsuyu. Indeed, the death of
Huayna C�pac and his legitimate son and heir, Ninan Cuyoche, which
touched off the disastrous dynastic struggles between Hu�scar and
Atahualpa, is believed to have been the result of a smallpox or measles
epidemic that struck in 1530-31.
With an estimated population of 9 to 16 million people prior to the
arrival of the Europeans, Peru's population forty years later was
reduced on average by about 80 percent, generally higher on the coast
than in the highlands. The chronicler Pedro de Cieza de Leon, who traveled
over much of Peru during this period, was particularly struck by the
extent of the depopulation along the coast. "The inhabitants of
this valley [Chincha, south of Lima]," he wrote, "were so
numerous that many Spaniards say that when it was conquered by the
Marquis [Pizarro] and themselves, there were ... more than 25,000 men,
and I doubt that there are now 5,000, so many have been the inroads and
hardships they have suffered." Demographic anthropologists Henry F.
Dobyns and Paul L. Doughty have estimated that the native American
population fell to about 8.3 million by 1548 and to around 2.7 million
in 1570. Unlike Mexico, where the population stabilized at the end of
the seventeenth century, it did not reach its nadir in Peru until the
latter part of the eighteenth century, after the great epidemic of 1719.
War, exploitation, socioeconomic change, and the generalized
psychological trauma of conquest all combined to reinforce the main
contributor to the demise of the native peoples--epidemic disease.
Isolated from the old world for millennia and therefore lacking
immunities, the Andean peoples were defenseless to the introduction of
the deadly viruses by the Europeans. Numerous killer pandemics swept
down from the north, laying waste to entire communities. Occurring one
after the other in roughly tenyear intervals during the sixteenth
century (1525, 1546, 1558-59, 1585), these epidemics did not allow the
population time to recover, while impairing its ability to reproduce
itself.
Peru
Peru - The Colonial Economy
Peru
With the discovery of the great silver lodes at Potos� in Per� Alto
(Upper Peru--present-day Bolivia) in 1545 and mercury at Huancavelica in
1563, Peru became what historian Frederick B. Pike describes as
"Spain's great treasure house in South America." As a result,
the axis of the colonial economy began to move away from the direct
expropriation of Incan wealth and production to sustain the initial
Spanish population through the encomienda system to the
extraction of mineral wealth. The population at Potos� in the high
Andes reached its apogee in 1650 at about 160,000, making it one of the
largest cities in the Western world at the time. In its first ten years,
according to Alexander von Humboldt, Potos� produced some 127 million
pesos, which fueled for a time the Habsburg war machine and Spanish
hegemonic political pretensions in Europe. Silver from Potos� also
dynamized and helped to develop an internal economy of production and
exchange that encompassed not only the northern highlands, but also the
Argentine pampa, the Central Valley of Chile, and coastal Peru and
Ecuador. The main "growth pole" of this vast "economic
space," as historian Carlos Assadourian Sempat calls it, was the
Lima-Potos� axis, which served as centers of urban concentration,
market demand, strategic commodity flows (silver exports and European
imports), and inflated prices.
If Potos� silver production was the mainspring of this economic
system, Lima was its hub. "The city of the Kings" (Los Reyes)
had been founded by Pizarro as the capital of the new viceroyalty in
1535 in order to reorient trade, commerce, and power away from the Andes
toward imperial Spain and Europe. As the outlet for silver bullion on
the Pacific, Lima and its nearby port, Callao, also received and
redistributed the manufactured goods from the metropolis for the growing
settlements along the growth pole. The two-way flow of imports and
exports through Lima concentrated both wealth and administration, public
and private, in the city. As a result, Lima became the headquarters for
estate owners and operators, merchants connecting their Andean trading
operations with sources of supply in Spain, and all types of service
providers, from artisans to lawyers, who needed access to the system in
a central place. Not far behind came the governmental and church
organizations established to administer the vast viceroyalty. Finally,
once population, commerce, and administration interacted, major cultural
institutions such as a university, a printing press, and theater
followed suit.
The great architect of this colonial system was Francisco Toledo y
Figueroa, who arrived in Lima in 1569, when its population was 2,500,
and served as viceroy until 1581. Toledo, one of Madrid's ablest administrators and
diplomats, worked to expand the state, increase silver production, and
generally reorganize the economy by instituting a series of major
reforms during his tenure.
Native communities (ayllus) were concentrated into poorly
located colonial settlements called (
reducciones) to facilitate administration
and the conversion of the native Americans to Christianity. The Incaic mita
system was shifted from performing public works or military service to
supplying compulsory labor for the mines and other key sectors of the
economy and state. Finally, various fiscal schemes, such as the tribute
tax to be paid in coin and the forced purchase of Spanish merchandise,
were levied on the indigenous population in order to force or otherwise
induce it into the new monetary economy as "free wage"
workers. In these, as in many other instances, the Spaniards used
whatever elements of the Andean political, social, and economic
superstructure that served their purposes and unhesitatingly modified or
discarded those that did not.
As a result of these and other changes, the Spaniards and their
creole successors came to monopolize control over the land, seizing many
of the best lands abandoned by the massive native depopulation.
Gradually, the land tenure system became polarized. One sector consisted
of the large haciendas, worked by native peasant serfs in a variety of
labor arrangements and governed by their new overlords according to
hybrid Andean forms of Iberian paternalism. The other sector was made up
of remnants of the essentially subsistence-based indigenous communities
that persisted and endured. This left Peru with a legacy of one of the
most unequal landholding arrangements in all of Latin America and a
formidable obstacle to later development and modernization.
Peru
Peru - Colonial Administration
Peru
The expansion of a colonial administrative apparatus and bureaucracy
paralleled the economic reorganization. The viceroyalty was divided into
audiences (
audiencias), which were further subdivided
into provinces or districts (
corregimientos) and finally municipalities,
which included a city or town, governed by town councils cabildos), composed of the most prominent citizens, mostly encomenderos
in the early years and later hacendados.
The most important royal official was the viceroy, who had a host of
responsibilities ranging from general administration (particularly tax
collection and construction of public works) and internal and external
defense to support of the church and protection of the native
population. He was surrounded by a number of other judicial,
ecclesiastical, and treasury officials, who also reported to the Council
of the Indies, the main governing body located in Spain. This
configuration of royal officials, along with an official review of his
tenure called the residencia, served as a check on viceregal power.
In the early years of the conquest, the crown was particularly
concerned with preventing the conquistadors or encomenderos
from establishing themselves as a feudal aristocracy capable of
thwarting royal interests. Therefore, it moved quickly to quell the
civil disturbances that had racked Peru immediately after the conquest
and to decree the New Laws of 1542, which deprived the encomenderos
and their heirs of their rights to native American goods and services.
The early administrative functions of the encomenderos over
the indigenous population (protection and Christianization) were taken
over by new state-appointed officials called correqidores
de indios (governors of Indians). They were
charged at the provincial level with the administration of justice,
control of commercial relations between native Americans and Spaniards,
and the collection of the tribute tax. The corregidores
(Spanish magistrates) were assisted by curacas, members of the
native elite, who had been used by the conquerors from the very
beginning as mediators between the native population and the Europeans.
Over time the corregidores used their office to accumulate
wealth and power to dominate rural society, establishing mutual
alliances with local and regional elites such as the curacas,
native American functionaries, municipal officials, rural priests (doctrineros),
landowners, merchants, miners, and others, as well as native and mestizo
subordinates.
As the crown's political authority was consolidated in the second
half of the sixteenth century, so too was its ability to regulate and
control the colonial economy. Operating according to the mercantilistic
strictures of the times, the crown sought to maximize investment in
valuable export production, such as silver and later other mineral and
agricultural commodities, while supplying the new colonial market with
manufactured imports, so as to create a favorable balance of trade for
the metropolis. However, the tightly regulated trading monopoly,
headquartered in Seville, was not always able to provision the colonies
effectively. Assadorian shows that most urban and mining demand,
particularly among the laboring population, was met by internal Andean
production (rough-hewn clothing, foodstuffs, yerba mate tea, chicha
beer, and the like) from haciendas, indigenous communities, and textile
factories (
obrajes). According to him, the value of
these Andean products amounted to fully 60 to 70 percent of the value of
silver exports and elite imports linking Peru and Europe. In any case,
the crown was successful in managing the colonial export economy through
the development of a bureaucratic and interventionist state,
characterized by a plethora of mercantilistic rules that regulated the
conduct of business and commerce. In doing so, Spain left both a
mercantilist and export-oriented pattern and legacy of
"development" in the Andes that has survived up to the present
day, and which remains a problem of contemporary underdevelopment.
Peru
Peru - The Colonial Church
Peru
The crown, as elsewhere in the Americas, worked to solidify the
Andean colonial order in tandem with the church to which it was tied by
royal patronage dating from the late fifteenth century. Having
accompanied Francisco Pizarro and his force during the conquest, the
Roman Catholic friars proceeded zealously to carry out their mission to
convert the indigenous peoples to Christianity. In this endeavor, the
church came to play an important role in the acculturation of the
natives, drawing them into the cultural orbit of the Spanish settlers.
It also waged a constant war to extirpate native religious beliefs. Such
efforts met with only partial success, as the syncretic nature of Andean
Roman Catholicism today attests. With time, however, the evangelical
mission of the church gave way to its regular ecclesiastical endeavors
of ministering to the growing Spanish and creole population.
By the end of the century, the church was beginning to acquire
important financial assets, particularly bequests of land and other
wealth, that would consolidate its position as the most important
economic power during the colonial period. At the same time, it assumed
the primary role of educator, welfare provider, and, through the
institution of the Inquisition, guardian of orthodoxy throughout the
viceroyalty. Together, the church-state partnership served to
consolidate and solidify the crown authority in Peru that, despite
awesome problems of distance, rough terrain, and slow communications,
endured almost three centuries of continuous and relatively stable rule.
Silver production, meanwhile, began to enter into a prolonged period
of decline in the seventeenth century. This decline also slowed the
important transatlantic trade while diminishing the importance of Lima
as the economic hub of the viceregal economy. Annual silver output at
Potos�, for example, fell in value from a little over 7 million pesos
in 1600 to almost 4.5 million pesos in 1650 and finally to just under 2
million pesos in 1700. Falling silver production, the declining
transatlantic trade, and the overall decline of Spain itself during the
seventeenth century have long been interpreted by historians as causing
a prolonged depression both in the viceroyalties of Peru and New Spain.
However, economic historian Kenneth J. Andrien has challenged this view,
maintaining that the Peruvian economy, rather than declining, underwent
a major transition and restructuring. After silver production and the
transatlantic trade eroded the export economy, they were replaced by
more diversified, regionalized, and autonomous development of the
agricultural and manufacturing sectors. Merchants, miners, and producers
simply shifted their investments and entrepreneurial activities away
from mining and the transatlantic trade into internal production and
import-substituting opportunities, a trend already visible on a small
scale by the end of the previous century. The result was a surprising
degree of regional diversification that stabilized the viceregal economy
during the seventeenth century.
This economic diversification was marked by the rise and expansion of
the great estates or haciendas that were carved out of abandoned native
land as a result of the demographic collapse. The precipitous decline of
the native population was particularly severe along the coast and had
the effect of opening up the fertile bottom lands of the river valleys
to Spanish immigrants eager for land and farming opportunities. A
variety of crops were raised: sugar and cotton along the northern coast;
wheat and grains in the central valleys; grapes, olives, and sugar along
the entire coast. The highlands, depending on geographic and climatic
conditions, underwent a similar hacienda expansion and diversification
of production. There, coca, potatoes, livestock, and other indigenous
products were raised in addition to some coastal crops, such as sugar
and cereals.
This transition toward internal diversification in the colony also
included early manufacturing, although not to the extent of agrarian
production. Textile manufacturing flourished in Cusco, Cajamarca, and
Quito to meet popular demand for rough-hewn cotton and woolen garments.
A growing intercolonial trade along the Pacific Coast involved the
exchange of Peruvian and Mexican silver for oriental silks and
porcelain. In addition, <"http://worldfacts.us/Peru-Arequipa.htm"> Arequipa and then Nazca and Ica became known for
the production of fine wines and brandies. And throughout the
viceroyalty, small-scale artisan industries supplied a range of
lower-cost goods only sporadically available from Spain and Europe,
which were now mired in the seventeenth-century depression.
If economic regionalization and diversification worked to stabilize
the colonial economy during the seventeenth century, the benefits of
such a trend did not, as it turned out, accrue to Madrid. The crown had
derived enormous revenues from silver production and the transatlantic
trade, which it was able to tax and collect relatively easily. The
decline in silver production caused a precipitous fall in crown revenue,
particularly in the second half of the seventeenth century. For example,
revenue remittances to Spain dropped from an annual average of almost
1.5 million pesos in the 1630s to less than 128,000 pesos by the 1680s.
The crown tried to restructure the tax system to conform to the new
economic realities of seventeenth-century colonial production but was
rebuffed by the recalcitrance of emerging local elites. They tenaciously
resisted any new local levies on their production, while building
alliances of mutual convenience and gain with local crown officials to
defend their vested interests.
The situation further deteriorated, from the perspective of Spain,
when Madrid began in 1633 to sell royal offices to the highest bidder,
enabling self-interested creoles to penetrate and weaken the royal
bureaucracy. The upshot was not only a sharp decline in vital crown
revenues from Peru during the century, which further contributed to the
decline of Spain itself, but an increasing loss of royal control over
local creole oligarchies throughout the viceroyalty. Lamentably, the
sale of public offices also had longer-term implications. The practice
weakened any notion of disinterested public service and infused into the
political culture the corrosive idea that office-holding was an
opportunity for selfish, private gain rather than for the general public
good.
If the economy of the viceroyalty reached a certain steady state
during the seventeenth century, its population continued to decline.
Estimated at around 3 million in 1650, the population of the viceroyalty
finally reached its nadir at a little over 1 million inhabitants in
1798. It rose sharply to almost 2.5 million inhabitants by 1825. The
1792 census indicated an ethnic composition of 13 percent Spaniards, 56
percent native American, and 27 percent castas (mestizos), the
latter category the fastest-growing group because of both acculturation
and miscegenation between Spaniards and natives.
Demographic expansion and the revival of silver production, which had
fallen sharply at the end of the seventeenth century, promoted a period
of gradual economic growth from 1730 to 1770. The pace of growth then
picked up in the last quarter of the eighteenth century, partly as a
result of the so-called Bourbon reforms of 1764, named after a branch of
the ruling French Bourbon family that ascended to the Spanish throne
after the death of the last Habsburg in 1700.
In the second half of the eighteenth century, particularly during the
reign of Charles III (1759-1788), Spain turned its reform efforts to
Spanish America in a concerted effort to increase the revenue flow from
its American empire. The aims of the program were to centralize and
improve the structure of government, to create more efficient economic
and financial machinery, and to defend the empire from foreign powers.
For Peru, perhaps the most far-reaching change was the creation of a new
viceroyalty in the R�o de la Plata (River Plate) region in 1776 that
radically altered the geopolitical and economic balance in South
America. Upper Peru was detached administratively from the old
Viceroyalty of Peru, so that profits from Potos� no longer flowed to
Lima and Lower Peru, but to Buenos Aires. With the rupture of the old
Lima-Potos� circuit, Lima suffered an inevitable decline in prosperity
and prestige, as did the southern highlands (Cusco, Arequipa, and Puno).
The viceregal capital's status declined further from the general
measures to introduce free trade within the empire. These measures
stimulated the economic development of peripheral areas in northern
South America (Venezuela) and southern South America (Argentina), ending
Lima's former monopoly of South American trade.
As a result of these and other changes, the economic axis of Peru
shifted northward to the central and northern Sierra and central coast.
These areas benefited from the development of silver mining,
particularly at Cerro de Pasco, which was spurred by a series of
measures taken by the Bourbons to modernize and revitalize the industry.
However, declining trade and production in the south, together with a
rising tax burden levied by the Bourbon state, which fell heavily on the
native peasantry, set the stage for the massive native American revolt
that erupted with the T�pac Amaru rebellion in 1780-82.
Peru
Peru - Indigenous Rebellions
Peru
An upsurge in native discontent and rebellion had actually begun to
occur in the eighteenth century. To survive their brutal subjugation,
the indigenous peoples had early on adopted a variety of strategies but
were never as passive as portrayed in the scholarly literature until
recently. To endure, the native Americans did indeed have to adapt to
Spanish domination. As often as not, however, they found ways of
asserting their own interests.
After the conquest, the crown had assumed from the Incas patrimony
over all native land, which it granted in usufruct to indigenous
community families, in exchange for tribute payments and mita
labor services. This system became the basis for a long-lasting alliance
between the colonial state and the native communities, bolstered over
the years by the elaboration of a large body of protective legislation.
Crown officials, such as the corregidores de indios, were
charged with the responsibility of protecting natives from abuse at the
hands of the colonists, particularly the alienation of their land to
private landholders. Nevertheless, the colonists and their native
allies, the curacas, often in collusion with the corregidores
and local priests, found ways of circumventing crown laws and gaining
control of native American lands and labor. To counter such exploitation
and to conserve their historical rights to the land, many native
American leaders shrewdly resorted to the legal system. Litigation did
not always suffice, of course, and Andean history is full of desperate
native peasant rebellions.
The pace of these uprisings increased dramatically in the eighteenth
century, with five in the 1740s, eleven in the 1750s, twenty in the
1760s, and twenty in the 1770s. Their underlying causes were largely
economic. Land was becoming increasingly scarce in the communities
because of illegal purchases by unscrupulous colonists at a time when
the indigenous population was once again growing after the long,
postconquest demographic decline. At the same time, the native peasantry
felt the brunt of higher taxes levied by the crown, part of the general
reform program initiated by Madrid in the second half of the eighteenth
century. These increased tax burdens came at a time when the highland
elite--corregidores, priests, curacas, and
Hispanicized native landholders--was itself increasing the level of
surplus extracted from the native American peasant economy. According to
historian Nils P. Jacobsen, this apparent tightening of the colonial
"screw" during the eighteenth century led to the
"over-exploitation" of the native peasantry and the ensuing
decades of indigenous rebellions.
The culmination of this protest came in 1780 when Jos� Gabriel
Condorcanqui, a wealthy curaca and mestizo descendant of Inca
ancestors who sympathized with the oppressed native peasantry, seized
and executed a notoriously abusive corregidor near Cusco.
Condorcanqui raised a ragtag army of tens of thousands of natives, castas,
and even a few dissident creoles, assuming the name T�pac Amaru II
after the last Inca, to whom he was related. Drawing on a rising tide of
Andean millenarianism and nativism, T�pac Amaru II raised the specter
of some kind of return to a mythic Incaic past among the indigenous
masses at a time of increased economic hardship.
Captured by royalist forces in 1781, Condorcanqui was brought to
trial and, like his namesake, cruelly executed, along with several
relatives, in the main plaza in Cusco, as a warning to others. The
rebellion continued, however, and even expanded into the Altiplano
around Lake Titicaca under the leadership of his brother, Diego Crist�bal
T�pac Amaru. It was finally suppressed in 1782, and in the following
years the authorities undertook to carry out some of the reforms that
the two native leaders had advocated.
Peru
Peru - INDEPENDENCE IMPOSED FROM WITHOUT
Peru
Despite the T�pac Amaru revolts, independence was slow to develop in
the Viceroyalty of Peru. For one thing, Peru was a conservative,
royalist stronghold where the potentially restless creole elites
maintained a relatively privileged, if dependent, position in the old
colonial system. At the same time, the "anti-white"
manifestations of the T�pac Amaru revolt demonstrated that the
indigenous masses could not easily be mobilized without posing a threat
to the creole caste itself. Thus, when independence finally did come in
1824, it was largely a foreign imposition rather than a truly popular,
indigenous, and nationalist movement. As historian David P. Werlich has
aptly put it, "Peru's role in the drama of Latin American
independence was largely that of an interested spectator until the final
act."
What the spectator witnessed prior to 1820 was a civil war in the
Americas that pitted dissident creole elites in favor of independence
against royalists loyal to the crown and the old colonial order. The
movement had erupted in reaction to Napoleon Bonaparte's invasion of
Spain in 1808, which deposed Ferdinand VII and placed a usurper, Joseph
Bonaparte, on the Spanish throne. In America this raised the question of
the very political legitimacy of the colonial government. When juntas
arose in favor of the captive Ferdinand in various South American
capitals (except in Peru) the following year, even though of relatively
short duration, they touched off a process toward eventual separation
that ebbed and flowed throughout the continent over the next fifteen
years. This process developed its greatest momentum at the periphery of
Spanish power in South America--in what became Venezuela and Colombia in
the north and the R�o de la Plata region, particularly Argentina, in
the south.
Not until both movements converged in Peru during the latter phases
of the revolt, specifically the 4,500-man expeditionary force led by
General Jos� de San Mart�n that landed in Pisco in September 1820, was
Spanish control of Peru seriously threatened. San Mart�n, the son of a
Spanish army officer stationed in Argentina, had originally served in
the Spanish army but returned to his native Argentina to join the
rebellion. Once Argentine independence was achieved in 1814, San Mart�n
conceived of the idea of liberating Peru by way of Chile. As commander
of the 5,500-man Army of the Andes, half of which was composed of former
black slaves, San Mart�n, in a spectacular military operation, crossed
the Andes and liberated Chile in 1817. Three years later, his somewhat
smaller army left Valpara�so for Peru in a fleet commanded by a former
British admiral, Thomas Alexander Cochrane (Lord Dundonald).
Although some isolated stirrings for independence had manifested
themselves earlier in Peru, San Mart�n's invasion persuaded the
conservative creole intendant of Trujillo, Jos� Bernardo de Tagle y
Portocarrero, that Peru's liberation was at hand and that he should
proclaim independence. It was symptomatic of the conservative nature of
the viceroyalty that the internal forces now declaring for independence
were led by a leading creole aristocrat, the fourth marquis of Torre
Tagle, whose monarchist sympathies for any future political order
coincided with those of the Argentine liberator.
The defeat of the last bastion of royal power on the continent,
however, proved a slow and arduous task. Although a number of other
coastal cities quickly embraced the liberating army, San Mart�n was
able to take Lima in July 1821 only when the viceroy decided to withdraw
his considerable force to the Sierra, where he believed he could better
make a stand. Shortly thereafter, on July 28, 1821, San Mart�n
proclaimed Peru independent and then was named protector by an assembly
of notables. However, a number of problems, not the least of which was a
growing Peruvian resentment over the heavy-handed rule of the foreigner
they dubbed "King Jos�," stalled the campaign to defeat the
royalists. As a result, San Mart�n decided to seek aid from Sim�n Bol�var
Palacios, who had liberated much of northern South America from Spanish
power.
The two liberators met in a historic meeting in Guayaquil in mid-1822
to arrange the terms of a joint effort to complete the liberation of
Peru. Bol�var refused to agree to a shared partnership in the Peruvian
campaign, however, so a frustrated San Mart�n chose to resign his
command and leave Peru for Chile and eventual exile in France. With
significant help from San Mart�n's forces, Bol�var then proceeded to
invade Peru, where he won the Battle of Jun�n in August 1824. But it
remained for his trusted lieutenant, thirty-one-year-old General Antonio
Jos� de Sucre Alcal�, to complete the task of Peruvian independence by
defeating royalist forces at the hacienda of Ayacucho near Huamanga (a
city later renamed Ayacucho) on December 9, 1824. This battle in the
remote southern highlands effectively ended the long era of Spanish
colonial rule in South America.
INSTABILITY AFTER
INDEPENDENCE
Peru's transition from more than three centuries of colonial rule to
nominal independence in 1824 under President Bol�var (1824-26) proved
torturous and politically destablizing. Independence did little to alter
the fundamental structures of inequality and underdevelopment based on
colonialism and Andean neofeudalism. Essentially, independence
represented the transfer of power from the Spanish mainlanders (peninsulares)
to sectors of the elite creole class, whose aim was to preserve and
enhance their privileged socioeconomic status. However, the new creole
elite was unable to create a stable, new constitutional order to replace
the crown monolith of church and state. Nor was it willing to
restructure the social order in a way conducive to building a viable
democratic, republican government. Ultimately, the problem was one of
replacing the legitimacy of the old order with an entirely new one,
something that many postcolonial regimes have had difficulty
accomplishing.
Into the political vacuum left by the collapse of Spanish rule surged
a particularly virulent form of Andean caudillismo. Caudillo strongmen,
often officers from the liberation armies, managed to seize power
through force of arms and the elaboration of extensive and intricate
clientelistic alliances. Personalistic, arbitrary rule replaced the rule
of law, while a prolonged and often byzantine struggle for power was
waged at all levels of society. The upshot was internal political
fragmentation and chronic political instability during the first two
decades of the postindependence era. By one count, the country
experienced at least twenty-four regime changes, averaging one per year
between 1821 and 1845, and the constitution was rewritten six times.
This is not to say that larger political issues did not inform these
conflicts. A revisionist study by historian Paul E. Gootenberg shows in
great detail how the politics of trade (free or protectionist) and
regionalism were central to the internecine caudillo struggles of the
period. In this interpretation, nationalist elites--backing one caudillo
or another--managed to outmaneuver and defeat liberal groups to maintain
a largely protectionist, neomercantilistic, postcolonial regime until
the advent of the guano boom at mid-century. This view stands in
opposition to the dominant interpretation of the period, according to
which unrestricted liberalism and free trade led to Peru's
"dependency" on the international economy and the West.
However bewildering, the chaotic era of the caudillo can be divided
into several distinct periods. In the first, Bol�var tried,
unsuccessfully, to impose a centralist and utopian liberal government
from Lima. When events in Colombia caused him to relinquish power and
return to Bogot� in 1826, his departure left an immediate vacuum that
numerous Peruvian strongmen would try to fill. One of the most
successful in terms of tenure was the conservative General Agust�n
Gamarra (1829-34) from Cusco, who managed to crush numerous rebellions
and maintain power for five years. Then full-scale civil wars carried
first General Luis de Orbegoso (1834-35) and then General Felipe
Salaverry (1835-36) into the presidential palace for short terms. The
power struggles reached such a chaotic state by the mid-1830s that
General Andr�s de Santa Cruz y Calahumana marched into Peru from
Bolivia to impose the Peru-Bolivia Confederation of 1836-39. This
alliance upset the regional balance of power and caused Chile to raise
an army to defeat Santa Cruz and restore the status quo ante, which, in
effect, meant a resumption of factional conflict lasting well into the
1840s.
The descent into chronic political instability, coming immediately
after the destructive wars for independence (1820- 24), accelerated
Peru's general postindependence economic decline. During the 1820s,
silver mining, the country's traditional engine of growth, collapsed,
while massive capital flight resulted in large external deficits. By the
early 1830s, the silver-mining industry began to recover, briefly
climbing back to colonial levels of output in the early 1840s. Economic
recovery was further enhanced in the 1840s as southern Peru began to
export large quantities of wool, nitrates, and, increasingly, guano.
On the other hand, the large-scale importation of British textiles
after independence virtually destroyed the production of native artisans
and obrajes, which were unable to compete with their more
technologically advanced and cost-efficient overseas competitors. For
the most part, however, the economy continued in the immediate decades
after independence to be characterized by a low level of marketable
surplus from largely self-sufficient haciendas and native communities.
The expansion of exports during the 1840s did help, finally, to
stabilize the Peruvian state, particularly under the statesmanlike, if
autocratic, leadership of General Marshal Ram�n Castilla (1845-51,
1855-62). Castilla's rise to power, coming as it did at the onset of the
guano boom, marked the beginning of an age of unparalleled economic
growth and increasing political stability that effectively ended the
country's postindependence decline. Indeed, to many observers, Peru
during the so-called guano age (1845-70) seemed uniquely positioned to
emerge as the preeminent country in all of South America.
Peru
Peru - THE GUANO ERA
Peru
Consolidation of the State
The guano boom, made possible by the droppings from millions of birds
on the Chincha Islands, proved to be a veritable bonanza for Peru,
beginning in the 1840s. By the time that this natural resource had been
depleted three decades later, Peru had exported some 12 million tons of
the fertilizer to Europe and North America, where it stimulated the
commercial agricultural revolution. On the basis of a truly enormous
flow of revenue to the state (nearly US$500 million), Peru was presented
in the middle decades of the nineteenth century with a historic
opportunity for development. Why this did not materialize, but rather
became a classic case of boom-bust export dependence, has continued to
be the subject of intense discussion and debate. Most analysts, however,
concur with historian Magnus M�rner that "guano wealth was, on the
whole, a developmental opportunity missed."
On the positive side, guano-led economic growth--on average 9 percent
a year beginning in the 1840s--and burgeoning government coffers
provided the basis for the consolidation of the state. With adequate
revenues, Castilla was able to retire the internal and external debt and
place the government on a sound financial footing for the first time
since independence. That, in turn, shored up the country's credit rating
abroad (which, however, in time proved to be a double-edged sword in the
absence of fiscal restraint). It also enabled Castilla to abolish
vestiges of the colonial past--slavery in 1854 and the onerous native
tribute-- modernize the army, and centralize state power at the expense
of local caudillos.
Peru
Peru - THE GUANO ERA - Failed Development
Peru
The guano bonanza also set in motion more negative trends. Castilla
"nationalized" guano in order to maximize benefits to the
state but in so doing reinforced aspects of the old colonial pattern of
a mercantilist political economy. The state then consigned the
commercialization of guano to certain favored private sectors based in
Lima that had foreign connections. This created a nefarious and often
collusive relationship between the state and a new "liberal"
group of guano consignees.
Soon, this increasingly powerful liberal plutocracy succeeded in
reorienting the country's trade policy away from the previous
nationalist and protectionist era toward export-led growth and low
tariffs. Capital investment derived from the guano boom
and abroad flowed into the export sector, particularly sugar, cotton,
and nitrate production. The coast now became the most economically
dynamic region of the country, modernizing at a pace that outstripped
the Sierra. Coastal export-led growth not only intensified the uneven
and dualist nature of Peruvian development, but subjected the economy to
the vicissitudes of world trade. Between 1840 and 1875, the value of
exports surged from 6 million pesos to almost 32 million, while imports
went from 4 to 24 million pesos. On the face of it, the liberal export
model, based on guano, pulled Peru out of its postindependence economic
stagnation and seemed dramatically successful. However, while great
fortunes were accruing to the new coastal plutocracy, little thought was
given to closing the historical inequalities of wealth and income or to
fostering a national market for incipient home manufacturing that might
have created the foundation for a more diversified and truly long-term
economic development.
What proved a greater problem in the short term was the state's
increasing reliance and ultimate dependence on foreign loans, secured by
the guano deposits which, however, were a finite and increasingly
depleted natural resource. These loans helped finance an overly
ambitious railroad and road-building scheme in the 1860s designed to
open up Peru's natural, resourcerich interior to exploitation. Under the
direction of American railroad engineer Henry Meiggs (known as the
"Yankee Pizarro"), Chinese coolies constructed a spectacular
Andean railroad system over some of the most difficult topography in the
world. But the cost of constructing some 1,240 kilometers of railroad,
together with a litany of other state expenditures, caused Peru to jump
from last to first place as the world's largest borrower on London money
markets.
Peru also fought two brief but expensive wars. The first, in which
Peru prevailed, was with Ecuador (1859-60) over disputed territory
bordering the Amazon. However, Castilla failed to extract a definitive
agreement from Ecuador that might have settled conclusively the border
issue, so it continued to fester throughout the next century. More
successful was the Peruvian victory in 1866 over Spain's attempts to
seize control of the guano-rich Chincha Islands in a tragicomic venture
to recapture some of its lost empire in South America.
By the 1870s, Peru's financial house of cards, constructed on guano,
finally came tumbling down. As described by Gootenberg, "Under the
combined weight of manic activity, unrestrained borrowing, dismal choice
of developmental projects, the evaporation of guano, and gross fiscal
mismanagement, Peru's state finally collapsed ..." Ironically, the
financial crisis occurred during the presidency of Manuel Pardo
(1872-76), the country's first elected civilian president since
independence and leader of the fledgling antimilitary Civilista Party
(Partido Civilista--PC).
By the 1870s, economic growth and greater political stability had
created the conditions for the organization of the country's first
political party. It was composed primarily of the plutocrats of the
guano era, the newly rich merchants, planters, and businesspeople, who
believed that the country could no longer afford to be governed by the
habitual military "man on horseback." Rather, the new age of
international trade, business, and finance needed the managerial skills
that only civilian leadership could provide. Their candidate was the
dynamic and cosmopolitan Pardo, who, at age thirty-seven, had already
made a fortune in business and served with distinction as treasury
minister and mayor of Lima. Who better, they asked, at a time when the
government of Colonel Jos� Balta (1868-72) had sunk into a morass of
corruption and incompetence, could clean up the government, deal with
the mounting financial problems, and further develop the liberal
export-model that so benefited their particular interests?
However, the election of the competent Pardo in 1872 and his ensuing
austerity program were not enough to ward off the impending collapse.
The worldwide depression of 1873 virtually sealed Peru's fate, and as
Pardo's term drew to a close in 1876, the country was forced to default
on its foreign debt. With social and political turmoil once again on the
rise, the Civilistas found it expedient to turn to a military figure,
Mariano Ignacio Prado (1865-67, 1876-79), who had rallied the country
against the Spanish naval attack in 1865 and then served as president.
He was reelected president in 1876 only to lead the country into a
disastrous war with its southern neighbor Chile in 1879.
Peru
Peru - WAR WITH CHILE
Peru
The war with <"../chile/index.html">Chile
developed over the disputed, nitrate-rich Atacama Desert. Neither Peru,
nor its ally, <"../bolivia/index.html">Bolivia,
in the regional balance of power against Chile, had been able to
solidify its territorial claims in the desert, which left the rising
power of Chile to assert its designs over the region. Chile chose to
attack Bolivia after Bolivia broke the Treaty of 1866 between the two
countries by raising taxes on the export of nitrates from the region,
mainly controlled by Chilean companies. In response, Bolivia invoked its
secret alliance with Peru, the Treaty of 1873, to go to war.
Peru was obligated, then, to enter a war for which it was woefully
unprepared, particularly since the antimilitary Pardo government had
sharply cut the defense budget. With the perspective of hindsight, the
outcome with Peru's more powerful and better organized foe to the south
was altogether predictable. This was especially true after Peru's
initial defeat in the naval Battle of Iquique Bay, where it lost one of
its two iron-clad warships. Five months later, it lost the other,
allowing Chile to gain complete control of the sea lanes and thus to
virtually dictate the pace of the war. Although the Peruvians fought the
superior Chilean expeditionary forces doggedly thereafter, resorting to
guerrilla action in the Sierra after the fall of Lima in 1881, they were
finally forced to conclude a peace settlement in 1883. The Treaty of Anc�n
ceded to Chile in perpetuity the nitrate-rich province of Tarapac� and
provided that the provinces of Tacna and Arica would remain in Chilean
possession for ten years, when a plebiscite would be held to decide
their final fate. After repeated delays, both countries finally agreed
in 1929, after outside mediation by the United States, to a compromise
solution to the dispute by which Tacna would be returned to Peru and
Chile would retain Arica. For Peru, defeat and dismemberment by Chile in
war brought to a final disastrous conclusion an era that had begun so
auspiciously in the early 1840s with the initial promise of guano-led
development.
Peru
Peru - The New Militarism
Peru
After a period of intense civil strife similar to the political chaos
during the immediate postindependence period half a century earlier, the
armed forces, led by General Andr�s Avelina C�ceres (1886-90,
1894-95), succeeded in establishing a measure of order in the country. C�ceres,
a Creole and hero of the guerrilla resistance to the Chilean occupation
during the War of the Pacific, managed to win the presidency in 1886. He
succeeded in imposing a general peace, first by crushing a native
rebellion in the Sierra led by a former ally, the respected native
American varayoc (leader) Pedro Pablo Atuspar�a. C�ceres then
set about the task of reconstructing the country after its devastating
defeat.
The centerpiece of his recovery program was the Grace Contract, a
controversial proposal by a group of British bondholders to cancel
Peru's foreign debt in return for the right to operate the country's
railroad system for sixty-six years. The contract provoked great
controversy between nationalists, who saw it as a sellout to foreign
interests, and liberals, who argued that it would lay the basis for
economic recovery by restoring Peru's investment and creditworthiness in
the West. Finally approved by Congress in 1888, the Grace Contract,
together with a robust recovery in silver production (US$35 million by
1895), laid the foundations for a revival of export-led growth.
Indeed, economic recovery would soon turn into a sustained, long-term
period of growth. Nils Jacobsen has calculated that "Exports rose
fourfold between the nadir of 1883 and 1910, from 1.4 to 6.2 million
pounds sterling and may have doubled again until 1919; British and
United States capital investments grew nearly tenfold between 1880 and
1919, from US$17 to US$161 million." However, he also notes that it
was not until 1920 that the nation fully recovered from the losses
sustained between the depression of 1873 and the postwar beginnings of
recovery at the end of the 1880s. Once underway economic recovery
inaugurated a long period of stable, civilian rule beginning in 1895.
Peru
Peru - The Aristocratic Republic
Peru
The Aristocratic Republic began with the popular "Revolution of
1895," led by the charismatic and irrepressible Jos� Nicol�s de
Pi�rola (1895-99). He overthrew the increasingly dictatorial C�ceres,
who had gained the presidency again in 1894 after having placed his
crony Colonel Remigio Morales Berm�dez (1890-94) in power in 1890. Pi�rola,
an aristocratic and patriarchal figure, was fond of saying that
"when the people are in danger, they come to me." Although he
had gained the intense enmity of the Civilistas in 1869 when, as
minister of finance in the Balta government, he had transferred the
lucrative guano consignment contract to the foreign firm of Dreyfus and
Company of Paris, he now succeeded in forging an alliance with his
former opponents. This began a period known as the Aristocratic Republic
(1895- 1914), during which Peru was characterized not only by relative
political harmony and rapid economic growth and modernization, but also
by social and political change.
From the ruins of the War of the Pacific, new elites had emerged
along the coast and coalesced to form a powerful oligarchy, based on the
reemergence of sugar, cotton, and mining exports, as well as the
reintegration of Peru into the international economy. Its political
expression was the reconstituted Civilista Party, which had revived its
antimilitary and proexport program during the period of intense national
disillusion and introspection that followed the country's defeat in the
war. By the time the term of Pi�rola's successor, Eduardo L�pez de
Roma�a (1899-1903), came to an end, the Civilistas had cleverly managed
to gain control of the national electoral process and proceeded to elect
their own candidate and party leader, the astute Manuel Candamo
(1903-1904), to the presidency. Thereafter, they virtually controlled
the presidency up until World War I, although Candamo died a few months
after assuming office. Elections, however, were restricted, subject to
strict property and literacy qualifications, and more often than not
manipulated by the incumbent Civilista regime.
The Civilistas were the architects of unprecedented political
stability and economic growth, but they also set in motion profound
social changes that would, in time, alter the political panorama. With
the gradual advance of export capitalism, peasants migrated and became
proletarians, laboring in industrial enclaves that arose not only in
Lima, but in areas of the countryside as well. The traditional haciendas
and small-scale mining complexes that could be connected to the
international market gave way increasingly to modern agroindustrial
plantations and mining enclaves. With the advent of World War I, Peru's
international markets were temporarily disrupted and social unrest
intensified, particularly in urban centers where a modern labor movement
began to take shape.
Peru
Peru - Impact of World War I
Peru
The Civilistas, however, were unable to manage the new social forces
that their policies unleashed. This first became apparent in 1912 when
the millionaire businessman Guillermo Billinghurst (1912-14)--the
reform-minded, populist former mayor of Lima--was able to organize a
general strike to block the election of the official Civilista
presidential candidate and force his own election by Congress. During
his presidency, Billinghurst became embroiled in an increasingly bitter
series of conflicts with Congress, ranging from proposed advanced social
legislation to settlement of the Tacna-Arica dispute. When Congress
opened impeachment hearings in 1914, Billinghurst threatened to arm the
workers and forcibly dissolve Congress. This provoked the armed forces
under Colonel Oscar Raimundo Benavides (1914-15, 1933-36, and 1936-39)
to seize power.
The coup marked the beginning of a long-term alignment of the
military with the oligarchy, whose interests and privileges it would
defend up until the 1968 revolution of General Juan Velasco Alvarado
(1968-75). It was also significant because it not only ended almost two
decades of uninterrupted civilian rule, but, unlike past military
interventions, was more institutional than personalist in character.
Benavides was a product of Pi�rola's attempt to professionalize the
armed forces under the tutelage of a French military mission, beginning
in 1896, and therefore was uncomfortable in his new political role.
Within a year, he arranged new elections that brought Jos� de Pardo y
Barreda (1904-1908, 1915-19) to power.
A new round of economic problems, deepening social unrest, and
powerful, new ideological currents toward the end of World War I,
however, converged to bring a generation of Civilista rule to an end in
1919. The war had a roller coaster effect on the Peruvian economy.
First, export markets were temporarily cut off, provoking recession.
Then, when overseas trade was restored, stimulating demand among the
combatants for Peru's primary products, an inflationary spiral saw the
cost of living nearly double between 1913 and 1919.
This inflation had a particularly negative impact on the new working
classes in Lima and elsewhere in the country. The number of workers had
grown sharply since the turn of the century--by one count rising from
24,000, or 17 percent of the capital's population in 1908, to 44,000, or
20 percent of the population in 1920. Similar growth rates occurred
outside of Lima in the export enclaves of sugar (30,000 workers), cotton
(35,000), oil (22,500), and copper. The Cerro de Pasco copper mine alone
had 25,500 workers. The growth and concentration of workers was
accompanied by the spread of anarchic ideas before and during the war
years, making the incipient labor movement increasingly militant.
Violent strikes erupted on sugar plantations, beginning in 1910, and the
first general strike in the country's history occurred a year later.
Radical new ideologies further fueled the growing social unrest in
the country at the end of the war. The ideas of the Mexican and Russian
revolutions, the former predating the latter, quickly spread radical new
doctrines to the far corners of the world, including Peru. Closer to
home, the indigenista (Indigenist) movement increasingly
captured the imagination of a new generation of Peruvians, particularly
urban, middle-class mestizos who were reexamining their roots in a
changing Peru. Indigenismo (Indigenism) was promoted by a group
of writers and artists who sought to rediscover and celebrate the
virtues and values of Peru's glorious Incan past. Awareness of the
indigenous masses was heightened at this time by another wave of native
uprisings in the southern highlands. They were caused by the disruption
and dislocation of traditional native American communities brought about
by the opening of new international markets and reorganization of the
wool trade in the region.
All of these social, economic, and intellectual trends came to a head
at the end of the Pardo administration. In 1918-19 Pardo faced an
unprecedented wave of strikes and labor mobilization that was joined by
student unrest over university reform. The ensuing worker-student
alliance catapulted a new generation of radical reformers, headed by V�ctor
Ra�l Haya de la Torre--a young, charismatic student at San Marcos
University--and Jos� Carlos Mari�tegui--a brilliant Lima journalist
who defended the rights of the new, urban working class--to national
prominence.
Peru
Peru - The Eleven-Year Rule
Peru
The immediate political beneficiary of this turmoil, however, was a
dissident Civilista, former president Augusto B. Legu�a y Salcedo
(1908-12, 1919-30), who had left the party after his first term. He ran
as an independent in the 1919 elections on a reform platform that
appealed to the emerging new middle and working classes. When he
perceived a plot by the Civilistas to deny him the election, the
diminutive but boundlessly energetic Legu�a (he stood only 1.5 meters
tall and weighed a little over 45 kilograms) staged a preemptive coup
and assumed the presidency.
Legu�a's eleven-year rule, known as the oncenio (1919- 30),
began auspiciously enough with a progressive, new constitution in 1920
that enhanced the power of the state to carry out a number of popular
social and economic reforms. The regime weathered a brief postwar
recession and then generated considerable economic growth by opening the
country to a flood of foreign loans and investment. This allowed Legu�a
to replace the Civilista oligarchy with a new, if plutocratic,
middle-class political base that prospered from state contracts and
expansion of the government bureaucracy. However, it was not long into
his regime that Legu�a's authoritarian and dictatorial tendencies
appeared. He cracked down on labor and student militancy, purged the
Congress of opposition, and amended the constitution so that he could
run, unopposed, for reelection in 1924 and again in 1929.
Legu�a's popularity was further eroded as a result of a border
dispute between Peru and Colombia involving territory in the
rubber-tapping region between the R�o Caquet� and the northern
watershed of the R�o Napo. Under the United Statesmediated Salom�n-Lozano
Treaty of March 1922, which favored Colombia, the R�o Putumayo was
established as the boundary between Colombia and Peru. Pressured by the United States to accept the unpopular treaty,
Legu�a finally submitted the document to the Peruvian Congress in
December 1927, and it was ratified. The treaty was also unpopular with
Ecuador, which found itself surrounded on the east by Peru.
The orgy of financial excesses, which included widespread corruption
and the massive build-up of the foreign debt, was brought to a sudden
end by the Wall Street stock market crash of 1929 and ensuing worldwide
depression. Legu�a's eleven-year rule, the longest in Peruvian history,
collapsed a year later. Once again, the military intervened and
overthrew Legu�a, who died in prison in 1932.
Meanwhile, the onset of the Great Depression galvanized the forces of
the left. Before he died prematurely at the age of thirty-five in 1930,
Mari�tegui founded the Peruvian Socialist Party (Partido Socialista
Peruano--PSP), shortly to become the Peruvian Communist Party (Partido
Comunista Peruano--PCP), which set about the task of political
organizing after Legu�a's fall from power. Although a staunch Marxist
who believed in the class struggle and the revolutionary role of the
proletariat, Mari�tegui's main contribution was to recognize the
revolutionary potential of Peru's native peasantry. He argued that
Marxism could be welded to an indigenous Andean revolutionary tradition
that included indigenismo, the long history of Andean peasant
rebellion, and the labor movement.
Haya de la Torre returned to Peru from a long exile to organize the
American Popular Revolutionary Alliance (Alianza Popular Revolucionaria
Americana--APRA), an anti-imperialist, continent-wide, revolutionary
alliance, founded in Mexico in 1924. For Haya de la Torre, capitalism
was still in its infancy in Peru and the proletariat too small and
undeveloped to bring about a revolution against the Civilista oligarchy.
For that to happen, he argued, the working classes must be joined to
radicalized sectors of the new middle classes in a cross-class,
revolutionary alliance akin to populism. Both parties--one from a
Marxist and the other from a populist perspective--sought to organize
and lead the new middle and working classes, now further dislocated and
radicalized by the Great Depression. With his oratorical brilliance,
personal magnetism, and national-populist message, Haya de la Torre was
able to capture the bulk of these classes and to become a major figure
in Peruvian politics until his death in 1980 at the age of eighty-six.
Peru
Peru - Impact of the Depression and World War II
Peru
After 1930 both the military, now firmly allied with the oligarchy,
and the forces of the left, particularly APRA, became important new
actors in Peruvian politics. This period (1930-68) has been
characterized in political terms by sociologist Dennis Gilbert as
operating under essentially a "tripartite" political system,
with the military often ruling at the behest of the oligarchy to
suppress the "unruly" masses represented by APRA and the PCP.
Lieutenant Colonel Luis M. S�nchez Cerro and then General Benavides led
another period of military rule during the turbulent 1930s.
In the presidential election of 1931, S�nchez Cerro (1931- 33),
capitalizing on his popularity from having deposed the dictator Legu�a,
barely defeated APRA's Haya de la Torre, who claimed to have been
defrauded out of his first bid for office. In July 1932, APRA rose in a
bloody popular rebellion in Trujillo, Haya de la Torre's hometown and an
APRA stronghold, that resulted in the execution of some sixty army
officers by the insurgents. Enraged, the army unleashed a brutal
suppression that cost the lives of at least 1,000 Apristas (APRA
members) and their sympathizers (partly from aerial bombing, used for
the first time in South American history). Thus began what would become
a virtual vendetta between the armed forces and APRA that would last for
at least a generation and on several occasions prevented the party from
coming to power.
Politically, the Trujillo uprising was followed shortly by another
crisis, this time a border conflict with Colombia over disputed
territory in the Let�cia region of the Amazon. Before it could be
settled, S�nchez Cerro was assassinated in April 1933 by a militant
Aprista, and Congress quickly elected former president Benavides to
complete S�nchez Cerro's five-year term. Benavides managed to settle
the thorny Let�cia dispute peacefully, with assistance from the League
of Nations, when a Protocol of Peace, Friendship, and Cooperation was
signed in May 1934 ratifying Colombia's original claim. After a disputed
election in 1936, in which Haya de la Torre was prevented from running
and which Benavides nullified with the reluctant consent of Congress,
Benavides remained in power and extended his term until 1939.
During the 1930s, Peru's economy was one of the least affected by the
Great Depression. Thanks to a relatively diversified range of exports,
led by cotton and new industrial metals (particularly lead and zinc),
the country began a rapid recovery of export earnings as early as 1933.
As a result, unlike many other Latin American countries that adopted
Keynesian and import-substitution
industrialization measures to counteract the decline,
Peru's policymakers made relatively few alterations in their long-term
model of export-oriented growth.
Under S�nchez Cerro, Peru did take measures to reorganize its
debt-ridden finances by inviting Edwin Kemmerer, a well-known United
States financial consultant, to recommend reforms. Following his advice,
Peru returned to the gold standard, but could not avoid declaring a
moratorium on its US$180-million debt on April 1, 1931. For the next
thirty years, Peru was barred from the United States capital market.
Benavides's policies combined strict economic orthodoxy, measures of
limited social reform designed to attract the middle classes away from
APRA, and repression against the left, particularly APRA. For much of
the rest of the decade, APRA continued to be persecuted and remained
underground. Almost from the moment APRA appeared, the party and Haya de
la Torre had been attacked by the oligarchy as antimilitary,
anticlerical, and "communistic." Indeed, the official reason
often given for APRA's proscription was its
"internationalism," because the party began as a
continent-wide alliance "against Yankee imperialism"--
suggesting that it was somehow subversively un-Peruvian.
Haya de la Torre had also flirted with the Communists during his
exile in the 1920s, and his early writings were influenced by a number
of radical thinkers, including Marx. Nevertheless, the 1931 APRA program
was essentially reformist, nationalist, and populist. It called, among
other things, for a redistributive and interventionist state that would
move to selectively nationalize land and industry. Although certainly
radical from the perspective of the oligarchy, the program was designed
to correct the historical inequality of wealth and income in Peru, as
well as to reduce and bring under greater governmental control the
large-scale foreign investment in the country that was high in
comparison with other Andean nations.
The intensity of the oligarchy's attacks was also a response to the
extreme rhetoric of APRA polemicists and reflected the polarized state
of Peruvian society and politics during the depression. Both sides
readily resorted to force and violence, as the bloody events of the
1930s readily attested--the 1932 Trujillo revolt, the spate of prominent
political assassinations (including S�nchez Cerro and Antonio Mir�
Quesada, publisher of El Comercio), and widespread imprisonment
and torture of Apristas and their sympathizers. It also revealed the
oligarchy's apprehension, indeed paranoia, at APRA's sustained attempt
to mobilize the masses for the first time into the political arena. At
bottom, Peru's richest, most powerful forty families perceived a direct
challenge to their traditional privileges and absolute right to rule, a
position they were not to yield easily.
When Benavides's extended term expired in 1939, Manuel Prado y
Ugarteche (1939-45), a Lima banker from a prominent family and son of a
former president, won the presidency. He was soon confronted with a
border conflict with Ecuador that led to a brief war in 1941. After
independence, Ecuador had been left without access to either the Amazon
or the region's other major waterway, the R�o Mara��n, and thus
without direct access to the Atlantic Ocean. In an effort to assert its
territorial claims in a region near the R�o Mara��n in the Amazon
Basin, Ecuador occupied militarily the town of Zarumilla along its
southwestern border with Peru. However, the Peruvian Army (Ej�rcito
Peruano-- EP) responded with a lightning victory against the Ecuadorian
Army. At subsequent peace negotiations in Rio de Janeiro in 1942, Peru's
ownership of most of the contested region was affirmed.
On the domestic side, Prado gradually moved to soften official
opposition to APRA, as Haya de la Torre moved to moderate the party's
program in response to the changing national and international
environment brought on by World War II. For example, he no longer
proposed to radically redistribute income, but instead proposed to
create new wealth, and he replaced his earlier strident
"anti-imperialism" directed against the United States with
more favorable calls for democracy, foreign investment, and hemispheric
harmony. As a result, in May 1945 Prado legalized the party that now
reemerged on the political scene after thirteen years underground.
The Allied victory in World War II reinforced the relative democratic
tendency in Peru, as Prado's term came to an end in 1945. Jos� Luis
Bustamante y Rivero (1945-48), a liberal and prominent international
jurist, was overwhelmingly elected president on the basis of an alliance
with the now legal APRA. Responding to his more reform- and
populist-oriented political base, Bustamante and his Aprista minister of
economy moved Peru away from the strictly orthodox, free-market policies
that had characterized his predecessors. Increasing the state's
intervention in the economy in an effort to stimulate growth and
redistribution, the new government embarked on a general fiscal
expansion, increased wages, and established controls on prices and
exchange rates. The policy, similar to APRA's later approach in the late
1980s, was neither well-conceived nor efficiently administered and came
at a time when Peru's exports, after an initial upturn after the war,
began to sag. This resulted in a surge of inflation and labor unrest
that ultimately destabilized the government.
Bustamante also became embroiled in an escalating political conflict
with the Aprista-controlled Congress, further weakening the
administration. The political waters were also roiled in 1947 by the
assassination by Aprista militants of Francisco Grana Garland, the
socially prominent director of the conservative newspaper La Prensa.
When a naval mutiny organized by elements of APRA broke out in 1948, the
military, under pressure from the oligarchy, overthrew the government
and installed General Manuel A. Odr�a (1948-50, 1950-56), hero of the
1941 war with Ecuador, as president.
Peru
Peru - Rural Stagnation and Social Mobilization
Peru
Odr�a imposed a personalistic dictatorship on the country and
returned public policy to the familiar pattern of repression of the left
and free-market orthodoxy. Indicative of the new regime's hostility
toward APRA, Haya de la Torre, after seeking political asylum in the
Embassy of Colombia in Lima in 1949, was prevented by the government
from leaving the country. He remained a virtual prisoner in the embassy
until his release into exile in 1954. However, along with such
repression Odr�a cleverly sought to undermine APRA's popular support by
establishing a dependent, paternalistic relationship with labor and the
urban poor through a series of charity and social welfare measures.
At the same time, Odr�a's renewed emphasis on export-led growth
coincided with a period of rising prices on the world market for the
country's diverse commodities, engendered by the outbreak of the Korean
War in 1950. Also, greater political stability brought increased
national and foreign investment, particularly in the manufacturing
sector. Indeed, this sector grew almost 8 percent annually between 1950
and 1967, increasing from 14 to 20 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). Overall, the economy experienced a prolonged period of
strong, export-led growth, amounting on average to 5 percent a year
during the same period.
Not all Peruvians, however, benefited from this period of sustained
capitalist development, which tended to be regional and confined mainly
to the more modernized coast. This uneven pattern of growth served to
intensify the dualistic structure of the country by widening the
historical gap between the Sierra and the coast. In the Sierra, the
living standard of the bottom one- quarter of the population stagnated
or fell during the twenty years after 1950. In fact, the Sierra had been
losing ground economically to the modernizing forces operative on the
coast ever since the 1920s. With income distribution steadily worsening,
the Sierra experienced a period of intense social mobilization during
the 1950s and 1960s.
This was manifested first in the intensification of rural- urban
migration and then in a series of confrontations between peasants and
landowners. The fundamental causes of these confrontations were
numerous. Population growth, which had almost doubled nationally between
1900 and 1940 (3.7 million to 7 million), increased rapidly to 13.6
million by 1970. This turned the labor market from a state of chronic
historical scarcity to one of abundant surplus. With arable land
constant and locked into the system of latifundios, ownership-to-area ratios deteriorated sharply,
increasing peasant pressures on the land.
Peru's land-tenure system remained one of the most unequal in Latin
America. In 1958 the country had a high coefficient of 0.88 on the Gini
index, which measures land concentration on a scale of 0 to 1. Figures
for the same year show that 2 percent of the country's landowners
controlled 69 percent of arable land. Conversely, 83 percent of
landholders holding no more than 5 hectares controlled only 6 percent of
arable land. Finally, the Sierra's terms
of trade in agricultural foodstuffs steadily declined
because of the state's urban bias in food pricing policy, which kept
farm prices artificially low.
Many peasants opted to migrate to the coast, where most of the
economic and job growth was occurring. The population of metropolitan
Lima, in particular, soared. While standing at slightly over 500,000 in
1940, it increased threefold to over 1.6 million in 1961 and nearly
doubled again by 1981 to more than 4.1 million. The capital became
increasingly ringed with squalid barriadas (shantytowns) of urban migrants, putting pressure on the
liberal state, long accustomed to ignoring the funding of government
services to the poor.
Those peasants who chose to remain in the Sierra did not remain
passive in the face of their declining circumstances but became
increasingly organized and militant. A wave of strikes and land
invasions swept over the Sierra during the 1950s and 1960s as campesinos
demanded access to land. Tensions grew especially in the Convenci�n and
Lares region of the high jungle near Cusco, where Hugo Blanco, a
Quechua-speaking Trotskyite and former student leader, mobilized
peasants in a militant confrontation with local gamonales.
While economic stagnation prodded peasant mobilization in the Sierra,
economic growth along the coast produced other important social changes.
The postwar period of industrialization, urbanization, and general
economic growth created a new middle and professional class that altered
the prevailing political panorama. These new middle sectors formed the
social base for two new political parties--Popular Action (Acci�n
Popular--AP) and the Christian Democratic Party (Partido Dem�crata
Cristiano-- PDC)--that emerged in the 1950s and 1960s to challenge the
oligarchy with a moderate, democratic reform program. Emphasizing
modernization and development within a somewhat more activist state
framework, they posed a new challenge to the old left, particularly
APRA.
For its part, APRA accelerated its rightward tendency. It entered
into what many saw as an unholy alliance (dubbed the convivencia,
or living together) with its old enemy, the oligarchy, by agreeing to
support the candidacy of conservative Manuel Prado y Ugarteche in the
1956 elections, in return for legal recognition. As a result, many new
voters became disillusioned with APRA and flocked to support the
charismatic reformer Fernando Bela�nde Terry (1963-68, 1980-85), the
founder of the AP. Although Prado won, six years later the army
intervened when its old enemy, Haya de la Torre (back from six years of
exile), still managed, if barely, to defeat the upstart Bela�nde by
less than one percentage point in the 1962 elections. A surprisingly
reform-minded junta of the armed forces headed by General Ricardo P�rez
Godoy held power for a year (1962-63) and then convoked new elections.
This time Bela�nde, in alliance with the Christian Democrats, defeated
Haya de la Torre and became president.
Bela�nde's government, riding the crest of the social and political
discontent of the period, ushered in a period of reform at a time when
United States president John F. Kennedy's Alliance
for Progress was also awakening widespread
expectations for reform throughout Latin America. Bela�nde tried to
diffuse the growing unrest in the highlands through a three- pronged
approach: modest agrarian reform, colonization projects in the high
jungle or monta�a, and the construction of the north- south Jungle
Border Highway (la carretera marginal de la selva or la
marginal), running the entire length of the country along the
jungle fringe. The basic thrust of the Agrarian Reform Law of 1969,
which was substantially watered down by a conservative coalition in
Congress between the APRA and the National Odriist Union (Uni�n
Nacional Odri�sta--UNO), was to open access to new lands and production
opportunities, rather than dismantle the traditional latifundio system.
However, this plan failed to quiet peasant discontent, which by 1965
helped fuel a Castroite guerrilla movement, the Movement of the
Revolutionary Left (Movimiento de la Izquierda Revolucionaria-- MIR),
led by rebellious Apristas on the left who were unhappy with the party's
alliance with the country's most conservative forces.
In this context of increasing mobilization and radicalization, Bela�nde
lost his reformist zeal and called on the army to put down the guerrilla
movement with force. Opting for a more technocratic orientation
palatable to his urban middle class base, Bela�nde, an architect and
urban planner by training, embarked on a large number of construction
projects, including irrigation, transportation, and housing, while also
investing heavily in education. Such initiatives were made possible, in
part, by the economic boost provided by the dramatic expansion of the
fishmeal industry. Aided by new technologies and the abundant fishing
grounds off the coast, fishmeal production soared. By 1962 Peru became
the leading fishing nation in the world, and fishmeal accounted for
fully one-third of the country's exports.
Bela�nde's educational expansion dramatically increased the number
of universities and graduates. But, however laudable, this policy tended
over time to swell recruits for the growing number of left-wing parties,
as economic opportunities diminished in the face of an end, in the late
1960s, of the long cycle of export- led economic expansion. Indeed,
economic problems spelled trouble for Bela�nde as he approached the end
of his term. Faced with a growing balance-of-payments problem, he was
forced to devalue the sol in 1967. He also seemed to many nationalists
to capitulate to foreign capital in a final settlement in 1968 of a
controversial and long-festering dispute with the International
Petroleum Company (IPC) over La Brea y Pari�as oil fields in northern
Peru. With public discontent growing, the armed forces, led by General
Velasco Alvarado, overthrew the Bela�nde government in 1968 and
proceeded to undertake an unexpected and unprecedented series of
reforms.
Peru
Peru - Military Reform from Above
Peru
The military intervention and its reformist orientation represented
changes both in the armed forces and Peruvian society. Within the armed
forces, the social origins of the officer corps no longer mirrored the
background and outlook of the creole upper classes, which had
historically inclined the officers to follow the mandate of the
oligarchy. Reflective of the social changes and mobility that were
occurring in society at large, officers now exhibited middle- and lower
middle class, provincial, mestizo or cholo backgrounds. General Velasco, a cholo himself,
had grown up in humble circumstances in the northern department of Piura
and purportedly went to school barefoot.
Moreover, this generation of officers had fought and defeated the
guerrilla movements in the backward Sierra. In the process, they had
come to the realization that internal peace in Peru depended not so much
on force of arms, but on implementing structural reforms that would
relieve the burden of chronic poverty and underdevelopment in the
region. In short, development, they concluded, was the best guarantee
for national security. The Bela�nde government had originally held out
the promise of reform and development, but had failed. The military
attributed that failure, at least in part, to flaws in the democratic
political system that had enabled the opposition to block and stalemate
reform initiatives in Congress. As nationalists, they also abhorred the
proposed pact with the IPC and looked askance at stories of widespread
corruption in the Bela�nde government.
Velasco moved immediately to implement a radical reform program,
which seemed, ironically, to embody much of the original 1931 program of
the army's old nemesis, APRA. His first act was to expropriate the large
agroindustrial plantations along the coast. The agrarian reform that
followed, the most extensive in Latin America outside of Cuba, proceeded
to destroy the economic base of power of the old ruling classes, the
export oligarchy, and its gamonal allies in the Sierra. By 1975
half of all arable land had been transferred, in the form of various
types of cooperatives, to over 350,000 families comprising about
onefourth of the rural population, mainly estate workers and renters (colonos).
Agricultural output tended to maintain its rather low pre-reform levels,
however, and the reform still left out an estimated 1 million seasonal
workers and only marginally benefited campesinos in the native
communities (about 40 percent of the rural population).
The Velasco regime also moved to dismantle the liberal, export model
of development that had reached its limits after the long postwar
expansion. The state now assumed, for the first time in history, a major
role in the development process. Its immediate target was the
foreign-dominated sector, which during the 1960s had attained a
commanding position in the economy. At the end of the Bela�nde
government in 1968, three-quarters of mining, one-half of manufacturing,
two-thirds of the commercial banking system, and one-third of the
fishing industry were under direct foreign control.
Velasco reversed this situation. By 1975 state enterprises accounted
for more than half of mining output, two-thirds of the banking system, a
fifth of industrial production, and half of total productive investment.
Velasco's overall development strategy was to shift from a laissez-faire
to a "mixed" economy, to replace export-led development with
import-substitution industrialization. At the same time, the state
implemented a series of social measures designed to protect workers and
redistribute income in order to expand the domestic market.
In the realm of foreign policy, the Velasco regime undertook a number
of important initiatives. Peru became a driving force not only behind
the creation of an Andean
Pact in 1969 to establish a common market with
coordinated trade and investment policies, but also in the movement of
nonaligned countries of the Third World. Reflecting a desire to end its
perceived dependency economically and politically on the United States,
the Velasco government also moved to diversify its foreign relations by
making trade and aid pacts with the Soviet Union and East European
countries, as well as with Japan and West European nations. Finally,
Peru succeeded during the 1970s in establishing its international claims
to a 303-kilometer territorial limit in the Pacific Ocean.
By the time Velasco was replaced on August 29, 1975, by the more
conservative General Francisco Morales Berm�dez Cerrutti (1975-80), his
reform program was already weakening. Natural calamities, the world oil
embargo of 1973, increasing international indebtedness (Velasco had
borrowed heavily abroad to replace lost investment capital to finance
his reforms), overbureaucratization , and general mismanagement had
undermined early economic growth and triggered a serious inflationary
spiral. At the same time, Velasco, suffering from terminal cancer, had
become increasingly personalistic and autocratic, undermining the
institutional character of military rule. Unwilling to expand his
initial popularity through party politics, he had created a series of
mass organizations, tied to the state in typically corporatist and patrimonialist fashion, in order to mobilize support
and control the pace of reform. However, despite his rhetoric to create
truly popular, democratic organizations, he manipulated them from above
in an increasingly arbitrary manner. What had begun as an unusual
populist type of military experiment evolved into a form of what
political scientist Guillermo O'Donnell calls "bureaucratic
authoritarianism," with increasingly authoritarian and
personalistic characteristics that were manifested in
"Velasquismo."
Velasco's replacement, General Morales Berm�dez, spent most of his
term implementing an economic austerity program to stem the surge of
inflation. Public opinion increasingly turned against the rule of the
armed forces, which it blamed for the country's economic troubles,
widespread corruption, and mismanagement of the government, as well as
the general excesses of the "revolution." Consequently,
Morales Berm�dez prepared to return the country to the democratic
process.
Elections were held in 1978 for a Constituent Assembly empowered to
rewrite the constitution. Although Bela�nde's AP boycotted the
election, an array of newly constituted leftist parties won an
unprecedented 36 percent of the vote, with much of the remainder going
to APRA. The Assembly, under the leadership of the aging and terminally
ill Velasco (who would die in 1980), completed the new document in 1979.
Meanwhile, the popularity of former president Bela�nde underwent a
revival. Bela�nde was decisively reelected president in 1980, with 45
percent of the vote, for a term of five years.
Peru
Peru - Return to Democratic Rule
Peru
Bela�nde inherited a country that was vastly different from the one
he had governed in the 1960s. Gone was the old export oligarchy and its gamonal
allies in the Sierra, and the extent of foreign investment in the
economy had been sharply reduced. In their place, Velasco had borrowed
enormous sums from foreign banks and so expanded the state that by 1980
it accounted for 36 percent of national production, double its 1968
share. The informal sector of small- and medium-sized businesses outside
the legal, formal economy had also proliferated.
By 1980 Bela�nde's earlier reforming zeal had substantially waned,
replaced by a decidedly more conservative orientation to government. A
team of advisers and technocrats, many with experience in international
financial organizations, returned home to install a neoliberal economic
program that emphasized privatization of state-run business and, once
again, export-led growth. In an effort to increase agricultural
production, which had declined as a result of the agrarian reform, Bela�nde
sharply reduced food subsidies, allowing producer prices to rise.
However, just as Velasco's ambitious reforms of the early 1970s were
eroded by the 1973 worldwide oil crisis, Bela�nde's export strategy was
shattered by a series of natural calamities and a sharp plunge in
international commodity prices to their lowest levels since the Great
Depression. By 1983 production had fallen 12 percent and wages 20
percent in real terms while inflation once again surged. Unemployment
and underemployment was rampant, affecting perhaps two-thirds of the
work force and causing the minister of finance to declare the country in
"the worst economic crisis of the century." Again, the
government opted to borrow heavily in international money markets, after
having severely criticized the previous regime for ballooning the
foreign debt. Peru's total foreign debt swelled from US$9.6 billion in
1980 to US$13 billion by the end of Bela�nde's term.
The economic collapse of the early 1980s, continuing the long-term
cyclical decline begun in the late l960s, brought into sharp focus the
country's social deterioration, particularly in the more isolated and
backward regions of the Sierra. Infant mortality rose to 120 per 1,000
births (230 in some remote areas), life expectancy for males dropped to
58 compared with 64 in neighboring Chile, average daily caloric intake
fell below minimum United Nations standards, upwards of 60 percent of
children under five years of age were malnourished, and underemployment
and unemployment were rampant. Such conditions were a breeding ground
for social and political discontent, which erupted with a vengeance in
1980 with the appearance of the Shining Path (Sendero Luminoso--SL).
Founded in the remote and impoverished department of Ayacucho by Abim�el
Guzm�n Reynoso, a philosophy professor at the University of Huamanga,
the SL blended the ideas of MarxismLeninism , Maoism, and those of Jos�
Carlos Mari�tegui, Peru's major Marxist theoretician. Taking advantage
of the return to democratic rule, the deepening economic crisis, the
failure of the Velasco-era reforms, and a generalized vacuum of
authority in parts of the Sierra with the collapse of gamonal
rule, the SL unleashed a virulent and highly effective campaign of
terror and subversion that caught the Bela�nde government by surprise.
After first choosing to ignore the SL and then relying on an
ineffective national police response, Bela�nde reluctantly turned to
the army to try to suppress the rebels. However, that proved extremely
difficult to do. The SL expanded its original base in Ayacucho north
along the Andean spine and eventually into Lima and other cities,
gaining young recruits frustrated by their dismal prospects for a better
future. To further complicate pacification efforts, another rival
guerrilla group, the T�pac Amaru Revolutionary Movement (Movimiento
Revolucionario T�pac Amaru--MRTA), emerged in Lima.
Counterinsurgency techniques, often applied indiscriminately by the
armed forces, resulted in severe human rights violations against the
civilian population and only created more recruits for the SL. By the
end of Bela�nde's term in 1985, over 6,000 Peruvians had died from the
violence, and over US$1 billion in property damage had resulted. Strongly criticized by
international human rights organizations, Bela�nde nevertheless
continued to rely on military solutions, rather than other emergency
social or developmental measures that might have served to get at some
of the fundamental, underlying socioeconomic causes of the insurgency.
The severe internal social and political strife, not to mention the
deteriorating economic conditions, manifested in the Shining Path
insurgency may have contributed in 1981 to a flareup of the border
dispute with Ecuador in the disputed Mara��n region. Possibly looking
to divert public attention away from internal problems, both countries
engaged in a brief, five-day border skirmish on the eve of the
thirty-ninth anniversary of the signing of the 1942 Protocol of Rio de
Janeiro (Rio Protocol). Peruvian forces prevailed, and although a
ceasefire was quickly declared, it did nothing to resolve the two
opposing positions on the issue of the disputed territory. Essentially,
Peru continued to adhere to the Rio Protocol by which Ecuador had
recognized Peruvian claims. On the other hand, Ecuador continued to
argue that the Rio Protocol should be renegotiated, a position first
taken by President Velasco Ibarra in 1960 and adhered to by all
subsequent Ecuadorian presidents.
Along with these internal and external conflicts, Bela�nde also
confronted a rising tide of drug trafficking during his term. Coca had
been cultivated in the Andes since pre-Columbian times. The Inca elite
and clergy used it for certain ceremonies, believing that it possessed
magical powers. After the conquest, coca chewing, which suppresses
hunger and relieves pain and cold, became common among the oppressed
indigenous peasantry to deal with the hardships imposed by the new
colonial regime, particularly in the mines. The practice has continued,
with an estimated 15 percent of the population chewing coca on a daily
basis by 1990.
As a result of widespread cocaine consumption in the United States
and Europe, demand for coca from the Andes soared during the late 1970s.
Peru and Bolivia became the largest coca producers in the world,
accounting for roughly four-fifths of the production in South America.
Although originally produced mainly in five highland departments,
Peruvian production has become increasingly concentrated in the Upper
Huallaga Valley, located some 379 kilometers northeast of Lima. Peasant
growers, some 70,000 in the valley alone, are estimated to receive
upwards of US$240 million annually for their crop from
traffickers--mainly Colombians who oversee the processing,
transportation, and smuggling operations to foreign countries,
principally the United States.
After the cultivation of coca for narcotics uses was made illegal in
1978, efforts to curtail production were intensified by the Bela�nde
government, under pressure from the United States. Attempts were made to
substitute other cash crops while police units sought to eradicate the
plant. This tactic only served to alienate the growers and to set the
stage for the spread of the SL movement into the area in 1983-84 as
erstwhile defenders of the growers. By 1985 the SL had become an armed
presence in the region, defending the growers not only from the state,
but also from the extortionist tactics of the traffickers. The SL,
however, became one of the wealthiest guerrilla movements in modern
history by collecting an estimated US$30 million in "taxes"
from Colombian traffickers who controlled the drug trade.
As the guerrilla war raged on and with the economy in disarray, Bela�nde
had little to show at the end of his term, except perhaps the
reinstitution of the democratic process. During his term, political
parties had reemerged across the entire political spectrum and
vigorously competed to represent their various constituencies. With all
his problems, Bela�nde had also managed to maintain press and other
freedoms (marred, however, by increasing human rights violations) and to
observe the parliamentary process. In 1985 he managed to complete his
elected term, only the second time that this had happened in forty
years.
After presiding over a free election, Bela�nde turned the presidency
over to populist Alan Garc�a P�rez of APRA who had swept to victory
with 48 percent of the vote. Bela�nde's own party went down to a
resounding defeat with only 6 percent of the vote, while the Marxist
United Left (Izquierda Unida--IU) received 23 percent. The elections
revealed a decided swing to the left by the Peruvian electorate. For
APRA Garc�a's victory was the culmination of more than half a century
of political travail and struggle.
Peru
Peru - Geography
Peru
Natural Systems and Human Life
Peru is a complex amalgam of ancient and modern cultures,
populations, conflicts, questions, and dilemmas. The land itself offers
great challenges. With 1,285,216 square kilometers, Peru is the
eighteenth largest nation in area in the world and the fourth largest
Latin American nation. It ranked fifth in population in the region, with
22,767,543 inhabitants in July 1992. Centered in the heart of the
8,900-kilometer-long Andean range, Peru's geography and climates,
although similar to those of its Andean neighbors, form their own
peculiar conditions, making the region one of the world's most
heterogeneous and dynamic. Peru's principal natural features are its
desert coast; the forty great snow-covered peaks over 6,000 meters in
altitude, and the mountain ranges they anchor; Lake Titicaca, which is
shared with Bolivia, and at 3,809 meters above sea level the world's
highest navigable lake; and the vast web of tropical rivers like the
Ucayali, Mara��n, and Huallaga, which join to form the Amazon above
Peru's "Atlantic" port of Iquitos.
The Costa, Sierra, and Selva (selva--jungle), each
comprising a different and sharply contrasting environment, form the
major terrestrial regions of the country. Each area, however, contains
special ecological niches and microclimates generated by ocean currents,
the wide range of Andean altitudes, solar angles and slopes, and the
configurations of the vast Amazonian area. As a consequence of these
complexities, thirty-four ecological subregions have been identified.
Although there is great diversity in native fauna, relatively few
animals lent themselves to the process of domestication in prehistoric
times. Consequently, at the time of European arrival the only large
domesticated animals were the llamas and alpacas. Unfortunately, llamas
and alpacas are not powerful beasts, serving only as light pack animals
and for meat and wool. The absence of great draft animals played a key
role in the evolution of human societies in Peru because without animals
such as horses, oxen, camels, and donkeys, which powered the wheels of
development in the Old World, human energy in Peru and elsewhere in the
Americas could not be augmented significantly. As far as is known, the
enormous potential in hydrologic resources in preconquest times was
tapped only for agricultural irrigation and basic domestic usage.
Through the elaborate use of massive irrigation works and terracing,
which appeared in both highland and coastal valleys in pre-Chav�n
periods (1000 B.C.), the environment of the Andes was opened for
intensive human settlement, population growth, and the emergence of
regional states.
The development of Andean agriculture started about 9,000 years ago,
when inhabitants began experimenting with the rich vegetation they
utilized as food gatherers. Each ecological niche, or "floor,"
begins about 500 to 1,000 meters vertically above the last, forming a
minutely graduated and specialized environment for life. The central
Andean area is, thus, one of the world's most complex biospheres, which
human efforts made into one of the important prehistoric centers of
plant domestication. Native domesticated plants number in the hundreds
and include many varieties of such important crops as potatoes, maize
(corn), lima beans, peppers, yucca or manioc, cotton, squashes and
gourds, pineapples, avocado, and coca, which were unknown in the Old
World. Dozens of varieties of fruits and other products, despite their
attractive qualities, are little known outside the Andean region.
Conquest of the Aztec alliance in Mexico and the Inca Empire
(Tawantinsuyu) in the Andes gave impetus to one of the most important
features of the colonial process, the transfer of wealth, products, and
disease between the hemispheres. Andean plant resources, of course,
contributed significantly to life in Europe, Africa, and Asia. Although
attention has usually focused on the hoards of Inca gold and silver
shipped to Spain and thus funneled to the rest of Europe, the value of
Andean potatoes to the European economy and diet probably far exceeded
that of precious metals. By the same token, the Spanish conquerors
introduced into the New World wheat, barley, rice, and other grains;
vegetables like carrots; sugarcane; tea and coffee; and many fruits,
such as grapes, oranges, and olives. The addition of Old World cattle,
hogs, sheep, goats, chickens, and draft animals--horses, donkeys, and
oxen--vastly increased Andean resources and altered work methods, diets,
and health. The trade-off in terms of disease was one-sided; measles,
malaria, yellow fever, cholera, whooping cough, influenza, smallpox, and
bubonic plague, carried by rats, arrived with each ship from Europe. The
impact of these diseases was more devastating than any other aspect of
the conquest, and they remain major scourges for the majority of
Peruvians.
<>The Coastal Region
<>The Andean Highlands
<>High-Altitude Adaptations
<>The Amazonian Tropics
<>The Maritime Region
<>Natural Disasters and
Their Impact
<>People, Property, and
Farming
Peru
Peru - The Coastal Region
Peru
Peru's coast is a bleak, often rocky, and mountainous desert that
runs from Chile to Ecuador, punctuated by fifty-two small rivers that
descend through steep, arid mountains and empty into the Pacific. The
Costa is a strange land of great dunes and rolling expanses of barren
sand, at once a desert but with periods of humidity as high as 90
percent in the winter from June to September, when temperatures in Lima
average about 16 degrees Celsius. Temperatures along the coast rise near
the equator in the north, where the summer can be blazingly hot, and
fall to cooler levels in the south. If climatic conditions are right,
there can be a sudden burst of delicate plant life at certain places on
the lunar-like landscape, made possible by the heavy mist. Normally,
however, the mist is only sufficient to dampen the air, and the sand
remains bleakly sterile. These conditions greatly favor the preservation
of delicate archaeological remains. The environment also facilitates
human habitation and housing because the climate is benign and the lack
of rain eases the need for water-tight roofing.
Humans have lived for over 10,000 years in the larger coastal
valleys, fishing, hunting, and gathering along the rich shoreline, as
well as domesticating crops and inventing irrigation systems. The
largest of these littoral oases became the sites of towns, cities,
religious centers, and the seats of ancient nations. Although migration
from the highlands and other provincial regions has long occurred, the
movement of people to the Costa was greatly stimulated by the growth of
the fishing industry, which transformed villages and towns into
frontier-like cities, such as Chimbote. In the early 1990s, over 53
percent of the nation's people lived in these sharply delimited coastal
valleys. As the population becomes ever more concentrated in the coastal
urban centers, people increasingly overrun the rich and ancient
irrigated agricultural lands, such as those in the R�mac Valley where
greater Lima is situated, and the Chicama Valley at the site of the city
of Trujillo. Although the region contains 160,500 square kilometers of
land area, only 4 percent, or 6,900 square kilometers of it, is arable.
By 1990 population growth had increased the density of habitation to
1,715 persons for each square kilometer of arable land. Throughout all
the coastal valleys, human settlements remain totally dependent on the
waters that flow from the Andes along canals and aqueducts first
designed and built 3,000 years ago. Here, uncontrolled and unplanned
urban growth competes directly with scarce and vitally needed
agricultural land, steadily removing it from productive use.
Peru
Peru - The Andean Highlands
Peru
The Sierra is the commanding feature of Peru's territory, reaching
heights up to 6,768 meters. Hundreds of permanently glaciated and
snowcapped peaks tower over the valleys. The steep, desiccated Pacific
flank of the Andes supports only a sparse population in villages located
at infrequent springs and seepages. In contrast, tropical forests
blanket the eastern side of the Andes as high as 2,100 meters. Between
these extremes, in the shadows of the great snowpeaks, lie the most
populous highland ecological zones: the intermontane valleys (kichwa)
and the higher uplands and grassy puna or Altiplano plateaus.
Approximately 36 percent of the population lives in thousands of small
villages and hamlets that constitute the rural hinterland for the
regional capitals and trading centers. Over 15 percent of Peruvians live
at altitudes between 2,000 and 3,000 meters, 20 percent live between
3,000 and 4,000 meters, and 1 percent regularly reside at altitudes over
4,000 meters.
Although rich in mineral resources, such as copper, lead, silver,
iron, and zinc, which are mined at altitudes as high as 5,152 meters,
the Andes are endowed with limited usable land. The highlands encompass
34 percent of the national territory, or 437,000 square kilometers, but
only 4.5 percent of the highlands, or 19,665 square kilometers, is
arable and cultivated. Nevertheless, this area constitutes more than
half the nation's productive land. About 93,120 square kilometers of the
Sierra is natural pasture over 4,000 meters in altitude, too high for
agriculture. The 4.5 percent of arable land, therefore, has fairly dense
populations, particularly in Puno, Cajamarca, and in valleys such as the
Mantaro in Jun�n Department and Callej�n de Huaylas in Ancash
Department. The highland provinces have a population density of 460
persons per square kilometer of habitable, arable land.
The best areas for cultivation are the valleys, which range from
2,000 to 3,500 meters in altitude. Although many valleys have limited
water supplies, others, due to glacial runoffs, enjoy abundant water for
irrigation. In the protected valleys, the dry climate is temperate, with
no frost or great heat. In the high plateau or puna regions above 3,939
meters, the climate is cold and severe, often going below freezing at
night and seldom rising above 16� C by day. A myriad of native tubers
thrives at altitudes from 2,800 meters to almost 4,000 meters, including
over 4,000 known varieties of the potato, oca, and olluco, as
well as grains such as quinoa. The hardy native llamas and alpacas
thrive on the tough ichu grass of the punas; European sheep and
cattle, when adapted, do well at lesser altitudes.
For the Peruvians, there are two basic Andean seasons, the rainy
winter from October through April and the dry summer in the remaining
months. Crops are harvested according to type throughout the year, with
potatoes and other native tubers brought in during the middle to late
winter and grains during the dry season. The torrential rains of the
winter months frequently cause severe landslides and avalanches, called huaycos,
throughout the Andean region, damaging irrigation canals, roads, and
even destroying villages and cities. In the valley of Callej�n de
Huaylas, the city of Huaraz (Huar�s) was partially destroyed in 1941 by
just such a catastrophe, an event repeated a few kilometers away in
1962, when the town of Ranrahirca was annihilated by a huayco
that killed about 3,000 people.
The formidable terrain of the Andes, where the land may fall away
from 4,848 meters to 545 meters and then rise to 6,666 meters in a space
of 48 kilometers as the condor flies, poses a ubiquitous challenge to
any modern means of transport. Thus, the Andean region was not
penetrated by wheeled vehicles until railroads were built in the latter
half of the nineteenth century. Moreover, most of the nation did not see
wheels until the dirt road system was under construction in the 1920s.
To do this, President Augusto B. Legu�a y Salcedo (1908-12, 1919-30)
revived a national system of draft labor harkening back to the Inca's
conscripted labor force, or mita, used for road and bridge
building in ancient times.
Peru
Peru - High-Altitude Adaptations
Peru
As with the Himalayan mountains, the Andes impose severe conditions
and many limitations on life. Consequently, Andean people are physically
adapted to the heights in special ways. In contrast to persons born and
raised at sea level, those living at Andean altitudes 2,500 meters or
more above sea level have as much as 25 percent more blood that is more
viscous and richer in red cells, a heart that is proportionately larger,
and specially adapted, larger lungs, with an enhanced capacity to take
in oxygen from the rare atmosphere. Biological adaptations have
permitted the native highlanders to work efficiently and survive
successfully in the Andean altitudes for 20,000 years.
The first important scientific research on high-altitude biology was
undertaken by the Peruvian physician-scientist Carlos Monge Medrano in
the 1920s. He showed that coca-leaf chewing played a role in aiding the
metabolism in high-altitude populations. More recent studies have shown
that coca chewing significantly aids in metabolizing high carbohydrate
foods like potatoes, yucca, and corn, which are traditional staples in
the Andean region, thus providing the chewer with more rapid energy
input from his meals. Supposed narcotic effects of coca-leaf chewing are
nil because enzymes in the mouth convert coca into atropine-like
substances, unlike those involved in cocaine. Anthropologists Catherine
Allen and Enrique Mayer have also demonstrated the central role
traditional coca use plays in Andean communities as a medicine, ritual
substance, and an element in economic and social affairs.
Peru
Peru - The Amazonian Tropics
Peru
The Selva, which includes the humid tropics of the Amazon jungle and
rivers, covers about 63 percent of Peru but contains only about 11
percent of the country's population. The region begins high in the
eastern Andean cloud forests, called the ceja de monta�a
(eyebrow of the jungle), or Mont�na or Selva Alta, and descends with
the rush of silt-laden Andean rivers--such as the Mara�on, Huallaga,
Apur�mac, and Urubamba--to the relatively flat, densely forested,
Amazonian plain. These torrential rivers unite as they flow, forming the
Amazon before reaching the burgeoning city of Iquitos. Regarded as an
exotic land of mystery and promise throughout much of the twentieth
century, the Selva has been seen in Peru as the great hope for future
development, wealth, and the fulfillment of national destiny. As such,
it became President Fernando Bela�nde Terry's "Holy Grail" as
he devoted the energies of his two administrations (1963-68, 1980-85) to
promoting colonization, development schemes, and highway construction
across the Monta�a and into the tropical domain.
Human settlements in the Amazonian region are invariably riverine,
clustering at the edges of the hundreds of rivers and oxbow lakes that
in natural conditions are virtual fish farms in terms of their
productivity. The streams and rivers constitute a serpentine network of
pathways plied by boats and canoes that provide the basic transport
through the forest. Here, the Shipibo, Ash�ninka (Campa), Aguaruna, and
other tribes lived in relative independence from the Peruvian state
until the midtwentieth century. Although the native people have cleverly exploited the
extraordinary riverine environment for at least 5,000 years, both they
and the natural system have been under relentless pressures of
population, extractive industries, and the conversion of forest into
farm and pasture. Amazonian forest resources are enormous but not
inexhaustible. Amazonian timber is prized worldwide, but when the great
cedar, rosewood, and mahogany reserves are cut, they are rarely
replaced.
Peru's tropics are also a fabled source for traditional medicinal
plants, such as the four types of domesticated coca, which are prized
through the entire Andean and upper Amazonian sphere, having been widely
traded and bartered for 4,500 years. Unfortunately, coca's traditional
uses as a beneficial drug for dietary, medical, and ritual purposes,
and, during the twentieth century, as a primary flavoring for cola
drinks have given way to illegal plantings on a large scale for cocaine
production. All of the new, illegal plantations are located in Peru's
upper Amazon drainage and have seriously deteriorated the forests,
soils, and general environment where they exist. The use of chemical
sprays and the widespread clearing of vegetation to eliminate illegal
planting has also created unfortunate and extensive environmental
side-effects.
In the early 1990s, the Selva was still considered an important
potential source for new discoveries in the medicinal, fuel, and mineral
fields. Petroleum and gas reserves have been known to exist in several
areas, but remained difficult to exploit. And, in Peru's southern
Amazonian department of Madre de Dios, a gold rush has been in progress
since the 1970s, producing a frontier boom effect with various negative
repercussions. The new population attracted to the region has placed
numerous pressures on the native tribal communities and their lands.
All of these intrusions into the fragile Amazon tropics were fraught
with environmental questions and human dilemmas of major scale. In this
poorly understood environment, hopes and development programs have often
gone awry at enormous cost. In their wake, serious problems of
deforestation, population displacement, challenge to the tribal rights
of the native "keepers of the forest," endless infrastructural
costs, and the explosive expansion of cocaine capitalism have emerged.
In the 1963-90 period, Peru looked to the tropics as the solution for
socioeconomic problems that it did not want to confront in the
highlands. In the early 1990s, it was faced with paradox and quandary in
both areas.
Peru
Peru - The Maritime Region
Peru
A maritime region constitutes a fourth significant environment within
the Peruvian domain. The waters off the Peruvian coast are swept by the
Humboldt (or Peruvian) Current that rises in the frigid Antarctic and
runs strongly northward, cooling the arid South American coastline
before curving into the central Pacific near the Peru-Ecuador border.
Vast shoals of anchovy, tuna, and several varieties of other valued fish
are carried in this stream, making it one of the world's richest
commercial fisheries. The importance of guano has diminished since the
rise of the anchovy fishing industry. The billions of anchovy trapped by
modern flotillas of purse seiners guided by spotter planes and
electronic sounding devices are turned into fish meal for fertilizer and
numerous other industrial uses. Exports of fish meal and fish products
are of critical importance for Peru's economy. For this reason, changes
in the environmental patterns on the coast or in the adjacent ocean have
devastating consequences for employment and, therefore, national
stability. The periodic advent of a warm current flowing south, known as
El Ni�o (The Christ-child), and intensive fishing that has temporarily
depleted the seemingly boundless stocks of anchovy have caused major
difficulties for Peru.
Peru
Peru - Natural Disasters and Their Impact
Peru
Severely affecting conditions on both land and sea, El Ni�o is yet
another peculiarity of the Peruvian environment. This stream of
equatorial water periodically forces its way southward against the
shoreline, pushing the cold Humboldt Current and its vast fishery deeper
and westward into the ocean, while bringing in exotic equatorial
species. El Ni�o is not benign, even though named after the
Christ-child because it has often appeared in December. Instead, over
cycles of fifteen to twenty-five years, El Ni�o disrupts the normally
rainless coastal climate and produces heavy rainfalls, floods, and
consequent damages. The reverse occurs in the highlands, where
drought-like conditions occur, often over two-to-five-year periods,
reducing agricultural production. The impact of this phenomenon came to
be more fully understood only in the 1980s, and it has been shown to
influence Atlantic hurricane patterns as well. Moreover, archaeological
research by Michael Edward Moseley has demonstrated that El Ni�o
turbulence probably led to the heretofore unexplained collapses of
apparently prosperous ancient Andean societies. From 1981 to 1984,
Peruvians experienced severe destruction from this perturbation; the
destruction clearly contributed to the rapidly deteriorating
socioeconomic conditions in the country.
Another major environmental variable is the activity of the Nazca
plate, which abuts Peru along the Pacific shore and constantly forces
the continental land mass upward. Although volcanism created numerous
thermal springs throughout the coastal and highland region and created
such striking volcanic cones as El Misti, which overlooks the city of
Arequipa, it also poses the constant threat of severe earthquakes.
In the Sierra, much farmland rests at the foot of great, unstable
mountains, such as those overlooking the spectacular valley of Callej�n
de Huaylas, which is replete with the evidence of past avalanches and
seismic upheaval. It is also one of the most productive agricultural
areas in the highlands. On May 31, 1970, an earthquake measuring 7.7 on
the Richter scale staggered the department of Ancash and adjacent areas.
A block of glacial ice split from the top of El Huascar�n, Peru's
tallest mountain (6,768 meters), and buried the provincial capital of
Yungay under a blanket of mud and rock, killing about 5,000 people. In
the affected region, 70,000 persons were killed, 140,000 injured, and
over 500,000 left homeless. It was the most destructive disaster in the
history of the Western Hemisphere and had major negative effects on the
national economy and government reform programs at a critical moment
during the administration of Juan Velasco Alvarado (1968-75).
In precolonial times, the Incas and their ancestors had long grappled
with the seismic problem. Many archaeologists have attributed the
special trapezoidal character of Inca architecture to precautions
against earthquakes. The first name of the founder of the Inca empire,
Pachacuti Inca Yupanqui, means "cataclysm." The Incas
understood their terrain. Since 1568 there have been over 70 significant
earthquakes in Peru, or one every six years, although each year the
country registers as many as 200 lesser quakes. As an expression of
their own powerlessness in the face of such events, many Peruvians pray
for protection to a series of earthquake saints. Among such saints are
Cusco's Se�or de los Temblores (Lord of the Tremors), revered since a
disaster in 1650, and the Se�or de los Milagros (Lord of Miracles),
worshipped in Lima and nationwide since a quake in 1655.
Peru
Peru - People, Property, and Farming
Peru
Human adaptation to the high altitudes, coastal desert, and tropical
jungles requires specialized knowledge and skill in addition to the
physiological adjustments noted to cope with altitudinal stress. Over
the course of thousands of years, people invented elaborate irrigation
systems to take advantage of the potential productivity in the coastal
valleys. Visitors to even the smallest coastal valleys can still find
elaborate evidence of these ancient public works. Many of these networks
are still in use or form the basis of rebuilt systems that provide water
to the lucrative commercial agriculture now practiced. Both in
prehistoric times and now, the key to social and political affairs in
these and all other coastal valleys is access to water, effective
irrigation technology, and the ability to keep a large labor force at
the task of construction and maintenance.
The coastal valleys from colonial times to the present have been
dominated by extensive systems of plantation agriculture, with powerful
elite families in control of the land and water rights. The principal
crops harvested under these regimes are sugarcane and cotton, with a
mixture of other crops, such as grapes and citrus, also being planted.
Before the Agrarian Reform Law of 1969, about 80 percent of the arable
coastal land was owned by 1.7 percent of the property owners. Despite
the dominance of the great coastal estates, there were, and still are,
thousands of smaller farms surrounding them, producing a wide variety of
food crops for the urban markets and for subsistence. Since land reform,
ownership of the great plantations has been transferred to the employees
and workers, who operate them as a type of cooperative. The coastal
farmland is extremely valuable because of the generous climate, flat
lands, and usually reliable irrigation waters, without which nothing
would succeed. These advantageous conditions are supplemented by the use
of excellent guano and fish-meal fertilizers. As a result, the
productive coastal land, amounting to only 3.8 percent of the national
total, including pasture and forest, yields a reported 50 percent of the
gross agricultural product.
In the intermontane Andean valleys, there is a wide variety of
farming opportunities. The best lands are those that benefit year round
from the constant flow of melting glacial waters. Most farming depends
on the advent of the rains, and farmers must plan their affairs
accordingly. In many areas, farmers have built reservoir and canal
systems, but, for the most part, they must time their planting to
coincide with the capricious onset of the rainy season. Where irrigation
works are operative, as on the coast, farmers are joined in
water-management districts and irrigation boards, which govern water
flow, canal maintenance, and enforcement of complex water rights, rules,
and customs.
Over 70 percent of the smallest farms are less than five hectares in
size, with the great majority of them found in the Andean highlands. A
typical peasant household with such a small property cannot harvest
anything but the most minimum subsistence from it and inevitably must
supplement household earnings from other sources, with most or all
family members working. The adequacy of each small farm and its
dispersed chacras (plots of land used for gardening) of course
varies with water supply, altitude, soil fertility, and other local
factors. The best irrigated farmland in the kichwa valleys
tends to be highly subdivided in the competition for a rural subsistence
base. The largest land holdings are the property of corporate
communities, such as the numerous Peasant Communities (Comunidades
Campesinas) and Peasant Groups (Grupos Campesinos). In 1990 these
official forms of common entitlement, as opposed to individual private
ownership, accounted for over 60 percent of pasture lands, much of which
lies in the punas of the southern Andes.
The ecological mandates of the Andean environment thus structure the
day-to-day farming activities of all highlanders and the character of
their domestic economies. Research conducted by anthropologist Stephen
B. Brush showed how peasant farmers traditionally have utilized the
different ecological niches at their disposal. At the highest altitudes
of production, animals are grazed and specialized tubers grown; at the
intermediate altitudes grains like wheat, barley, rye, and corn, as well
as pulses, such as broad beans, peas, and lentils, are sown along with a
wide variety of vegetables, including onions, squashes, carrots, hot rocoto
peppers, and tomatoes. At still lower levels, tropical fruits and crops
prosper.
Some communities have direct access to all of these production
environments, whereas others may be confined to one zone only.
Traditionally, the strategy of families, the basic social units of
production and consumption, is to arrange access to products from the
different zones through the social mechanisms available to them.
Particular chacras serve as virtual chess pieces as families
buy and sell property, or enter into sharecropping arrangements in order
to obtain access to specific cropping areas. Marital arrangements may
also be made with specific properties in mind. Thus, the system of small
farms (
minifundios) will invariably involve a
confusing but systematic pattern of holdings.
In Huaylas, Ancash Department, for example, farmers owning small but
highly productive irrigated chacras at about 2,700 meters
cultivate corn, vegetables, and alfalfa. Slightly higher irrigated
property is devoted to grains, and higher still, chacras are
devoted to potatoes, oca and other tubers, and quinoa. Above the
cultivated land and on the nonirrigated hillsides, cattle and sheep are
grazed on communally held open ranges and puna. In the deep protected
gorges and canyons on the fringes of the district, small chacras
at altitudes of 1,500 meters produce a variety of tropical crops.
Consequently, within a relatively small area a single family may own or
have usufruct rights to a checkerboard of small chacras, whose
total area does not exceed four or five hectares, but whose range of
production provides a diverse nutritional subsistence base.
For this reason, attempts to unify smallholdings to make them more
efficient can likely yield the opposite effect in terms of the household
economy. This is, in fact, what happened in many areas after the
Agrarian Reform Law of 1969 was implemented, prohibiting sharecropping
and restricting the geographical range of ownership in order to achieve
hoped for economies
of scale. After the initial attempts to enforce the
new, well-meaning laws, the minifundio system began to reemerge
as peasants discovered ways to circumvent its restrictions, which
inadvertently limited their ownership and use of chacras to a
narrow range of ecological zones.
In other areas, such as those described by Enrique Mayer in the Hu�nuco
region, the relatively compressed ecology found in Huaylas gives way to
one spread out over the eastern flanks of the Andes, stretching down
eventually to the Selva. In contrast to the confining peasant farms of
Huaylas, farmers in the Hu�nuco region develop barter and trade
relations across the production zones, permitting them to exchange their
farm produce, such as potatoes, for other crops grown at different
levels.
Although most Andean farmers are independent producers, there are
various types of large holdings, of which three are particularly
important: the manorial estate, the minifundio and family farm,
and the corporate community holding. Historically, the most significant
holdings relative to socioeconomic power were the great manorial
properties known as haciendas, which averaged over 1,200 hectares in
size but often exceeded 20,000 hectares prior to being eliminated during
the 1969-75 land reform. At the time the land reform began, 1.3 percent
of the highland farm owners held over 75 percent of the farm and grazing
lands, while 96 percent of the farmers held ownership of but 8.5 percent
of the farm area. The corporate community holdings are in the form of
land held in common title by a Peasant Community. After the land reform,
groups of communities were organized as corporate bodies by the
government to enable them, in theory, to combine lands and resources to
gain the advantages of an economy of scale. These organizations and the
Peasant Communities, reportedly numbering 5,500 in 1991, assumed titles
to the haciendas expropriated during the reform period.
By contrast, the population living in the Selva is engaged in a
totally different set of agroecological patterns of activity. The native
peoples of the tropics, living in riverine settings for the greater
part, depend on fishing, hunting, and selective gathering from the
forest. They also engage in highly effective horticulture, usually in a
system known as slash-and-burn. Long thought to be a destructive and
inefficient method of farming, studies have revealed it to be quite the
contrary. In this system, the tribal farmer usually exploits a
particular plot for only a three-to-five-year period and then abandons
it to open another fresh area. This practice allows the vegetation and
thin soil to recuperate before the farmer returns to use it again in ten
to twenty years. Another facet of the system is that all fields are used
in a pattern of multicropping. In this approach, as many as fifteen
different crops are intermingled in such a way that each plant
complements the others in terms of nutrients used or returned to the
soil. The arrangement also provides a disadvantageous environment for
plant diseases and insect pests. Another common horticultural system
employed along the river banks in the dry season takes advantage of
extensive silt deposits left by the seasonal floods. On such open plots,
farmers tend to monocrop or, at least, to reduce the number of varieties
sown.
Peru
Peru - The Society
Peru
PERUVIANNESS (PERUANIDAD) has often been debated by Peruvian
authors who evoke patriotism, faith, cultural mystique, and other
allegedly intrinsic qualities of nationality. Peru, however, is not to
be characterized as a homogeneous culture, nor its people as one people.
Peruvians speak of their differences with certainty, referring to lo
criollo ("of the Creole"), lo serrano ("of
the highlander"), and other special traits by which social groups
and regions are stereotyped. The national creole identity incorporates a
combination of unique associations and ways of doing things a la
criolla.
The dominant national culture emanating from Lima is urban,
bureaucratic, street-oriented, and fast-paced. Yet the identity that
goes with being a lime�o (a Limean) is also profoundly
provincial in its own way. In the first half of the twentieth century,
the Lima cultural character transcended class values and ranks and to a
significant degree was identified as the national Peruvian culture. The
great migrations from 1950 to 1990 altered that personality
substantially. By 1991 the national character, dominated by the urban
style of Lima, was complicated by millions of serranos, whose
rural Spanish contrasts with the fast slurring and slang of the Lima
dialect. Highland music is heard twenty-four hours a day on more than a
dozen Lima radio stations that exalt the regional cultures, give
announcements in Quechua, and relentlessly advertise the new businesses
of the migrant entrepreneurs. The places mentioned and the activities
announced are in greater Lima, but unknown to the lime�o. The
new lime�o, while acquiring creole traits, nevertheless
presents another face, one with which the Lima native does not closely
relate and does not understand because few true lime�os
actually visit the provinces, much less stay there to live. Nor do they
visit the sprawling "young towns" ( pueblos jovenes)
of squatters that are disdained or even feared. Urban Hispanic Peruvians
have always been caught in the bind of contradiction, at once claiming
the glory of the Inca past while refusing to accept its descendants or
their traditions as legitimately belonging in the modern state. In the
early 1990s, however, this change was taking place, desired or not.
Events have been forcing the alteration of traditions in both the
coast (Costa) and highlands (Sierra) in a process that would again
transform the country, as did both conquest and independence. The
peoples of the Altiplano and valleys of the Andean heartland--long
exploited and neglected and driven both by real needs and the quest for
respect and equity--have surged over the country in a
"reconquest" of Peru, stamping it with their image.
For respect and equity to develop, the white and mestizo elites will
have to yield the social and economic space for change and reconcile
themselves to institutional changes that provide fairness in life
opportunities. Up to 1991, the highlanders (serranos) had
seized that space from a reluctant nation by aggressive migration,
establishing vast squatter settlements and pushing hard against the
walls of power. As with the Agrarian Reform Law of 1969, the elites and
special interests that benefited from traditional socioeconomic
arrangements had protected these old ways with few concessions to wider
public and national needs. For the cholo, Peru's generic
"everyman," to gain a place of respect, well-being, and a
sense of progress will be a test of endurance, experiment, and sacrifice
as painful and difficult as any in the hemisphere. With the agony of
terroristic and revengeful revolution perpetrated by the Shining Path
(Sendero Luminoso--SL) and the T�pac Amaru Revolutionary Movement
(Movimiento Revolucionario T�pac Amaru--MRTA), on the one hand, and the
chaotic collapse of the institutional formal economy, on the other,
average Peruvians from all social groups were caught between the
proverbial "sword and wall."
Just as the highland migration to the urban coast was the major
avenue for social change through the 1980s, increasing numbers of
Peruvians sought to continue this journey away from the dilemmas of
their homeland by moving to other countries. About 700,000 had emigrated
by 1991, with over 40 percent going to the United States. Catholic
University of Peru professor Te�filo Altamirano has documented the new
currents of mobility that went from Lima, Jun�n, and Ancash to every
state in the United States, with heaviest concentrations in New Jersey,
New York, California, and Florida. In 1990 about 300,000 of Altamirano's
compatriots (paisanos) lived--either legally or not--in the
United States.
In the early 1990s, Peru's identity as a nation and people was
becoming more complex and cosmopolitan, while the distinctive traits of
the culture were being broadened, disseminated, and shared by an
increasingly wider group of citizens. The crosscurrents to these trends
were configured around the struggle for retention and status of the
native cultures: the Quechua, the Aymara, and the many tribal societies
of Amazonia. Whereas tens of thousands deliberately embarked on
life-plans of social mobility by altering their persona from indio
(Indian) to cholo to mestizo in moving from the native American
caste to upper-middle class, a new alternative for some was to use
ethnic loyalty and identity as a device of empowerment and, thus, an
avenue for socioeconomic change. How Peruvian institutions, state
policy, and traditions adjusted to these trends would determine what
Peruvians as a society would be like in the twenty-first century.
Peru
Peru - Population
Peru
The special configuration and character of Peru's modern society owe
their start to the Spanish conquest, when Europeans and Africans came
into sexual contact with what had been a racially homogeneous
population. In its own conquests, however, the Inca Empire had embraced
a wide range of cultural groups that spoke over fifty languages and
practiced diverse customs. As a multicultural state, the Incas had
grappled with the problem of tribal diversity and competition, often
resolving their disagreements with conquered peoples through violence
and repression. Another Inca solution to such dilemmas was to forcibly
relocate recalcitrant populations to more governable locations and
replace them with trustworthy communities. Peoples resettled in this
manner were called mitimaes, and the process contributed
significantly to the complications of Andean ethnicity. In addition to
these measures, the Incas often took the children of local leaders and
other key personages as hostages to guarantee political tranquility. In
some ways, then, the Inca experience harshly prefigured the Spanish
conquest.
With the arrival of conquering migrants from the Old World, new mixed
races were born. The initial importance of these offspring of whites and
Africans with native American mothers was minimal, however, because of
the "great dying" of the indigenous population instigated by
European diseases and the subsequent collapse and demoralization of the
native society and economy. The continuous impact of repressive colonial
regimes did not permit any resurgence of native vitality or
organization, although there were a number of rebellions and revolts.
Under these conditions, Peru reached its nadir in 1796, near the end of
the colonial period, when fewer than 1.1 million inhabitants were
censured. This figure marked a fall from an estimated pre-Columbian
total of at least 16 million, although some scholars think the figure
may be twice that number, and others less. Peru recovered slowly, only
slightly exceeding its minimally estimated preconquest population size
in 1981.
The critical factors in population growth since the midnineteenth
century have been the rapid emergence of the mestizo population, which
grew at a rate of over 3 percent per year throughout the colonial period
until the 1980s, and the reduction but not the disappearance of sweeping
epidemic diseases. Another factor that played a role in this increase
was the influx of foreign migrants from Europe, and especially from
China and, more recently, Japan. The rate of growth became very high
during the twentieth century owing to a number of factors. The then
dominant mestizo and other mixed populations were obviously more
resistant to the diseases to which the native peoples, lacking natural
immunities, succumbed. The mestizos also enjoyed important cultural
advantages in a colonialist society, which actively discriminated
against the native population on racial and ethnic grounds. From
conquest to the present, it has been the fate of the native peoples not
to prosper.
The Spanish colonial policy regarding population management in the
viceroyalty, as throughout the hemisphere, was to create bureaucratic
order through an official hierarchy of caste, with obligations and
privileges attached thereto. The system attempted to keep people sorted
out according to genealogical history and place of birth. Thus, white
Spaniards ranked first, followed by all others: a male offspring of a
Spaniard and a native American was called a mestizo, or cholo;
of a Spaniard and African, a mulatto; of an African and a native
American, a zambo; of a mestizo and indio, a salta
atr�s (jump backward). The order encompassed all of the
combinations and recombinations of race, with over fifty commonly used
terms, many of which--such as mestizo, mulatto, zambo, cholo,
criollo, indio, negro (Negro or black), and blanco
(white)--survive in common usage today. For both white Europeans and
Africans, there were two categories--those born in the Old World were
called peninsulares and bosales, respectively, whereas
those of both races born in Peru were called criollos (Creoles). In the
case of whites, the fact that Creoles were lower in rank than their
peninsular counterparts was resented and contributed eventually to the
overthrow of colonial rule.
There were six basic castes in Colonial Peru: Spaniards, native
Americans, mestizos, Negroes, mulattos, and zambos. In theory,
these categories defined a person's place of residence and occupation,
taxes, obligations to the viceroyalty under the mita, which
churches and masses could be attended, and which parts of the towns
could be entered. Sumptuary laws determined the nature of one's clothing
as well, and prohibited natives in particular from riding horses, using
buttons, having weapons, and even owning mirrors and playing stringed
instruments. Such a system was hard, if not impossible, to keep on
track, and its rules and powers were irregularly applied. Nevertheless,
vestiges of the colonial social caste system and its associated behavior
and attitudes linger in present-day Peruvian society in many ways.
Although largely replaced along the coast by mestizos,
Afro-Peruvians, and Chinese laborers, the native peoples survived
biologically as well as culturally in the highlands. Their survival was
attributed to many factors: the sheer numbers of their original
population; their relative isolation, resulting in part from the
collapse of the society and inefficiency of the colonial regimes; and
this assumption of the kind of passive defensive posture of silence and
apparent submissive behavior that has been characterized as a
"weapon of the weak." In numerous cases, communities managed
to place themselves under the wing of religious orders and, ironically,
the hacienda system, with its conditions of serfdom. This developed with
the demise of the system of serfdom called the encomienda and
the state monopoly of selling goods to the native peoples called the repartimiento.
If nothing more, by becoming serfs on the haciendas, native Americans
were defended by landlords, who were inclined to protect their peons
from exploitation by others and especially from having to serve in the mita
de minas (the mine labor draft). Consequently, the bastions of
highland indigenous culture have been the small, isolated mountain
villages and hamlets; dispersed farming and pastoral communities; and
haciendas, where populations were encapsulated under protective
exploitation and ignored by their absentee landlords.
<>Settlement Patterns
<>Urban, Rural, and
Regional Populations
<>Demography of Growth,
Migration, and Work
<>Regionalism and Political
Divisions
Updated population figures for Peru.
Peru
Peru - Settlement Patterns
Peru
In pre-Columbian eras, the highland population was ensconced on
ridges, hillsides, and other locations that did not interfere with
farming priorities. Large ceremonial buildings, temples, or
administrative centers, were, however, located in central locations,
often apart from the residences of average persons. By the time of
conquest, the Incas had rearranged settlements to suit their own vision
of administrative needs in conquered areas. Thus, Inca planners and
architects constructed special towns and cities, such as Hu�nuco Viejo,
to handle their needs.
With Viceroy Francisco Toledo y Figueroa's colonial reforms in the
late sixteenth century, however, the traditional Andean settlement
patterns were drastically altered through the establishment of
settlements called reductions (
reducciones), which were located in the less
advantageous areas, and the founding of new Spanish towns and cities.
The reduction system forced native Americans to settle in nucleated
villages and towns, which were easily controlled by their masters, the encomenderos, as well as clergy and regional governors (
corregidores de indios). The Spaniards also
established their own towns, which were off limits to most native
peoples except for occasional religious celebrations or for work
assignments. These towns eventually became home to the dominant mestizo.
As the municipal and economic centers of each district and province,
these mestizo towns (poblachos mestizos) remain the dominant
settlements, constituting the district and provincial capitals
throughout the country. Today, virtually all of the small towns and
villages throughout the highlands are either the product of the
reduction system of forced relocation or were established as Spanish
colonial municipalities.
The striking similarities among settlements in terms of design and
architecture are no accident. Virtually all settlements thus exhibit the
grid pattern or model of rectangular blocks arranged around a town
square, universally known as the arms plaza (plaza de armas).
This design reflects the military dimension of the conquest culture, the
central place in an encampment being where armaments were kept when not
deployed. By direct analogy, it also demonstrates and symbolizes central
authority and power. Typically, then, the most important residents lived
close to the plaza de armas, in the most prominent houses.
Status, conferred by birth, race, and occupation, was confirmed by a
central urban residence. In modern practice, status has continued to be
reflected in a hierarchy of urban residence descending from Lima to the
departmental, provincial, and district capitals. No one of importance or
power is rural.
Peru.
Peru
Peru - Urban, Rural, and Regional Populations
Peru
The change in distribution from rural to urban has been profound: the
urban population rose from 47 percent in 1961 to an estimated 70 percent
in 1990. By that time, Peru's population had reached a point where its
configurations were thus substantially different than they were a
generation earlier, largely because of the enormous growth of
metropolitan Lima, which includes the seaport of Callao. Indeed, four of
the largest political districts of greater Lima began as squatter
settlements and now would rank among the nation's top ten cities if they
had been counted separately. The leading cities in Peru represent a mix
of old colonial places--Lima, Arequipa, Trujillo, Cusco (Cuzco), Piura,
and Ica--and newly emergent ones, such as Huancayo, Chimbote, Iquitos,
and Juliaca, whose new elites derive mostly from the highly mobile
provincial middle and lower classes. In the Sierra, Juliaca, because of its role in
marketing and transportation, surpassed the departmental capital of Puno
in both size and importance to become the most important city south of
Cusco.
Burgeoning cities, such as the industrial port of Chimbote, had a
kind of raw quality to them in the early 1990s, with blocks and blocks
of recently constructed one- and two-story buildings and a majority of
streets neither paved nor cobbled. As the site of Peru's prestige
industry--an electrically powered steel mill-- and as a major port for
the anchovy industry, Chimbote attracted bilingual mestizos and cholos,
who continued to pour into the city from the highlands of Ancash,
especially the provinces of Huaylas, Corongo, Pallasca, and Sihuas. The
migrants' dynamism, powered by a will to progress and modernize, built
the city from a quaint seaside town of 4,200 residents in 1940 to
296,000 in 1990, with neither the approval nor significant assistance of
government planners or development programs. Although the energy and
growth of Chimbote was impressive, the lack of urban infrastructure in
the basic services, absence of attention to environmental impacts, and
totally inadequate municipal budgets led directly to converting Chimbote
Bay, the best natural port on Peru's coast, into a cesspool of
industrial and urban wastes (meters thick in places). Even smaller
coastal boom towns, such as Supe, have suffered the same outcomes. It
was not surprising that the 1991 cholera outbreak should have started in
Chimbote.
Just as the cities have grown, the rural sector's share of the
population has declined. Nevertheless, in the early 1990s there were
still more persons living in the rural regions than ever before in the
nation's history. In fact, the rural population in 1991 equaled the
total population of the country in 1961.
At first, the country seemed to relish its growth even though the
population explosion distressed the urbane sensibilities of the elite
and the comfortable middle classes. Through its increase in size, Peru
gained stature internationally and maintained a superiority of sorts
vis-�-vis Ecuador, Bolivia, and Chile, its regional rivals. It could be
maintained that Peru's policy was to let the population problem
"solve itself" through spontaneous migration by which people
found their own solutions for the maldistribution of wealth, services,
resources, and power. The vast and growing squatter settlements in Lima,
however, gave many serious pause, and alternatives were proposed.
Peru.
Peru
Peru - Demography of Growth, Migration, and Work
Peru
Significant in different ways were the divisions according to the
major ecological zones. In 1990 the coastal region held 53 percent of
the nation's peoples; the highlands, 36 percent; and the Selva, the
other 11 percent. This distribution pattern marked an abrupt change from
almost thirty years earlier when the figures for coast and highlands
were nearly the reverse. These shifts obviously had significant
implications for the nation in terms of government, the economy, and
social relations. For example, the agricultural sector had two parts:
the mechanized high-export production of the coastal plantations and
cooperatives, and the intensively farmed small-holdings of the Sierra,
which have depended most heavily on hand labor and were essentially
unchanged in technology since the colonial period. Although the highland
farm technology was effective, Andean production was undermined by
urbanward migrations and the revolution and repression of the 1980s.
Within the contexts of these significant demographic changes, the
general growth of the population has been constant since its low point
at the end of the colonial period. Between 1972 and 1981, the country
grew by 25 percent. The increase may have been greater between 1981 and
1991, reaching over 30 percent, if projections were correct. The
increase ran counter to the anticipated benefits stemming from the
continued drop in fertility rates, which declined from 6.7 children born
per woman in 1965 to 3.3 in 1991, and in birth rates, which dropped from
a high of 45 births per 1,000 in 1965 to 27 per 1,000 in 1992. The crude
death rates, however, despite the many problems in health care, fell
over this same period from 16 to 7 per 1,000, basically matching the
decline in the birthrate and retaining the actual rate of population
growth near its same level as before. Life expectancy for males in Peru
has increased from fifty-one years in 1980 to estimates of sixty-three
years in 1991, second lowest in South America after Bolivia.
Demographers projected that Peru's population would reach 28 million by
the year 2000 and 37 million in 2025 if these rates continued.
Contemporary dilemmas paled before the problems posed by such estimates.
A significant lowering in infant deaths would markedly increase the
overall growth rate and accompanying problems posed to institutions,
services, and resources.
Population Policy and Family Planning
The issue of slowing population growth through the systematic
implementation of modern birth-control methods had remained lowkey since
the late 1960s but erupted during the 1980s, as a result of pressure
coming particularly from women. Research in the early 1980s showed that
over 75 percent of women wished to use contraceptives, but over 50
percent did not do so out of fear and uncertainty about their effects or
because of the disapproval of the spouse. In this context, the 1985 Law
of the National Population Council came into being under the premise
that although abortion and voluntary sterilization were excluded, all
other "medical, educational, and information services about family
planning guarantee that couples and all persons can freely choose the
method for control of fecundity and for family planning." The
proposed law was opposed in 1987 by the Assembly of Catholic Bishops,
which retained its opposition to artificial methods and
"irresponsible philosophies." Implementation of the law,
however, began that year, setting targets for lowering fecundity rates
to 2.5 children per family by the year 2000 and greatly amplifying the
availability of clinical resources and contraceptives. In addition to
government programs, there were sixteen private organizations promoting
various aspects of the policy by 1988.
In 1986 a reported 46 percent of women of child-bearing age were
using some form of contraception, but it was not known what percentage
of men used contraceptives. The data on the incidence of abortions was
not compiled until the 1980s, but according to hospital reports, in 1986
there were 31,860 abortions performed for life-threatening sociomedical
reasons, which represented almost 43 percent of all hospital cases
involving obstetrical procedures. The estimated rate of clandestine
abortions, however, was reportedly at the high rate of 143 cases per
1,000 pregnancies, despite a law that in theory prohibited such
interventions. A survey in 1986 of women's attitudes toward
contraception and family planning showed that over 27 percent of women
would halt their family size after one child, 69 percent would limit
their family to two, and over 80 percent desired no more than three
children. It was clear from this response that Peruvian women wanted to
limit family size and that their demands for increased state and private
services would continue to rise.
During the 1975-90 period, contraceptives became more widely
available throughout Peru, being distributed or sold nationwide through
Ministry of Health programs and private clinics, pharmacies, and even by
street vendors in marketplaces. Pharmacies were the most common source
of both information about and supply of contraceptives. Not
surprisingly, use of birthcontrol techniques increased sharply with
socioeconomic status, educational level, and urban coastal residence.
Lima and the Patterns of Migration
The first Bela�nde administration (1963-68) initiated concerted
efforts to develop the Amazon Basin through its ambitious Jungle Border
Highway (la carretera marginal de la selva or la marginal)
program, the organization of colonization projects, and special
opportunity zones to steer highland migrants in that direction and away
from the coast. Bela�nde's Selva-oriented program thus tended to divert
investments away from the Sierra, even though much was done there on a
small local scale through the self-help Popular Cooperation (Cooperaci�n
Popular) projects. In hindsight, the resulting degradation of the
tropical biosphere in the wake of these schemes created new sets of
problems that were far from anyone's mind in 1964. Unfortunately, the
net result of these expensive and sweeping efforts at tropical
development has not been as planned. Significant changes in the
direction of migration did not take place, and the jungle perimeter road
system covering hundreds of kilometers was often used as landing strips
by airborne drug traffickers and for military maneuvers.
Just as there are strong "pull" factors that attract
persons to Lima and the other major cities, there are also many
conditions that "push" people out of their communities: the
loss or lack of adequate farmland, natural disasters such as earthquakes
and landslides, lack of employment options, and a host of personal
reasons. In addition, since the outbreak of terrorist activities by the
Shining Path movement in 1980 and subsequent military reactions, over
30,000 persons have been dislocated from towns and villages in the
Ayacucho and Huancavelica highlands, most of them gravitating to Ica or
Lima.
The profound changes during the 1950-90 period, spurred by sheer
increases in numbers, largely resulted from a desire for better life
opportunities and progress. The significant demographic change that took
place was the migration from rural areas to the cities, especially Lima.
Five major features gave this great migration a particular Peruvian
character: the concentration of people in Lima and other coastal cities,
the regional heterogeneity of the migrants, the tendency of people to
follow their family and paisanos to specific places, the
development of migrant organizations, and the willingness of migrants to
assist their homelands.
The migrants, searching for employment and better living conditions,
went predominantly from the provinces to the national capital, creating
a megalopolis out of Lima and Callao. In 1990 greater Lima had over 30
percent of all Peruvians as residents. On the north coast, cities such
as Piura, Chiclayo, and Trujillo have attracted persons from their own
regions in considerable numbers; significant growth has occurred in the
southern highland cities of Arequipa, Juliaca, and Cusco, as well as in
the remote jungle city of Iquitos. Despite rates of increase averaging
more than 330 percent between 1961 and 1990, these cities drew few
people compared to the numbers of persons drawn to greater Lima. In 1990
Lima was 14 percent larger than the next 24 cities combined, and 58
percent of all urban dwellers lived in greater Lima. As such, Lima had
become one of the world's leading cities in terms of its level of
primacy, that is, its overwhelming demographic dominance with respect to
the next largest urban centers.
Lima's development as a "primate" city (megalopolis) began
taking shape during the nineteenth century when the nation was
recuperating from the disastrous War of the Pacific (1879-83) with
Chile. This trend accelerated dramatically after about 1950, when the
fishing industry began its expansion and Peru started to industrialize
its urban economy in a determined manner. Thus, throughout most of this
long period, no less than a third of the capital's residents were born
elsewhere.
Lima's dominance has been more than demographic. In the late 1980s,
the metropolis consumed over 70 percent of the nation's electrical
energy; had 69 percent of its industry, 98 percent of private
investment, and 83 percent of bank deposits; yielded 83 percent of the
nation's taxes; had 42 percent of all university students, taught by 62
percent of all professors; and had 73 percent of the nation's
physicians. Over 70 percent of the country's wages were paid out in Lima
to 40 percent of all school teachers, 51 percent of public employees,
and equivalent percentages of the skilled labor force and other urban
workers. From television and radio stations to telephones, most consumer
goods, recreational facilities, and other items of modern interest were
also concentrated in Lima. In short, if Peru had it, it came first to
Lima and more often than not was unavailable elsewhere.
Government, too, has been totally centralized in the capital since
the establishment of the viceregal court in the sixteenth century. The
centrality of Lima in colonial times was so significant that persons
committing crimes were often punished by exiling them from the capital
for various periods of time; the farther away, the worse the penalty.
This notion still underlies much of the cultural concept of social value
in Peru today. Everyone living outside of greater Lima is automatically
a provincial (provinciano), a person defined as being
disadvantaged and, perhaps, not quite as civilized as a lime�o.
Under such circumstances, it is hardly surprising that Lima has
attracted the vast majority of Peruvians hoping to improve their lives,
whether looking for employment, seeking an education, or attempting to
influence bureaucratic decisions and win assistance for their
communities. Lima has been both hated and loved by provincianos,
who have been engaged in unequal struggle for access to the nation's
wealth and power. The factor of primacy loomed as one of Peru's most
significant problems, as the nation attempted to decentralize various
aspects of the government under a reorganization law promulgated in
March 1987.
Another aspect of the migration had to do with its heterogeneity of
origin in terms of both place and sociocultural features. At the
beginning of the twentieth century, most of the provincial migrants were
fairly homogeneous representatives of local elites and relatively
prosperous sectors of provincial urban capitals. The last decades of the
century, however, have seen a marked growth in the social and cultural
diversity of the migrants. Between 1950 and 1990, increasing numbers of
persons came from villages and hamlets, not the small district capitals,
and thus were more representative of the bilingual and bicultural
population, referred to as cholos. Whereas in the earlier years
of this period, it was unusual to hear migrants speaking the Quechua or
Aymara languages on the street, by 1990 it was commonplace to hear these
languages used for commerce and general discourse in Lima. This change
occurred mostly after 1970, when the populist military regime of Juan
Velasco Alvarado began a strong effort to legitimize the native tongues.
And thus, it has also become more common to see persons retaining
various aspects of their regional clothing styles, including hats and
colorful skirts, and in, general, not discarding those cultural class
markers that were so denigrated a short generation earlier.
A third migratory pattern was that people invariably followed in the
footsteps of relatives and fellow paisanos. Once a village had
a few paisanos established in the city, they were soon followed
by others. During the course of Peruvian migration, relatively few
persons simply struck out on the migratory adventure alone. Thus, the
society of migrants was not a collection of alienated "lost
souls," but rather consisted of groups of people with contacts,
social roles, and strong cultural and family ties.
This fact produced the fourth dimension of the Peruvian migratory
process: the propensity of migrants to organize themselves into
effective voluntary associations. The scale and pattern of these
associations distinguished the process in Peru from that in most other
countries. The organizations have taken several forms, but the two most
outstanding examples are found in the squatter settlements and regional
clubs that have proliferated in all the largest cities, particularly
Lima. The process of urban growth in Lima has produced an urban
configuration that conforms to no central plan. Without access to
adequate housing of any type, and without funds or available loans,
migrants set about developing their own solutions by establishing
organizations of their own, occasionally under the sponsorship of APRA.
They planned a takeover of unoccupied land at the fringes of the city
and, with the suddenness and effectiveness of a military attack, invaded
the property, usually on a Saturday night.
Once on the land, the migrants laid out plots with precision and
raised temporary housing in a matter of hours. Called by the somewhat
deprecatory term barriada, the shantytowns quickly developed
both an infrastructural and a sociopolitical permanence, despite initial
official disapproval and police harassment. At first, the land invasions
and barriada formation provoked enormous unease among
traditional lime�os and especially in the halls of government.
The barriadas were wildly characterized as dangerous slums by
the Lima middle- and upper classes, which felt threatened by the
squatters. Research by anthropologist Jos� Matos Mar Santos and others
demonstrated beyond doubt, however, that these "spontaneous
settlements" were, in fact, solutions to grave urban problems.
Subsequent research by anthropologist Susan Lobo established that such
settlements were civilly organized and rapidly assumed positive urban
attributes under the squatters' own initiatives.
In 1990 there were over 400 of these large settlements surrounding
Lima and Callao, containing at least half of Lima's population. Over
time, many of them--such as San Mart�n de Porres, Comas, and Pamplona
Alta--had become new political districts within the province of Lima,
with their own elected officials and political power. Political
scientists Henry A. Deitz and David Collier have called attention to
squatter organizations as mechanisms of empowerment for persons
otherwise denied a base or place in the political system. An important
step for the squatters was the acquisition of the skill and the ability
to exercise influence in the corridors of bureaucratic power. As these
settlements and their organizations gained public legitimacy in the
1960s, the Velasco government, on assuming power in 1968, soon renamed
them pueblos jovenes, a name which was quickly adopted and has
remained.
The regional club aspect of Peru's urban migration was not as obvious
a phenomenon as the ubiquitous squatter settlements. The need for a
social life, as well as the desire to maintain contact with the home
community, friends, and relatives, had moved migrants from particular
villages and towns to create representative organizations based on their
common place of origin. As a result, according to Te�filo Altamirano,
in 1990 there were over 6,000 such clubs in greater Lima, with hundreds
more to be found in the other major cities. Not only have these clubs
provided an important social venue for migrants, but they also have
served as a vehicle by which members could give not insubstantial
assistance to their homeland (terru�o), when called for.
Peru.
Peru
Peru - Regionalism and Political Divisions
Peru
The formidable mountain ranges, deep chasms, and deserts that
partition the habitable regions of Peru contribute greatly to the
formation and maintenance of political and social identities by
facilitating or obstructing communication, as well as by creating
economic diversity through zonal specializations. Archaeologists and
ethnohistorians have identified some forty-four different highland
cultures and thirty-eight more in coastal valleys that existed at the
time of the rise of the Inca Empire in the fifteenth century.
Tawantinsuyu (Land of the Four Quarters) retained these preexisting
ethnogeographic zones in one form or another, according to
anthropologist Michael Edward Moseley, establishing at least eighty
ethnically distinct political provinces throughout the empire's vast
territory.
The policies of the Tawantinsuyu presaged subsequent geopolitical
territorial arrangements. The "quarters" were unequal in size
and population, but roughly corresponded to the cardinal directions.
Each region began with its cobbled roadway leaving the "navel"
of the city of <"http://worldfacts.us/Peru-Cusco.htm">Cusco, whose perimeters shaped a symbolic Andean puma. To
the north, Chinchaysuyu encompassed most of the coast and highlands of
modern Peru, from Nazca, and eventually with conquest, to what is now
northern Ecuador. In terms of the divisions of the Inca Empire, 68
percent of Peruvians in 1990 lived in Chinchaysuyu. To the south
stretched the vast region of the puna and Lake Titicaca Basin called the
Collasuyu. With the Inca conquests, the Collasuyu quarter extended to
the R�o Maule in what is now central Chile. To the east and west were
two relatively small quarters, the Antisuyu and Cuntisuyu, respectively.
The former occupied the forested semitropical highland region called
Monta�a, and the latter, the arid mountains and coast encompassing
present-day Arequipa and adjacent departments. Seen in this perspective,
41 percent of the people lived in four departments occupying the central
region of the country, with 27 percent in the northern area, 23 percent
in the south, and 8 percent in the Amazonian departments of the east in
1990. These four modern quarters of Peru often have been utilized in the
context of planning studies.
The Spaniards reorganized the Tawantinsuyu on discovering that the
highland Inca capitals at Cusco and Cuenca (Ecuador) and their own first
choice of Jauja near present-day Huancayo suited neither their
physiological nor political needs. When they founded Lima, the Spaniards
turned the Inca spatial concepts upside down: centrality and place were
reoriented as Cusco became a province and no longer was the "navel
of the universe" from which all roads departed. Despite this
change, Spanish viceregal organization educed its structure from
longstanding ethnolinguistic and ecological realities. The Spaniards
formed provinces ( corregimientos), which later became
intendancies (intendencias), as well as Catholic dioceses or
parishes.
With independence, the colonial territories were again redefined, but
in most cases, the "new" politico-administrative boundaries
still recalled ancient cultural and linguistic outlines. The republic
carried forward many operational aspects of the colonial administrative
units. Throughout their national history, Peruvians have demonstrated a
propensity to revise their political affairs both with respect to
leadership and the boundaries within the nation. In 1980 the department
of Ucayali was created by splintering off two provinces from the Selva
department of Loreto, a reflection of development and population
increases in that immense tropical region. Moreover, after the census in
1981, six new provinces in Cajamarca, Ancash, and Ucayali departments
and twenty new districts were created in various parts of the country
through legislative acts. The new districts included six in the populous
highland department of Cajamarca; three each in Ucayali, Puno, and
Ancash; two in the province of Lima; and others in the departments of Hu�nuco
and Cusco. Each time a census occurs, political and social identities
are further refined, usually building on old traditions of similitude,
as well as a desire for separate political representation and control.
The result was a nation divided into a political hierarchy of 24
departments, 159 provinces, and 1,717 districts, each with its urbanized
capital symbolized by a plaza bordered by a "mother church"
and municipal office. Peruvians invariably identify themselves as being
from one of these divisions, as the place of birth, and thus everyone
carries a locality identity as a lime�o from Lima, a chalaco
from Callao, a cuzque�o from Cusco, a huaracino from
Huaraz, and so forth, down to the smallest hamlet. The political
fissioning thus reflects a strong geocultural identity and bonding,
manifested by the establishment and activities of thousands of regional
and local clubs and associations by migrants from these places who live
in cities throughout the country.
Provincial migrants, especially those in greater Lima, play important
and often key roles in the creation of new political divisions back in
their homelands, as was the case by 1990 in the highland district of
Santo Toribio in the province of Huaylas. The new district was the
result of political antagonisms originating in colonial times between
the small mestizo district capital of Huaylas and its rural hinterland
of Santo Toribio. After more than sixty years of plots and counterplots
in Lima and in the patria chica (hometown or "little
homeland"), the partisans of Santo Toribio, represented by migrants
in Lima, finally won out over the Huaylas district lobby made up of
migrants from the town that sought to maintain district unity.
In this maneuvering, the national political parties were used as the
fulcrum on which the scales were tipped. The municipal government of
Huaylas was held by members of the Popular Action (Acci�n Popular--AP)
party, whereas the Santo Toribio interests were aligned with the
American Popular Revolutionary Alliance (Alianza Popular Revolucionaria
Americana--APRA) party, which took power nationally under Alan Garc�a P�rez
(president, 1985- 90). This scenario is replicated throughout the
highlands and is at the core of virtually all such alterations in
political boundaries. In most cases, the imbroglio develops as rural
villagers, native Americans, and cholos vie for power with the
mestizo townspeople who have dominated them for centuries.
The same struggle has accompanied the dramatic growth of greater
Lima, to which migrants from the provinces have gone to seek access to
power, as well as education and jobs. Understanding the political
structure of Lima is in itself a study in the process of empowerment.
The city of Lima is actually a collection of municipalities. Instead of
the two municipal districts of colonial time--Lima and R�mac--by 1961
Lima contained fifteen district municipalities, and by 1990 it had grown
to thirty-three, all the result of migration. Like all their provincial
counterparts, each municipal district has its plaza, elected mayor and
council, and municipal functions. The government of the province of Lima
unites them and coordinates the metropolis as an urban entity. The rest
of metropolitan Lima consists of the constitutional province of Callao,
the old colonial port. Callao is fused with the capital by a continuous
blanket of housing projects, squatter settlements, and industries
through which one passes en route to Jorge Ch�vez International Airport
from Lima. Even so, in early 1991 there were still small patches of
irrigated farmland at the northern fringe of Callao Province, awaiting
the next spurt of urban growth to engulf them.
The administrative system of departments, provinces, and districts is
under the central authority of the national executive, that is, the
president and prime minister. As such, the decisions and policy
inevitably and ultimately descend from a government overwhelmed by the
needs, demands, and power of Lima. The centralization of power is
resented and regarded as anachronistic, a problem that has provoked
debate since 1860 about the wisdom of decentralization and how it might
be accomplished.
The reorganization decree promulgated by the Garc�a government in
March 1987 put forth a plan to decentralize the nation and establish new
administrative zones, regrouping the present twenty-four departments
into twelve larger regions with legislative, administrative, and taxing
powers. Interestingly, the names Inca, Wari (Huari), and Chav�n have
been applied to areas where those ancient cultures once thrived. If the
system becomes fully installed, it will dramatically alter Peru as a
nation and would be the most significant change in structure since
independence. In the early 1990s, few Peruvians yet understood how the
new system would work or what its impact would be. Because of many
uncertainties created by the unstable political and economic conditions
of the 1980s, both the Congress and the government of President Alberto
K. Fujimori (1990- ) postponed putting the full plan into effect,
although some aspects of the program had begun.
Peru.
Peru
Peru - CULTURE, CLASS, AND HIERARCHY IN SOCIETY
Peru
A large part of Peru's complicated modern social system started with
the hierarchical principles set down in colonial times that remain as
powerful guidelines for intergroup and interpersonal behavior. Peru's
ethnic composition, however, is mixed. In the early 1990s, Europeans of
various background made up 15 percent of the population, Asians from
Japan and China and Africans formed 3 percent, the mestizo population
constituted 37 percent, and the native Americans made up 45 percent,
according to various United States and British reference sources.
However, it is difficult to judge the composition of the native
population because census data have generally undercounted or frequently
failed to identify ethnic groups successfully. Even using language as
the primary criterion does not take bilingualism adequately into account
and omits other aspects of cultural behavior altogether. Thus, although
Cajamarca Department is 98- percent Spanish-speaking, the bulk of the
rural population lives in a manner identical to those classified as
native people because they speak Quechua. The question as to who is a
native has been an oft-debated issue. But how the individual chooses to
classify his or her cultural identity is determined by the forces of
society that give ethnic terms their social meaning. Because of Peruvian
society's longstanding negative attitudes and practices toward native
peoples, persons who have become socially mobile seek to change their
public identity and hence learning Spanish becomes critical. Denial of
the ability to speak Quechua, Aymara, or other native languages often
accompanies the switch.
Another separate dimension of the "Indian problem" so
widely discussed by Peruvian essayists has to do with the natives living
in the Selva and high Selva, or Monta�a, regions of the country. The
tribal peoples have a tenuous and generally unhappy relationship with
Peruvians and the state, evolved from long experience along the tropical
frontier. The Incas and their predecessors ventured only into the
fringes of the region called Antisuyu, and the Spanish followed their
pattern. The inhabitants were known collectively as savages (chunchos).
In documents they are politely referred to as jungle people (selv�colas
or selv�ticos). Thought to be savage, wild, and dangerous but
usually described as "simple" and innocent, they are also
widely considered to possess uncanny powers of witchcraft and healing.
Here, the sixteenth-century concept of the "noble savage" vies
with equally old notions that these are lazy, useless people who need to
get out of the way of progress. Indeed, modern currents of developmental
change, the expanding drug trade, oil exploration, the clearing of the
forest, and the search for gold in Madre de Dios Department have placed
native peoples under great pressures for which they are little prepared.
The Selva tribes, like native highlanders, Afro-Peruvians, and other
people "of color," are those who feel the discriminatory power
of the colonial legacy as well as modern stresses, especially if they
are poor. In demographic terms, the impact of poverty and oppression has
been, and remains, considerable. Thus, the mortality rates of native
peoples and especially their children are much higher than those of the
general population. Tribal peoples are still widely susceptible to
numerous uncontrolled infectious diseases and outside the religious
missions have little or no access to scientific medical care.
The tribal peoples of the lower Selva along the major rivers have
endured the stress and danger of contact with outside forces longer than
those groups located at the upper reaches of the streams. It is in these
"refuge areas" that most of the present tribal populations
survive.
More than any other sector of the population, the rural peoples of the
Selva, and especially the tribal groups, live at the fringe of the state
both literally and figuratively, being uncounted, unserved, and
vulnerable to those who would use the area as their own. According to
anthropologist St�fano Varese, there are about 50 tribes numbering an
estimated 250,000 persons and maintaining active communities, scattered
principally throughout the departments of Loreto, Amazonas, Ucayali, Hu�nuco,
and Madre de Dios. The national census, however, has lowered its
estimates from 100,830 in 1961 to 30,000 in 1981 for the tribal peoples,
even though field studies have not supported such conclusions.
In the Selva, tribal lands in the early 1990s were in even more
jeopardy than the Quechua and Aymara farmland in the Sierra. Although
community rights were acknowledged, if not respected, in the Andes,
outsiders have virtually never accepted this fact in the case of the
Amazonian peoples. Nevertheless, apparently many tribal societies, such
as the Shipibo, have held their traditional hunting, fishing, and
swidden lands in continuous usufruct for as long as 2,000 years. As a
result of the land reforms under the Velasco government, however, laws
established the land rights of Amazonian native communities.
Consequently, some groups, such as the Cocama-Cocamilla, have been able
to secure their agroecological base.
The Afro-Peruvians who came as slaves with the first wave of conquest
remained in that position until released from it by Marshal Ram�n
Castilla (1845-51, 1855-62) in 1854. During their long colonial
experience, many Afro-Peruvians, especially the mulattos and others of
mixed racial parentage, were freed to assume working-class roles in the
coastal valleys. Even fewer blacks than Europeans settled in the
highland towns and for virtually all the colonial epoch remained
concentrated in the central coastal valleys. Lima's colonial population
was 50 percent African during much of the era. Indeed, the term
"criollo" was originally identified with native-born blacks
and acquired much of its special meaning in association with urban,
streetwise behavior. The social status of blacks in many ways paralleled
that of the native Americans in rank and role in society.
Completing the human resource mix in Peru were the immigrants from
Europe and Asia. The former arrived with the advantages of conquest; the
latter arrived first as indentured laborers and later as Japanese and
Taiwanese immigrants who pursued careers in truck farming, commerce, and
business. The Chinese who were brought to Peru from Macao and other
ports between 1849 and 1874 numbered about 90,000. The Chinese influx
occurred in the same period as the United States' importation of Chinese
coolies, and many of the latter were eventually shipped from San
Francisco to Lima. Most Chinese eventually survived their indentures and
took up residence in the coastal towns where they established themselves
as active storekeepers and businesspeople. The growth of the Japanese
presence in Peru began early in the twentieth century and quietly
increased over the 1970-90 period. In 1990 Japanese immigrants
constituted the largest foreign group in Peru and were rapidly
integrating into Peruvian culture, gaining positions from president
(Fujimori) to popular folk singer (the "Little Princess from
Yungay"). In the middle range of Peruvian class structure, the
Chinese and especially the Japanese have achieved status and mobility in
ways the native peoples have not.
The key to understanding Peruvian society is to view aspects of its
dynamic ethnoracial character as a set of variables that constantly
interplays with socioeconomic factors associated with social class
configurations. Thus, a native American might acquire the Spanish
language, a university education, a large amount of capital, and a
cosmopolitan demeanor, but still continue to be considered an indio
(Indian) in many circles and thus be an unacceptable associate or
marital companion. Yet, there is opportunity for socioeconomic mobility
that permits ambitious individuals and families to ascend the hierarchy
ranks in limited ways and via certain pathways. Such mobility is easier
if one starts on the ladder as a mestizo or a foreigner, but especially
if one is white.
<>Indigenous Peoples
<>Legacy of Peonage
<>Elites
<>Military Classes
<>Urban Classes
Peru
Peru - Indigenous Peoples
Peru
The word indio, as applied to native highland people of
Quechua and Aymara origin, carries strong negative meanings and
stereotypes among non-native Peruvians. For that reason, the ardently
populist Velasco regime attempted with some success to substitute the
term peasant (campesino) to accompany the many far-reaching changes his
government directed at improving the socioeconomic conditions in the
highlands. Nevertheless, traditional usage has prevailed in many areas
in reference to those who speak native languages, dress in native
styles, and engage in activities defined as native. Peruvian society
ascribes to them a caste status to which no one else aspires.
The ingrained attitudes and stereotypes held by the mistikuna
(the Quechua term for mestizo people) toward the runakuna
(native people--the Quechua term for themselves) in most highland towns
have led to a variety of discriminatory behaviors, from mocking
references to "brute" or "savage" to obliging native
Americans to step aside, sit in the back of vehicles, and in general
humble themselves in the presence of persons of higher status. The
pattern of ethnoracist denigration has continued despite all of the
protests and reports, official policies, and compelling accounts of
discrimination described in Peruvian novels published since the
beginning of the twentieth century.
The regions and departments with the largest populations of native
peoples are construed to be the most backward, being the poorest, least
educated, and less developed. They are also the ones with the highest
percentages of Quechua and Aymara speakers. The reasons for the
perpetuation of colonial values with respect to autochthonous peoples is
complex, being more than a simple perseverance of custom. The social
condition of the population owes its form to the kinds of expectations
embedded in the premises and workings of the nation's institutions.
These are not easily altered. Spanish institutions of conquest were
implanted into colonial life as part of the strategy for ruling
conquered peoples: the indigenous people were defeated and captured and
thus, as spoils of war, were as exploitable as mineral wealth or land.
In the minds of many highland mestizos as well as betteroff urbanites,
they still are.
Although the Spanish crown attempted to take stern control over civic
affairs, including the treatment, role, and conditions of native
Americans who were officially protected, the well-intended regulations
were neither effective nor accepted by creole and immigrant interests.
Power and status derived from wealth and position, considered not only
to be in the form of money and property, but also coming from the
authority to exercise control over others. Functionaries of the colonial
regime paid for their positions so that they could exact the price of
rule from their constituent populations. Encomenderos, corregidores,
and the numerous bureaucrats all held dominion over segments of the
native population and other castes, which were obliged to pay various
forms of tribute. With the decline of the colonial administration and
the failure of the many attempts at reform to control the abuses of the
native peoples, Peru's political independence saw a transfer of power
into the hands of Creoles and mestizos, the latter of whom comprised the
majority of Peru's citizens in the early 1990s.
The growth of large estates with resident serf populations was an
important feature of this transition period. The process benefited from
the new constitutional policies decreeing the termination of the Indian
community (Comunidad Indio)--the corporate units formerly protected by
the crown. The subsequent breakup of hundreds of communities into
individually owned properties led directly to these lands being
purchased, stolen, or usurped by eager opportunists in the new society.
The most critical native American franchise was thus lost as entire
communities passed from a relatively free corporate status to one of
high vulnerability, subject to the whims of absentee landlords. Although
the development of haciendas occurred rapidly after the demise of the
colonial regime, the system had long been in place, established through
the assignment of property and people to benefit particular individuals
for their service to the crown, to institutions such as the church, and
to public welfare societies intended to offer succor to the poor by
maintaining hospitals and orphanages. Debt peonage constituted the basic
labor arrangement by which landlords of all types operated their
properties nationwide. The system endured until it was abolished by the
land reform of 1969.
Peru
Peru - Legacy of Peonage
Peru
Although a thing of the past, the numbing effects of four centuries
of peonage on Peruvian society should not be underestimated. One
archetypical Andean estate operated at Vicos, Ancash Department, from
1594 to 1952, before it became part of Peru's first land-reform
experiment. The 17,000-hectare estate and the landlord's interests were
managed by a local administrator, who employed a group of straw bosses,
each commanding a sector of the property and directing the work and
lives of the 1,700 peons (colonos) attached to the estate by
debt. Dressed in unique homespun woolen clothing that identified them as
vicosinos (residents of Vicos), each colono family
lived in a house it built but did not own. Rather, it owed the estate
three days of labor per week, and more if demanded, in exchange for a
small subsistence plot and limited rights to graze animals on the puna.
Grazing privileges were paid for by dividing the newborn animals each
year equally between colono and landlord. For the work, a
symbolic wage (temple) of twenty centavos (about two cents in
United States currency of the time) and a portion of coca and alcohol
were given to each peon. In addition, peons were obliged to provide
other services on demand to the administrator and landlord, such as
pasturing their animals, serving as maids and servants in their homes,
running errands of all types, and providing all manner of labor from
house construction to the repair of roads. The landlord might also rent
his peons to others and pay no wage.
To enforce order on the estate, the administrator utilized "the
fist and the whip." Vicos had its own jail to which colonos
were sent without recourse to any legal process; fines, whippings, and
other punishments could be meted out arbitrarily. As individuals, the colonos
were subject to severe restrictions, not being allowed to venture
outside of the district without permission, or to organize any
independent activities except religious festivals, weddings, and
funerals that took place in the hacienda's chapel and cemetery, only
occasionally with clerical presence. The only community-initiated
activities allowed were those under the supervision of the parish
church.
Outside the protection of the estate, peons correctly felt themselves
to be vulnerable to exploitation and feared direct contact with those mistikuna
whom they regarded as dangerous, even to the extent of characterizing
whites and powerful mestizos as pishtakos, mythical bogeymen
who kill or rape natives. In protecting themselves from the threats of
this environment, vicosinos, like tens of thousands of other colonos
across the Andes, chose to employ the "weapons of the weak,"
by striking a low profile, playing dumb, obeying, taking few
initiatives, and in general staying out of the way of mestizos and
strangers they did not know, reserving their own pleasures and
personalities for the company of family and friends.
Peonage under the hacienda functioned in a relatively standard
fashion throughout Peru, with variations between the coastal
plantations, on the one hand, and the highland estates and ranches, on
the other. On some highland estates, conditions were worse than those
described; in others they were not as restrictive or arbitrary. Although
called haciendas, the coastal plantations were far more commercialized,
being given to the production of goods for export or the large urban
markets. Under these more fluid socioeconomic circumstances, the
plantation workers, called yanaconas (after the Incan class of
serfs called yanas), who permanently resided on the estates,
also had access to subsistence plots. Moreover, they usually had
"company" housing, schools, and access to other facilities
specified under a signed labor contract often negotiated through worker
unions.
Nevertheless, there were lingering connections to the highland
manorial system. Because plantation crops, such as sugarcane and cotton,
require a large labor force for harvests and planting, workers are
seasonally recruited from the highland peasantry for these tasks. In
some instances, owners of coastal plantations also possessed highland
estates from which they might "borrow" the needed seasonal
workers from among the colonos they already controlled in
peonage and pay them virtually nothing. In most cases, however, the
coastal plantations simply hired gangs of peasant farmers for the short
term, using professional labor contractors to do the job. For thousands
of young men, this became an important first experience away from their
family and village, serving as a rite of passage into adulthood. It also
constituted an important step for many in developing the labor and life
skills needed to migrate permanently to the coast. Employment on the
coastal plantations offered many opportunities to the highland farmer to
use mechanized equipment and different tools, observe agricultural
procedures guided by scientific principles and experts, and work for
wages that greatly surpassed what they might earn in the villages. For
most farm workers, it was the only chance to actually accumulate money.
Peru
Peru - Elites
Peru
Concentrated in the provincial, departmental, and national capitals,
Peru's upper class was the other side of the coin of peonage. Whereas
the Quechua or Aymara native population was powerless, submissive, and
poor, the regional and national elites were Hispanic, dominant, and
wealthy. The inheritors of colonial power quickly reaffirmed their
political, social, and economic hegemony over the nation even though the
Peruvian state itself was a most unstable entity until the presidency of
Ram�n Castilla. They continued to strike the posture of conquerors
toward the native peoples, justifying themselves as civilized, culto
(cultured), and urbane, as well as gente decente (decent
people), in the customary phrase of the provincial town. Such
presumption of status is a powerful but unwritten code of entitlement.
It permits one to expect to have obedient servants, to be deferred to by
those of lesser station, and to be the first to enjoy opportunity,
services of the state, and whatever resources might be available.
The modern national upper classes of Peru are today a more diverse
population than was the case even at the end of the nineteenth century.
They have remained essentially identified with the Costa, even though
they have controlled extensive property in the highlands and Selva.
Nevertheless, these elites are highly conscious of class integrity as
social life unfolds in the context of private clubs and specialized
economic circles. The predilection of the upper-class families to show
the strength of their lineages is revealed not only in the use of full
names, which always contain both one's father's and mother's last names
in that order, but also the apellidos (last names) of important
grandparental generations. Thus, magazine society pages report names
like Jos� Carlos Prado Fernandini Beltr�n de Espantoso y Ugarteche, in
which only Prado is the last name in the American sense. Use of the
family pedigree to demonstrate rank is common among the elite when the
names are clearly associated with wealth and power.
As Peruvians have become more cosmopolitan, foreign names from
Britain, Italy, Austria, and Germany have appeared with increasing
frequency among those claiming upper-class credentials, leading to the
conclusion that it is easier to reach elite status from outside Peru
than to ascend from within the society. There are, of course a number of
families who can trace their lineages to the colonial period. However,
families of nineteenth- and early twentieth-century immigrants
constitute about 40 percent of Peru's most elite sector, indicating a
surprising openness to cosmopolitan mobility. In a 1980s list of Peru's
national elite containing over 250 family names, for example, only one
of clearly Quechua origins could be identified.
The racial composition of the upper class is predominantly white,
although a few mestizos are represented, especially at regional levels.
The social structure of the country follows a Lima-based model. The
national upper class is located almost exclusively in the province of
Lima, the second strata of elites is provincial, residing in the old
principal regional cities, such as Arequipa, Trujillo, and Cusco, but
not in Huancayo, Chimbote, or Juliaca, whose populations are
predominantly of highland mestizo and cholo origins.
Upper-class status in provincial life generally does not equate with the
same levels in Lima, but rather to a middle level in the national social
hierarchy.
Traditionally, the upper classes based their power and wealth on
rural land ownership and secondarily on urban industrial forms of
investment. This situation has changed in part through the rise of
business, industry, banking, and political opportunities, and also
because of the Agrarian Reform Law of 1969, which forced dramatic
changes in land tenure patterns. It was, however, a change as difficult
to make as any that could be imagined: the fabled landed oligarchy
greatly feared any alterations in its property rights, which included
the colonos and yanaconas attached to both highland
and coastal estates. Their control over Peru's power, purse, and
peasantry bordered on the absolute until the second half of the
twentieth century, when the great highland migrations took hold of
coastal cities and industrial growth exploded. Ensuing social and
political demands could no longer be managed from behind the traditional
scenes of power.
Vested interests of the landed upper class were ensconced in the
National Agrarian Association (Sociedad Nacional Agraria-- SNA). Until
the first government of Fernando Bela�nde, it had been impossible to
discover just what the property and investment interests of this group
were because government files on these subjects were closed and, indeed,
had never been publicly scrutinized. All of this changed abruptly after
the peasant land invasions of estates in 1963, when the need for
solutions overcame the secrecy. In 1966 economic historian Carlos
Malpica Silva Santisteban identified the landed oligarchy as a
relatively small group, with 190 families owning 54 percent of the
irrigated coast and 36 families or persons holding 63 percent of titled
land in the Selva, for a total of over 3 million hectares. In the
highlands, the data were similar in content but hard to verify.
Although upper-class wealth was founded on rural properties, it is
evident that elite urban, mining, and industrial interests were also
extensive. An indefatigable compiler of data on Peru's elites, Malpica
annotated an extensive catalog of modern business and banking concerns
showing the concentration of economic control in the hands of a tiny
group of elite families, many being familiar traditional members of the
oligarchy, now deprived of their land base by the agrarian reform. Of
the seventy-nine families holding significant blocks of shares in the
twelve principal insurance and banking operations in 1989, almost 50
percent were descended from the aforementioned European immigrant
groups. Despite this Eurocentric trend, descendants of Japanese and
Chinese immigrants have also entered the economic elites, if not with
the equivalent social status. At least one Chinese-Peruvian family,
which holds substantial banking, commercial, and industrial investments,
descends from immigrants who arrived as indentured laborers in the
nineteenth century.
Peru
Peru - Military Classes
Peru
The militarily connected population has developed into a significant
national sector. Playing an ever more important social role, los
militares (the military) have, in effect, emerged as a subsociety,
with special attributes and arrangements that set them apart from other
social classes as a powerful special interest elite, with its own
allegiances and identity, sense of mission, and objectives developed in
coherent, relatively independent ways from other national policy and
planning processes. No other groups within the population, with the
possible exception of the cabals of the oligarchy, can be so
characterized.
The people involved in ancillary activities--military industries,
medical services, civilian business managers and employees, service and
maintenance personnel, in addition to members of family networks who
benefit from having one of their number in the armed forces--probably
approach 1 million, or 4 percent of the nation's population. The
military domain commands 20 percent of central government expenditures,
5 percent more than education, the next largest share of the national
budget, and much more than health services, which claimed 5.8 percent in
1988. Indeed, Peru's military expenditures of US$106 per capita exceeded
three times the average expenditure per capita of all other South
American nations in 1988. Over a twenty-year period, the military budget
gained 38 percent in its share of the national budget, whereas education
dropped by 35 percent and health gained by less than 5 percent since
1972.
Professionalization has involved areas that few have analyzed but
that constitute the major reward system for professional career officers
and noncommissioned personnel. These are the elaborate infrastructure
and exclusive services for personnel and their families, including beach
resorts and hotels, consumer discount cooperatives, casinos and clubs,
schools of several types and levels, hospitals and general medical
services, insurance coverages, recreational facilities, and a variety of
other programs. In addition, there are extensive housing subdivisions in
Lima for the officer corps and other military employees, named for the
military branches that they serve. There are special retirement
provisions and a plethora of other benefits for members of military that
are unavailable to others in the society at large.
The sphere of military activities includes an extremely active
internal social calendar of commemorative events that have the function
of bonding the members and their families more tightly to group
interests. In sum, the Peruvian military constitutes a virtually
encapsulated society within the larger one and competes with advantage
for the public funds vis-�-vis other interests by operating its own
industries, sponsoring its own research and advanced study, and engaging
in civic-action programs that often replicate the assigned work of
civilian institutions, such as the Ministry of Agriculture.
Consequently, the ubiquitous and well-established institutions of
military society pervade Peruvian life at every turn and are regarded
with skepticism by many who see them as depriving civilian needs of
essential resources.
Peru
Peru - Urban Classes
Peru
Between the extremes of wealth and power represented by the white
upper class and the native caste is the predominantly mestizo and cholo
population, which largely comprises the lower and middle sectors of
rural and urban society. These are the most numerous and diverse
sectors, constituting the core of Peruvian national society in culture,
behavior, and identity. Together, these sectors include a wide range of
salaried workingclass families, persons in business and commercial
occupations, bureaucrats, teachers, all military personnel (except those
related to elite families), medical, legal, and academic professionals,
and so forth. In terms of occupation, residence, education, wealth,
racial, and ethnic considerations, the population is diverse, with few
clear-cut markers differentiating one segment from another. Yet, there
are obvious differences among the regions of the country that combine
with those indicators to suggest a person's social position in relation
to others. The importance of the regions derives from the fact that the
urban and rural areas of the Sierra are, as a whole, measurably poorer
than the Costa and Selva, and the various occupational groups less
well-off in proportion. As in the case of the provincial upper class,
being middle class in the regional context does not necessarily mean the
same thing in the capital, although being marked as lower class would
translate to the same category in Lima or Trujillo.
An important study by anthropologist Carlos E. Aramburu and his
colleagues in 1989 provides a graphic outline of how levels of living
vary throughout the nation. Analyzing the 1981 census, they ranked the
153 provinces on the basis of five variables: the proportion of
households without any modern household appliance; the average per
capita income; the percentage of illiterate women over fifteen years of
age; the number of children between six and nine years of age who
regularly worked; and the rate of infant mortality. These indicators
were representative of involvement in the economy, participation in
state-operated institutions, and access to health services, each of
which is critical for marking advances in the level of living from the
perspective of the modern state. Only 9 of the 100 highland provinces
were represented among those in the top two levels of wealth, and only
Arequipa was in the top rank. In contrast to the Selva provinces, which
lacked any rank, eighteen of the twenty-eight coastal provinces
registered in the top third of provinces according to wealth. At the
other end of the scale, all but three of the poorest fifty-three
provinces with 20 percent of the population were in the highlands, and
none were on the coast. These data, when juxtaposed with the
distribution of monolingual Quechua and Aymara speakers, confirm the
poverty status of Peru's native population at the bottom of the
socioeconomic scale.
Thus, the provincial upper classes, with few exceptions, do not
equate with the Lima-based national elite, whose socioeconomic position
is vastly enhanced by their status as Lima residents and, subsequently,
by their international connections. The same can be said for the other
middle and lower sectors of the provincial population in comparison to
Lima. In a very real sense then, Peru has two levels of class structure
layered in between the national extremes of the oligarchic elites and
the rural native peasantry: one in the context of Lima's primacy, the
other with reference to the rest of the nation.
Although the role of racial phenotypes and associated ethnic
behaviors is clearly seen at the extreme poles of Peruvian society, it
is somewhat obscured in the middle sectors. In general, the more closely
one approximates the ideal of Euro-American appearance, the greater the
social prestige and status derived. On the other hand, Peru is a country
whose majority population is darker skinned, with distinctive facial and
bodily features. The varied shades of meaning attached to the
designations mestizo and cholo are as much socioeconomic and
cultural in import as they are racial. Thus, in the Peruvian vernacular
phrase, "money whitens" one's self-concept and expectations.
With other non-native groups, such as the Japanese, Chinese, and
Afro-Peruvians, status and class considerations are structured somewhat
differently, yet exhibit the same tendencies toward ethnoracist marking.
Just how strongly stereotypes have prevailed over facts was witnessed by
the 1990 presidential election of the Japanese-Peruvian Alberto
Fujimori, who was constantly referred to as el chinito (the
little Chinaman). Racial terms are frequently employed in normal
discourse in ways that many foreigners find uncomfortable.
Afro-Peruvians are referred to as zambos negritos, or
more politely as morenos (browns). In many instances, this
terminology implies behavioral expectations and stereotypes, and yet in
others the same term is simply used as an impartial means of
description.
Peru
Peru - FAMILY LIFE
Peru
Much has been said about kinship and family in Latin America. The
"Peruvian family" is of course not a homogeneous entity, but
rather reflects both ethnic and socioeconomic factors. If there is a
generalization to be made, however, it is that families in Peru, no
matter what their status, show a high degree of unity, purpose, and
integration through generations, as well as in the nuclear unit. The
average size for families for the nation as a whole is 5.1 persons per
household, with the urban areas registering slightly more than this and,
contrary to what might be expected, rural families, especially in the
highlands, being smaller, with a national average size of 4.9 persons.
This apparent anomaly runs counter to the expected image of the rural
family. This is because the highland families that constitute the bulk
of rural households have been deeply affected by the heavy migration of
their members to the cities, coastal farms, and Selva colonizations.
The roles of the different family members and sexes tend to follow
rather uniform patterns within social class and cultural configurations.
In terms of family affairs, Hispanic Peruvian patterns are strongly
centered on the father as family head, although women increasingly
occupy this titular role in rural as well as urban areas, amounting to
20 percent of all households. As is the pattern in other countries,
women have increasingly sought wage and salaried work to meet family
needs. This, coupled with the fact that social and economic stress has
forced a departure from the traditionally practiced versions, the
patriarchal family is gradually losing its place as the model of family
life. Contributing to these changes are the neolocality of nuclear
families living in cities and the loss of male populations in rural
areas through migration and various povertyrelated conditions that lead
men to abandon their families. Families are patricentric, and the male
head of household is considered the authority. His wife follows him in
this respect, yet exercises considerable control over her own affairs
with respect to property and marketing. This gender and lineage
hierarchy is to be seen as families walk single-file to market, each
carrying their bundles, the husband leading the way, followed by his
wife and then the children.
In many Quechua communities, the ancient kinship system of
patrilineages (called kastas in some areas) survives. It is
thought to have been the basis for the Incaic clan village, the ayllu. In a patrilineal system, wives belong to their father's
lineage and their children to their father's side of the family tree.
This differs from the Hispanic system, which is bilateral, that is,
including one's mother's kin as part of the extended family, as in the
British system. Where the native Americans follow a patrilineal system,
families are at once at odds with the formal requirement of Peruvian
law, which demands the use of both paternal and maternal names as part
of one's official identity, thus forcing the bilateral pattern on them.
In many Hispanic mestizo homes, fathers often exercise strong
authoritarian roles, controlling the family budget, administering
discipline, and representing the group interest to the external world.
Mothers in these homes, on the other hand, often control and manage the
internal affairs in the household, assigning tasks to children and to
the female servant(s) present in virtually every urban middle- and
upper-class home. For children school is de rigueur, and the more
well-to-do, the more certain it is that they attend a private school,
where the educational standards approach or equal good schools in other
countries. The home is prized and well-cared for, with patios and yards
protected by glass-studded walls and, in recent years, by electrical
devices to keep out thieves.
The lower-class household in the urban areas--such as Lima, Trujillo,
or Arequipa--presents the other side of this coin. In metropolitan Lima,
7 percent of the population lives in a tugurio (inner-city
barrio) and 47 percent in a squatter settlement. The older pueblos
jovenes erected in the 1950s had the look in 1990 of concrete
middle-class permanency, with electricity, water, and sewerage. The
newer invaded areas, however, had a raw and dusty look: housing appeared
ramshackle, made of bamboo matting (esteras) and miscellaneous
construction materials scrounged from any available source. Here, as in
the tugurios, the domestic scene reveals a constant scramble
for existence: the men generally leave at the crack of dawn to travel
via long bus routes to reach work sites, often in heavy construction,
where without protective gear, such as hard hats or steel-toed shoes,
they haul iron bars and buckets of cement up rickety planks and
scaffolding. With an abundance of men desperate for work, modern
buildings are raised more with intensive labor than machinery.
Women's roles in the squatter settlements cover a wide variety of
tasks, including hauling water from corner spigots and beginning the
daily preparation of food over kerosene stoves. In the 1975-91 period,
the food supply for substantial numbers of the urban lower class in Lima
and other coastal cities came from the United States Food for Peace
(Public Law 480) programs administered by private voluntary
organizations. Women also keep their wide-ranging family members
connected, seeking the food supply with meager funds, and doing various
short-term jobs for cash. According to social scientist Carol Graham,
the poor urban areas have a high percentage of female-headed households,
as well as a large number of abandoned mothers who are left with the
full responsibility for supporting their households and raising the
children.
Urban Informal Sector
In 1990 the vast "informal sector" of Lima's economy was
the most striking feature of its commercial life. There, 91,000 street
vendors, 54 percent of them women, sold food in the streets or public
squares of central Lima or the residential area of Miraflores, the
upscale mecca of the city. Street vendors have been a part of Lima life
and culture since early colonial times, and the city government has
persistently attempted to remove them to fixed market places.
Nevertheless, street commerce in Lima throughout the colonial period and
until the twentieth century was generally regarded as a colorful,
folkloric aspect of urban life and was often depicted in period
paintings and descriptions. Since the great migrations began in the
early 1950s, however, the city elites have come to disdain the street
vendors who swarm over the R�mac Bridge every afternoon. As Hernando de
Soto has abundantly documented in El otro sendero (The
Other Path), this freewheeling entrepreneurial sector of the labor
force was, in the 1980s, producing the equivalent of almost 40 percent
of the national income. As "unregistered" business, this
activity is outside the control of the national economic institutions,
whose cumbersome and often corrupt bureaucratic regulations stifle
initiatives, especially if one lacks resources to pay all the bribes and
formal start-up costs. In the circumstances of 1991, the public need to
participate in the economy had, in essence, neutralized and bypassed the
official system.
Domestic Servants
The urban middle-class family without servants is incomplete.
Although household servants constitute a major element in the urban
informal economic sector, they are rarely analyzed as part of it. The
retaining, training, disciplining, or recruiting of domestic help is
constantly in progress under the supervision of the wife of the
household head. One of the most common sights in Lima is therefore the
small printed sign in front of houses reading "Se necesita
muchacha" ("girl needed").
There is a constant flow of young highland migrant women to urban
areas, and a very large portion of them seek domestic positions on first
arriving in Lima. Although census figures were dated, it appeared that
about 18 percent of all women employed in metropolitan Lima in 1990 were
domestic servants. Domestic service work of course pays poorly, and
social and sexual abuse appear often to accompany such employment.
Nevertheless, in the absence of other alternatives, migrant women find
these jobs temporarily useful in providing "free" housing and
a context for learning city life, while also having some opportunity to
attend night school to learn a profession, such as tailoring or
cosmetology, two of the more popular fields. As domestic work has been
increasingly regulated, the term empleada (employee) has begun
to replace the use of muchacha as the term of reference. Over
the 1960-91 period, households have been obliged to permit servants to
attend school and to cover other costs, such as social security.
Godparenthood
Family life at all levels of society is nourished by an ample number
of ceremonial events marking all rites of passage, such as birthdays,
anniversaries, graduations, or important religious events, such as
baptisms, confirmations, and marriages. Family life is thus marked by
small fiestas celebrating these events and passages. In this context,
Peruvians have greatly elaborated the Roman Catholic tradition of
godparenthood (padrinazgo) to encompass more occasions than
simply celebration of the sacraments of the church, although following
the same format. The parties involved include the child or person
sponsored in the ceremony, the parents, and the godparents who are the
sponsors and protectors. The primary relationship in this triad is
between the godchild (ahijado) and the godparents (padrinos).
The secondary bond of compadrazgo is between the parents and godparents who after the
ceremony will forever mutually call each other compadre or comadre.
For the child, the relationship with the godparents is expected to be
one of benefit, with the padrinos perhaps assisting with the
godchild's education, finding employment, or, at the least, giving a
small gift to the child from time to time. For the compadres,
there is the expectation of a formalized friendship, one in which favors
may be asked of either party.
Ritual sponsorship has two dimensions with respect to its importance
to family and community. On the one hand, the mechanism can be utilized
to solidify social and family relations within a small cluster of
relatives and friends, which is generally the case for families
concerned with enclosing their social universe for various reasons.
Among the top upper class, it may provide a way of concentrating power
relations, business interests, or wealth; among the Indian caste, the
inward selection of compadres may follow the need to protect
one's access to fields or to guarantee a debt. On the other hand, many
families deliberately choose compadres from acquaintances or
relatives who can assist in socioeconomic advancement. In this fashion,
the original religious institution has lent itself to social needs in a
dynamic and flexible manner. In the more closed type of community
setting, there are only five or six occasions for which godparents are
selected; among more socially mobile groups, there may be as many as
fifteen or more ways in which a family may gain compadres.
Thus, it would not be unusual for the parents of a family with four
children to count as many as forty or more different compadres.
In a more conservative setting, the number might be less than ten for a
similar family.
Rural Family and Household
The Andean peasantry, often maligned by those who discriminate
against them as being lazy and poor workers, are the reverse of the
stereotype. The peasant family begins its day at dawn with the chores of
animal husbandry, cutting the eucalyptus firewood, fetching water, and a
plethora of other domestic tasks. Field work begins with a trek to the
often distant chacras, which may be located at a different
altitude from the home and require several hours to reach. Where chacras
are very distant from the home, farmers maintain rough huts in which to
store tools or stay for several days. Andean peasants of all ages and
both sexes lead rigorous lives, hustling about steep pathways carrying
loads of firewood, produce, and tools on their backs.
Although horses and mules are of greater market value than burros,
they are more expensive to maintain, and thus burros are the most common
beasts of burden in most of the highlands. Native Andean llamas and
alpacas are commonly found in the central and southern Andes, where they
are still widely used for transport, wool, and meat. Peasant women and
girls, although carrying a burden, perpetually keep their hands at work
spinning wool to be hand woven by local artisans into clothing,
blankets, and ponchos. Although there are few who approach full
selfsufficiency in the Andes (and none on the coast), the Andean
peasantry make, repair, invent, and adapt most of their tools; they also
prepare food from grain they have harvested and animals they have raised
and butchered.
Although modern amenities and appliances have found their way into
most nonfarm households, the rural poor by necessity must conduct their
affairs without these instruments of pleasure and work. Even though
consumer items--such as electric irons, blenders (especially useful for
making baby food), televisions, and radiocassette tape players--are
keenly desired, surveys have shown that 25 percent of all Peruvian
households possess none of these things. The great majority of
households (more than 50 percent) lacking modern appliances were in the
rural areas of the Andes. The contributions of many hands, therefore,
are vital to the rural economy and household. The same survey by Carlos
Aramburu and his associates also showed that the poorest and most rural
areas were also the provinces that in demographic terms had the highest
dependency ratios (the largest number of persons--the very young and the
aged--who were only limited participants in the labor force).
Consequently, the loss of youth to migration cuts deeply into the
productive capacity of hundreds of families and their communities. In
those districts in the central highlands especially, where the Shining
Path has been active since the early 1980s, the absolute decline in work
force numbers has left a third of the houses empty, fields in permanent
fallow, and irrigation works in disrepair, losses which Peru could ill
afford in view of its declining agricultural production and great
dependency on imported foodstuffs, even in rural areas.
These demographic changes also threaten other community and family
institutions like the use of festive and exchange-labor systems (minka
and ayni, respectively) that have been such an integral part of
the traditional peasant farm tradition. The minka involves a
family working side by side with relatives and neighbors to plant or
harvest, often with the accompaniment of musicians and always with ample
basic food supplied by the hosts. On some occasions, invited workers may
request token amounts of the harvest. Exchange labor, or ayni,
is the fulfillment of an obligation to return the labor that someone
else has produced. The communities of peasant farmers, whether native or
cholo, utilize these mechanisms to augment family labor at
critical times. Minka work crews, however, are often
inefficient and overly festive, and their hosts are unable to keep
activities task-oriented on a late afternoon. As a consequence, farmers
who are mainly concerned with monetary profitability, tend to utilize
paid temporary workers instead of the minka, whose ceremonial
aspects are distracting. On the other hand, the purpose of the minka
is obviously social and communal, as well as economic. Family economic
activity in rural communities has invariably relied primarily on unpaid
family labor, augmented by periodic cooperative assistance from
relatives and neighbors to handle larger seasonal tasks.
Peru
Peru - COMMUNITY LIFE AND INSTITUTIONS
Peru
The importance of developing and maintaining effective intracommunity
relationships underlies many of the kinship traditions that are
universal in Andean and Peruvian family life in small towns. Throughout
the Andes, there has been a constant need for peasants to retain strong
interpersonal and family bonds for significant socioeconomic reasons.
For centuries the peasantry suffered the constant loss of land until the
Agrarian Reform Law of 1969 reversed the pattern. The stronger a
community is tied together, the greater has been its ability to defend
its interests against usurpers, a fact often shown in ethnographic
studies throughout the region.
By practice and reputation, Andean villages and towns often enjoy
reputations for cohesiveness, community action, and the good, simple
life. The tight social relationships in Peru's towns and villages,
peasant communities, and small cities, however, are not necessarily
based on "rural" or agricultural needs and a positive
community spirit. Even in small populations where everyone knows
everyone else, or knows about them, there can be marked ethnic and
social class differences and rivalries that afford many opportunities
for disagreement and feuds. Although people share their culture, values,
and participation in a community, family interests often clash over
property ownership and chacra boundaries, local politics, and
any of the myriad reasons why people might not like each other. Thus,
small town life can be difficult when conflicts erupt: "pueblo
chico, infierno grande" ("small town, big hell") is the
expression used. There are, therefore, two contradicting images of small
town life: one bucolic, tranquil, and good natured; the other, petty and
conflictive. Both images are rooted in fact.
Peru
Peru - Catholicism and Community
Peru
Like many Latin American nations, Peru's predominant religion is
Roman Catholicism, which after 460 years has remained a powerful
influence in both state affairs and daily activities. Church activities
and personnel are, of course, centered in Lima, symbolically located on
the east side of the Plaza de Armas to one side of the National Palace
and the Municipality of Lima, which occupy the north and west quarters,
respectively, of the central square from which all points in Peru are
measured. The ceremonial functions of the state are integrated into the
rites of the church, beginning with the inauguration of the president
with high mass in the cathedral, Holy Week events, and the observances
of major Peruvian saints' days and festivals, such as that of Santa Rosa
de Lima (Saint Rose of Lima) and others. The institutional role of the
church was established with conquest and the viceroyalty, but since
independence it has slowly declined through losing its exclusive control
over the domains of education, maintenance of vital statistics,
marriages, and the organization of daily life around church rites.
Nevertheless, the ceremonial aspects of the Catholic religion, moral
dictates, and values are profoundly embedded in Peruvian culture; parish
priests and bishops play active roles in local affairs where they are
present.
The policies of the church historically have been considered as very
conservative, and the various parishes and bishoprics were great
landlords, either managing their properties directly or renting them to
other elites. Church districts with such properties were eagerly sought
by ambitious clergy, many of whom even gained dubious reputations as hacendados. Throughout the highlands, the priesthood actively
carried the colonial legacy in its dealings with the Quechua and Aymara
peoples until the decade of the 1950s, when many foreign priests,
notably the Maryknolls in Puno, began introducing substantial changes in
these traditional patterns. Part of this development resulted in the
emergence of a strongly populist and social activist theme among many
clergy, such as Gustavo Guti�rrez, whose 1973 book, A Theology of
Liberation, was perhaps to have greater political impact outside of
Peru than in it. The changes, however, were considerable, and many
priests and nuns worked to assist the poor in ways that marked a
turnabout in both style and concept of duty from a short generation
before. Although the Peruvian priesthood has been thus invigorated, the
church remains unable to fill a large percentage of its parishes on a
regular basis, in part because of the demand for clergy in Lima and the
other coastal cities.
Roman Catholicism, as the official state religion, has played a major
role in Peruvian culture and society since conquest, with every village,
town, and city having its official church or cathedral, patron saint,
and special religious days, which are celebrated annually. These kinds
of activities are focal events for reaffirming social identity and play
key roles in the life of all types and sizes of community. Participation
in these events is spurred by both religious devotion and desire to
serve in community functions for prestige and perhaps political
purposes. The most notable of these activities are the patronal
festivals that each settlement annually celebrates. Costs for these
affairs vary greatly, depending on the size of the town or community. In
the case of large cities like Ica or Cusco, expenses are impressive. To
underwrite the costs, localities have each developed their own methods
of "taxation," although none would call it that. The most
common method is to obtain "volunteers," who agree to serve as
festival sponsors, called mayordomos, who can enlist their family members to aid in the work
of organizing and paying for community-wide celebrations. In small
places, the mayordomo and his or her family may handle the
costs within the group, even going into debt to do things properly. In
large towns and cities, the festivals are often sponsored by the
municipal government as well as the church, with mayordomos
serving in only limited capacities. In many towns, there is a religious
brotherhood (hermandad) or other organization that also takes
part in this fashion. Peru's largest religious celebration, the Se�or
de los Milagros, which takes place in Lima during the month of October
each year, is largely funded by the brotherhood of the Se�or de los
Milagros.
In communities that maintain strong native cultural traditions, Roman
Catholicism is intricately mixed with facets of Incaic beliefs and
practices. The native populations hold firm animistic notions about the
spirits and forces found in natural settings, such as the great
snowpeaks where the apus (lords of sacred places) dwell. Many
places are seen as inherently dangerous, emanating airs or essences that
can cause illness, and are approached with care. The Incas and other
Andean peoples revered the inti (sun) and pacha mama
(earth mother), as well as other gods and the principal ancestral heads
of lineages. The Spaniards, in converting the people to Catholicism,
followed a deliberate strategy of syncretism that was used throughout
the Americas. This process sought to substitute Christian saints for
local deities, often using existing temple sites as the location of
churches. Many of the biblical lessons and stories were conveyed through
dramatic reenactments of those events at fiestas that permitted people
to memorize the tales and participate in the telling. Thousands of
Andean fiestas are based on such foundations.
The annual celebrations of village patron saints' days often coincide
with important harvest periods and are clearly reinterpretations of
preconquest harvest observances disguised as Catholic feast days. In the
south highlands, among such pastoral peoples as those of Q'eros, Cusco
preserves many ancestral practices and lifeways. Elaborate rites to
promote the fertility of their llama and alpaca herds are still
undertaken. In other communities, religious rites that evoke natural and
spiritual forces require sacrifices of animals, such as llamas or guinea
pigs, the spillage of chicha or alcohol on sacred ground, or
the burying of coca and other ritual items to please the apus
or the pacha mama. In numerous highland areas, the Spanish
introduced the Mediterranean custom of blood sports, such as
bullfighting, bullbaiting, and games of horsemanship in which riders
riding at full gallop attempt to wring the necks of fowl or condors. Jos�
Mar�a Arguedas recounts these practices in his famous 1941 novel, Yawar
Fiesta.
Andean religious practices conform to the sociocultural divisions of
Peruvian society, with the Hispanicized coastal cities following general
Roman Catholic practices, and the Andean towns and villages reflecting
the syncretisms of conquest culture, which endure as strong elements in
modern belief and worldview. The importance of these events is
considerable because they evoke outpourings of devotion and emotional
expressions of belief, while giving opportunity for spiritual renewal.
They also function to tie the population together in their common belief
and allegiance to the immortal figure of the saint or apu, and
thus constitute important bonding mechanisms for families and
neighborhoods. From the major celebrations--such as those of two
specifically Peruvian saints, Santa Rosa of Lima and San Mart�n of
Porres (Saint Martin of Porres)--to the dozens of important regional
figures, such as the Virgin de la Puerta (Virgin of the Door) in La
Libertad Department and the revered saints and crosses in village
chapels, these feast days have a singular role in social life. Indeed,
not only do settlements have religious allegiances, but so, too, do
public institutions. For example, the armed forces celebrate the day of
their patroness, the Virgen de las Mercedes (Virgin of the Mercedes--Our
Lady of Ransom), with pomp and high-level participation around the
country.
Since about 1970, Protestantism has been winning converts in Peru at
a relatively rapid rate among the urban poor and certain Indian
populations. Yet, Peruvians, like those in other Andean
countries, have not been as receptive to Protestant entreaties to
convert as have people in Central America. According to one study, only
about 4.5 percent of Peruvians can be counted as Protestants, with the
Church of Jesus Christ of Latter Day Saints (Mormons) forming about a
quarter of the number and the rest belonging to various other groups. To
many, the appeal of Protestantism comes in reaction to the kinds of
ceremonial obligations that have accompanied Roman Catholic practice and
the failure of the traditional church to address adequately the pressing
issues that were problems among the poor.
Most intensive Protestant missionary attention has been directed
toward the tribal peoples of the Amazon Basin, where the Summer
Institute of Linguistics (SIL), Wycliffe Bible Translators, and similar
evangelical groups have long worked. In particular, the SIL has occupied
a peculiar position in Peru through its long-running contracts with the
Ministry of Education to educate the numerous tribes, such as the
Shipibo, and assist the government in developing linguistically correct
texts for several groups. Nevertheless, nationalistic public reaction to
the SIL's activities has provoked many attempts to force the
organization out of Peru. Because the force behind the evangelical
movements emanates largely from the United States and because Roman
Catholicism is the official state religion, there have been occasional
hints of loyalist hostility with respect to zealous proselytizing.
Catholic cults have also bloomed throughout Lima's squatter
settlements. The role of religion and the fact that the people
themselves generate institutions of worship with relatively little
external guidance is yet another expression of the migrants' striving
for a sense of community in the difficult circumstances of Lima's
squatter settlements.
Peru
Peru - Community Leadership
Peru
Throughout the highlands, there are vestiges of the colonial civic
and religious organizations of "indirect rule" originally
implanted by Spanish officials. Where they survive in Peru, principally
in Indian communities, there are networks of villages tied together in
an association broadly supervised by a parish priest or his surrogate.
The village religious leaders, who are called by various names such as alcaldes
ped�neos (lesser mayors) and varayoq or envarados
(staff bearers), plan and carry out elaborate yearly festival cycles
involving dozens of lesser special lay religious authorities. Often
referred to as carrying a "burden" or responsibility (cargo),
all of these village officials are selected annually by elaborate
systems of prestige rankings based on prior experience and local values
of devotion, honesty, reputation for work, and capacity to underwrite
the costs of office.
The principal officials in these hierarchies carry holy staffs of
office, often made of chonta (tucuma) palm wood brought from
the tropics and adorned with silver relics and symbols. The additional
duties of the varayoq include the supervision of village
morals, marriage, and the application of informal justice to offenders
of village norms. Although specifically outlawed in several of Peru's
older constitutions, the system has endured throughout the highlands.
Changes have occurred, however, when communities, under pressures to
modernize, abolished the varayoq institution. In other cases,
the system has evolved into a more formal political apparatus, leaving
the religious activities in the hands of the parish priest, lay
brotherhoods, and other devotees. The multicommunity Peasant Patrols (rondas
campesinas) in the highlands have acted as informal but powerful
self-defense forces controlling rustling and, beginning in the 1980s,
the intrusion of unwanted revolutionaries like the Shining Path. In
aspects of their orientation and organization, they may aspire to
resemble the varayoq as moral authorities.
The formal political and social organization of Peruvian towns and
cities of course follows the outlines laid down in the constitution of
1979 and various laws enacted by the Congress. One of the somewhat
confusing arrangements, however, pertains to the officially constituted
corporate community enterprises, the Peasant Communities, and their
offshoots--such as the Social Interest Agrarian Association (Sociedad
Agr�cola de Inter�s Social--SAIS) and the Social Property Enterprises
(Empresas de Propiedad Social--EPS). There is disagreement over how
these entities fit into the community and political picture because
their constituencies overlap with the political divisions. The districts
and provinces are political subdivisions with elected mayors and council
members charged with administering their areas. Corporate communities
are a form of agrarian cooperative business that own inalienable land,
with memberships that are not necessarily restricted to a single
residential unit like a town.
The Peasant Communities and other units conduct their affairs through
a president, as well as administrative and vigilance committees elected
by the general assembly of the membership. Community property and
members (comuneros) are within the administrative domains of
districts and provinces for all other civic purposes. In some areas, the
boundaries of the Peasant Communities coincide with those of a district,
as is frequently the case in the Mantaro Valley. In other areas,
community lands occupy only a portion of the district; there may also be
two separate Peasant Communities within a district, or districts with
residents who do not belong to the corporate organization.
Members of Peasant Communities and other corporate groups constitute
about 30 percent of all rural people and therefore have been a
significant factor in economic and political affairs throughout the
highlands and in some areas of the Costa, where the former plantations
passed into workers' hands after 1969. On the coast, there have long
been linkages between worker unions and the regional political powers,
but in the Sierra these ties have not developed strongly. The exception
is in the central highland department of Jun�n and in the southern
department of Puno, where in the 1980s there were powerful, organized
movements based on Peasant Communities and independent small farmers
groups allied with political parties. The influence of these groups was,
for the most part, localized.
Peru
Peru - Landlords and Peasant Revolts in the Highlands
Peru
In the great majority of highland provinces, political and economic
leadership and power were based on traditional social elites, a landlord
class that controlled the haciendas and, thus, very large proportions of
the rural poor. In these contexts, powerful landlords (terratenientes)
manipulated political affairs, either by themselves holding positions of
authority, such as the prefectures, municipal offices, and key
government posts, or influencing those who did. A tradition of
ruthlessness, greed, and abuse is associated with this system (gamonalismo)
throughout Peru. A gamonal is a person to be feared because he
has extraordinary and extralegal powers to protect his interests and act
against others. Although the agrarian reform of 1969 did much to cut
this power, local affairs in many districts and provinces have remained
under such domination, to the deep resentment of the rural poor, who
most directly feel its consequences.
Since the late nineteenth century, various regional movements have
arisen to address abuse. Historian Wilfredo K�psoli Escudero had
documented thirty-two peasant revolts and movements from 1879 to 1965, a
number that is not exhaustive but which contradicts the view that Peru's
native peasantry was passive in accepting its serfdom.
Characteristically, virtually all of these efforts were specifically
directed against the abuses of gamonales and hacendados, at
least in their initial phases. The forces in the 1885 Ancash uprising,
led by Pedro Pablo Atuspar�a, an alcalde ped�neo from a
village near Huaraz, eventually captured and held the Callej�n de
Huaylas Valley for several months before federal troops reclaimed it.
Most peasant revolts were not as dramatic, but all testified to the
burgeoning feelings of frustration, anger, and alienation that had built
up over the centuries. In part, this anger and frustration stemmed from
the fact that native American communities had been deprived of their
communal holdings after national independence, which meant that
extensive holdings passed from community control to private elite
interests. Demands for redress of this situation led to the
reestablishment of the official Indian Community in 1920 during the
second presidency of Augusto B. Legu�a (1919-30). Subsequently,
communities that could prove they at one time had held colonial title to
land were permitted to repossess it, a long and arduous bureaucratic
process in which the most successful communities were those with active
migrants in Lima who could lobby the government.
Another response was President Manuel A. Odr�a's (1948-56)
sanctioning of the Cornell-Peru project in which the Ministry of Labor
and Indian Affairs, in collaboration with Cornell University in Ithaca,
New York, would conduct a demonstration of community development and
land reform at Hacienda Vicos in Ancash Department, starting in 1952. It
was Peru's first such development program and received extensive
publicity around the country. This situation provoked consternation
among landlords and elite interests, which purposefully delayed the
conclusion of the project. The colonos of Vicos became an
independent community in 1962, when they were finally permitted to
purchase the estate they and their ancestors had cultivated for others
for 368 years.
With its widespread publicity, the Vicos project helped to whet
appetites for change. At that time, several hundred hacienda communities
like Vicos were requesting similar projects and the freedom to purchase
their lands. When the reluctant government of oligarch Manuel Prado y
Ugarteche (1939-45, 1956-62) and the slow and corrupt mechanisms of the
bureaucracy could not meet these rising demands, an explosive situation
developed. Peasant invasions of hacienda lands began a few days after
Fernando Bela�nde assumed office as president in 1963. He had promised
to organize a land reform, and the native communities, in their words,
were "helping" him keep his word. Hundreds of estates were
taken over by peasants, provoking a national crisis that eventually
subsided when Bela�nde convinced communities that his administration
would fulfill its promises. It did not happen.
However, on the "Day of the Indian" (D�a de la Raza--Race
Day), June 24, 1969, General Juan Velasco Alvarado (president, 1968-75),
head of the populist "Revolutionary Government of the Armed
Forces," decreed a sweeping and immediate land reform, ending
serfdom and private latifundios that included the sacrosanct
coastal plantations. Hope and expectations of the peasantry had never
been higher, but the succeeding years brought back the frustration;
serious problems resulted from natural disasters, the withdrawal of
significant international credit and support from the United States for
reform programs, bureaucratic failures, and a lack of welltrained
personnel. After the Velasco government gave way to more conservative
forces within the army in 1975, a retrenchment began. In this phase of
the process, some haciendas, including several in Ayacucho Department,
were returned to their former owners, provoking bitter disappointment
and further alienation among the peasants.
Peru
Peru - Shining Path and Its Impact
Peru
The social history of the 1960s and 1970s is background for the
emergence of the disturbing Shining Path (Sendero Luminoso-- SL)
movement. Its many violent actions have been directed against locally
elected municipal officials and anyone designated as a gamonal
in the departments of Ayacucho, Huancavelica, Apur�mac, Jun�n, Hu�nuco,
and portions of Ancash and Cusco departments, as well as some other
areas designated as emergency zones where government control was deeply
compromised. The Maoist-oriented SL opposed Lima as the metropolis that
usurps resources from the rest of the nation. Like most past
revolutionary movements (as opposed to peasant revolts) acting on behalf
of the poor, the SL leadership has consisted of disgruntled and angry
intellectuals, mestizos, and whites, apparently from provincial
backgrounds. Many adherents have been recruited from university and high
school ranks, where radical politicization has been a part of student
culture since the late nineteenth century. Others have come from the
cadres of embittered migrant youths living in urban lower-class
surroundings, disaffected and frustrated school teachers, and the
legions of alienated peasants in aggrieved highland provinces in
Huancavelica, Ayacucho, and adjacent areas.
Peru's socioeconomic and political disarray has taken on its present
pattern after four decades of extravagant demographic change, a
truncated land reform that never received effective funding or ancillary
support as needed in education, and incessant promises of development,
jobs, and progress without fulfillment. The SL has sought to eliminate
the perpetrators of past error to establish a new order of its own. The
SL's vengeful approach appeared attractive to many, coming at a time
when the migration pathway to social change appeared blocked, the
ability to progress by this method stymied by the economic crisis, and
rural development was at an all-time low ebb.
The immediate impact of the terror-inspiring violence of SL actions
and the correspondingly symmetrical responses of the Peruvian Arm (Ej�rcito
Peruano--EP) has had a devastating effect on rural and urban life,
public institutions, and agricultural production, especially in the
emergency zone department of Ayacucho. Since the SL's first brutal
attack on the defenseless people of Chuschi, its actions and the violent
reactions of the police and army have produced chaos throughout the
central highlands and deep problems in Lima.
From 1980 to 1990, an estimated 200,000 persons were driven from
their homes, with about 18,000 people killed, mostly in the department
of Ayacucho and neighboring areas. In five provinces in Ayacucho, the
resident population dropped by two-thirds, and many villages were
virtual ghost towns. This migration went to Lima, Ica, and Huancayo,
where disoriented peasants were offered little assistance and sometimes
were attacked by the police as suspected Senderistas (SL members). Many
communities have responded to SL attacks by organizing and fighting
back. Towns or villages in La Libertad and Cajamarca departments, in
particular, greatly amplified the system of rondas campesinas.
Elsewhere, the army organized local militias and patrols to combat and
ferret out SL cadres. Unfortunately, in addition to providing for
defense all of these actions left room for abuses, and there were
numerous cases of personal vendettas taking place that had little to do
with the task.
There was no question that the SL's revolutionary terrorism was
producing major disruptions and profound changes in Peruvian society.
Surveys indicated that 71 percent of Peruvians agreed that poverty,
social injustice, and the economic crisis were together the root cause
of the SL's revolution, and that 68 percent identified the SL as the
nation's most serious problem. Drug trafficking was ranked a distant
second by only 11 percent of respondents. At least one conclusion,
however, seemed abundantly clear: Peruvians had to address their
longstanding and deeply interrelated ills of poverty, inequity, and
ethnoracial discrimination if they hoped to take control of the
situation.
Peru
Peru - EDUCATION
Peru
In Peru schooling is regarded as the sine qua non of progress and the
key to personal advancement. In 1988 there were over 27,600 primary
schools in Peru, one for virtually every hamlet with over 200 persons
throughout the country. It is no exaggeration to say that the presence of a
village school and teacher is considered by the poor as the most
important first step on the road to "progress" out of poverty
and a state of disrespect, if not for themselves, for their children.
Because of the historical ethnic and racial discrimination against
native peoples, the village school became the instrument and method by
which one could learn Spanish, the most important step toward reducing
one's "visibility" as an identifiable object of denigration
and being able to gain mobility out of the native American caste. The
primary school also has provided the means to become a recognized
citizen because the exercise of citizenship and access to state services
require (in fact, if not officially) a basic ability to use written and
spoken Spanish. Thus, the spread of primary schools owed much to the
deep desire on the part of the native and rural poor to disassociate
themselves from the symbols of denigration. The thrust of Peruvian
education has been oriented toward this end, however subtly or even
unconsciously. School policies encouraged the discarding of native
American clothing and language, and the frequent school plays and skits
burlesqued native peoples' practices, such as coca chewing or fiestas,
or equated indigenous culture with drunkenness and, often, stupidity and
poverty, while at the same time exhorting native children to "lift
themselves up." The opposite pole to being native American was to
be Spanish- speaking, urban, white-collar, and educated.
The influence of these educational policies is reflected in the
currents of social change sweeping Peru in the second half of the
twentieth century. In the early 1960s, Peru was a nation where almost 39
percent of the population spoke native languages, half being bilingual
in Spanish and half monolingual in a native tongue. By 1981 only 9
percent were monolingual, and 18 percent remained bilingual. In 1990
over 72 percent claimed to speak only Spanish, whereas in 1961, about 60
percent did. In 1990 Quechua was by far the dominant native language
spoken in all departments, except Amazonas and Ucayali. Almost 80
percent of Aymara speakers lived in Puno, with many bilingual persons in
Arequipa, greater Lima, Tacna, and Moquegua. About 85 percent of the
population in 1991 was literate.
There are many technical and cultural difficulties associated with
gathering and reporting information on native languages. Because of
this, most experts have concluded that native languages are
significantly underreported with respect to bilingualism. According to
one study, native languages are the preferred means of communication
even within those households whose adult members are bilingual. However,
given the force of state policy in education and the many concomitant
pressures on the individual, Quechua and Aymara will likely survive
largely as second languages.
In the Sierra, where villages and communities are famous for their
voluntary work, the majority of self-financed public community projects
have been dedicated to the construction and maintenance of their escuelitas
(little schools) with little assistance except from their migrant clubs
and associations in Lima or other large cities. This overwhelming drive
to change personal, family, and community conditions by means of
education began at least 150 years ago, at a time when public education
was extremely limited and private schooling was open to only the elite
mestizo and white populations of the few major cities. In 1990, however,
28 percent of all Peruvians, over 5 million people, were matriculated in
primary or secondary schools, which were now within reach of people even
in the remotest of places.
In the mid-nineteenth century, aside from a few progressive districts
that operated municipal schools, most educational institutions were
privately operated. Individual teachers would simply open their own
institutes and through modest advertising gain a clientele of paying
students. There have been laws mandating public education since the
beginning of the republic, but they were not widely implemented. In 1866
the minister of justice and education sought to establish vocational
schools and uniform curricula for all public schools and to open schools
to women. The Constitutional Congress in 1867 idealistically called for
a secondary school for each sex in every provincial capital. With
constitutional changes and renewed attempts to modernize, it became the
obligation of every department and province to have full primary and
secondary education available, at least in theory, to any resident.
Primary education was later declared both free and compulsory for all
citizens.
The Ministry of Education in Lima exercises authority over a
sprawling network of schools for which it uniformly determines
curricula, textbook content, and the general values that guide classroom
activities nationwide. Because of the importance invested in education,
the role of the teacher is respected, especially at the district level,
where teachers readily occupy leadership positions. Owing to this
tendency, for many years teachers were prohibited from holding public
office on the theory that they would, like priests, exercise an unusual
level of influence in their districts. The power accruing to a teacher
as the only person with postsecondary education in a small rural town
can be considerable: the teacher is sought out to solve personal and
village problems, settle disputes, and act as spokesperson for the
community. Both men and women have eagerly sought teaching positions
because they have offered a unique opportunity for personal advancement.
In a nation steeped in androcentric traditions, however, teaching has
been especially important for women because it has been an avenue of
achieving upward mobility, gaining respect, and playing sociopolitical
roles in community affairs that have been otherwise closed to them.
Higher education is hence greatly respected. University professors
symbolize a high order of achievement, and they are addressed as profesor
or profesora. The same recognition of educational achievement
is given to other fields as well. Anyone receiving an advanced degree in
engineering is always addressed as engineer (ingeniero) or doctor.
The titles are prestigious and valued and permanently identify one as an
educated person to be rewarded with respect. The titles are therefore
coveted, and on graduation the new status is often announced in El
Comercio, Lima's oldest daily newspaper.
In 1990, in addition to its primary schools, Peru counted over 5,400
secondary schools (colegios) of all types. Although these too
were widely distributed throughout the country, the best secondary
schools were heavily concentrated in the major cities and especially in
Lima. There, the elite private international institutions and Peruvian
Catholic schools have offered excellent programs featuring multilingual
instruction and preparation aimed at linking students with foreign
universities. The private Catholic schools throughout the country, both
primary and secondary, have been highly regarded for their efforts to
instill discipline and character.
Because it is required by law that each provincial capital have a
public secondary school, such schools historically have come to enjoy
special status as surrogate intellectual centers in the absence of
universities in their regions. The tradition of strong high school
alumni allegiance is pronounced, with organizations and reunions
commonplace and attachments to classmates (condisc�pulos)
enduring. The importance of a high school diploma is further emphasized
by each graduating class, which bestows honor on some personage or event
by naming its graduation after them. High school graduates take the
selection of the class name as an opportunity to make a statement about
things that concern them and choose one that embodies their thoughts.
This custom is followed by university graduating classes as well.
Because people correlate social and economic well-being with
educational achievement, schooling becomes essential not only for its
functional usefulness but also for social reasons. The concept of
education is infused with high intrinsic value, and educated people by
definition are more cultivated (culto), worthy, and qualified
to be admired as role models than others. Educated persons are thought
to have the duty to speak out and address public issues on behalf of
others less privileged; many students have accepted this responsibility
as part of their student role.
The development of national identity is another area to which public
education is firmly committed. In the wake of the devastating War of the
Pacific--in which Peru lost territory, wealth, dignity, and pride--the
emergent public school system became the major vehicle by which citizens
established strong linkages to the state. Primary and secondary school
curricula are thus heavily laden with patriotic, if not jingoistic,
nationalism, elements of which are written into the nation's textbooks
by the Ministry of Education. If nothing else, the primary school pupil
learns that he or she is a Peruvian and that many of Peru's national
heroes, such as Admiral Miguel Grau, Colonel Francisco Bolognesi, and
Leoncio Prado, were martyrized on the nation's behalf by Chilean forces
against whom one must be constantly on guard. Ecuador is viewed in this
same tenor, but perceived as less menacing, constituting a vague threat
to the nation's security or Amazonic oil rights.
The school calendar is thus filled with observances and ceremonies
honoring national heroes and martyrs, including T�pac Amaru II (Jos�
Gabriel Condorcanqui). Parades, drum and bugle corps (banda de
querra--war band), and flag bearers spend dozens of hours in school
yards preparing for the celebration of national holidays (fiestas
patrias), national independence day affairs that are the feature of
every district, province, and department capital each year on July 27
and 28. In Lima the tradition of fiestas patrias involves a
major display of military forces and equipment accompanied by high
school units parading the length of Avenida Brasil (Brazil Avenue)
across Lima. Completing the essentially military focus on nationalism in
the public schools is the pupil uniform, a military cadet-type outfit
for boys that includes a cap introduced by the General Manuel Odr�a
regime in the 1950s.
<>Universities
Peru
Peru - Universities
Peru
As the first university founded in the Americas in 1551, the National
Autonomous University of San Marcos (Universidad Nacional Aut�nomo de
San Marcos--UNAM) has had a long and varied history of elitism, reform,
populism, controversy, respect, prestige, and, especially since the
mid-1980s, conflict and confusion born of political divisions and broad
social unrest. Although it remained the largest university in the
nation, it had lost much of its former prestige by 1990. In the 1970-90
period, several smaller private institutions, such as the Pontifical
Catholic University of Peru (Pont�fica Universidad Cat�lica del Per�),
located in <"http://worldfacts.us/Peru-Lima.htm">Lima, have gained more stature. The major public universities
are the specialized National Agrarian University (Universidad Nacional
Agrario--UNA) in Lima's La Molina District and the National Engineering
University (Universidad Nacional de Ingenier�a), also in the Lima area.
The most prestigious medical school is the private Cayetano Hered�a in
Lima.
Lima has captured most of the resources of higher education.
Universities in Lima, which had 42 percent of all students, employed 62
percent of all faculty in the late 1980s. Nevertheless, there are
universities in all but four of the departments. Although many of these
are newly founded and poorly equipped, the demand for access to advanced
study has provided them with a growing stream of students. The abandoned
colonial University of Huamanga (Universidad de Huamanga) in Ayacucho is
one of these, having been reopened in the late 1950s to fill an
educational void for students drawn from impoverished and isolated
Ayacucho Department. Although initiated on its modern course with high
hopes, it has suffered from budgetary inadequacies, frustrated plans,
and disgruntled students impatient for social change. During the late
1960s, it became the home to embittered revolutionaries, who emerged as
the leaders of the SL movement.
The public schools have long been deeply influenced by political
factionalism, which has divided the constitutionally established
governing bodies of universities. Internal politics at San Marcos and
other universities have involved complex alliance-making among
administrators, staff, faculty, and the student body, as well as
partisan political forces that crosscut these sectors with their own
agendas. Thus, APRA, various communist factions, and other groups have
played out their strategies, often with negative consequences or even
little direct reference to the mission of education as such. APRA,
however, did play a role in establishing the University of the Center
(Universidad del Centro) in Huancayo and Federico Villareal in Lima, now
the second-largest university. The present organization of the public
universities was originally conceived as a result of the Latin
American-wide university reform movement of the 1920s and 1930s which
attempted to democratize the traditional, colonial-style elite
traditions. What has evolved, however, has led to constant problems of
paralytic conflict, student strikes, slogan mongering, and, often,
closure of a university for one or more semesters at a time. As a
result, the private universities, such as those tied to the Catholic
Church and various segments of the upper-middle classes, have emerged as
the most stable and best staffed institutions during the last
twenty-five years.
Out of this milieu, one can begin to understand the political role of
teachers and their organizations, such as the Trade Union of Education
Workers (Sindicato �nico de Trabajadores de la Ense�anza del Per�--SUTEP),
the national teachers union. Most teachers attend teaching colleges
before entering the classroom with their certificates, and many of these
colleges, such as La Cantuta outside of Lima, have long been centers for
radical politics. With teachers earning less than the average beginning
police officer, discontent has run high among teachers for many years.
Thus, given the importance and role of teachers in district schools
nationwide, it is not surprising that SUTEP has been a strong voice in
expressing its social and economic discontent or that the SL and MRTA
had succeeded in recruiting followers from the ranks of SUTEP.
Peru
Peru - HEALTH
Peru
In the early 1990s, Peru was hit by a cholera epidemic, which
highlighted longstanding health care problems. Review of health
statistics amply illustrates Peru's vulnerability to disease and the
uneven distribution of resources to combat it. The most and the best of
the health facilities were concentrated in metropolitan Lima, followed
by the principal older coastal cities, including Arequipa, and the rest
of the country. The differences among these regions were not trivial.
Whereas Lima had a doctor for every 400 persons on average, and other
coastal areas had a ratio of one doctor for every 2,000, the highland
departments had one doctor for every 12,000 persons. The same levels of difference applied with respect to
hospital beds, nurses, and all the medical specialties.
In the early 1990s, over 25 percent of urban residences and over 90
percent of rural residences lacked basic potable water and sewerage.
Thus, the population has been inevitably exposed to a wide variety of
waterborne diseases. The incidence of disease not surprisingly reflected
the inequities evidenced in the health system: the leading causes of
death by infectious diseases have varied from year to year, but
invariably the principal ones have been respiratory infections,
gastroenteritis, common colds, malaria, tuberculosis, influenza,
measles, chicken pox, and whooping cough. The cholera epidemic, which
began in 1990 and claimed international headlines, ranked well down the
list of causes for death behind these others, which have been endemic
and basically taken for granted. In a typical case, during one year in
Huaylas District, which had a small clinic and often was fortunate
enough to have a doctor in residence, 40 percent of all deaths
registered were children below four years of age, who died because of a
regional influenza epidemic.
Although Peru's infant mortality rate per 1,000 live births dropped
from 130 to 80 over a 26-year period (1965-91), the rate in 1991 was
still over twice the rate of Colombia and four times the rate of Chile.
The mortality rate for children under 5 was also brought down greatly,
from 233 per 1,000 in 1960 to 107 per 1,000 in 1991. Both measures for
1991 still exceeded all the other Latin American countries except
Bolivia and Haiti. The only direct measure of social welfare that
deteriorated was nutrition: calorie consumption per capita fell 5
percent from the average for 1964-66 to 1984-86. In 1988 calorie
consumption was 2,269, as compared with 2,328 in 1987. Because calorie
consumption levels generally parallel income levels, the decrease must
have been concentrated at the level of the extremely poor.
Peru's lack of general well-being was further suggested by the
nation's high and growing dependence on foreign food since 1975 through
direct imports, which had increased 300 percent, and food assistance
programs, which showed a tenfold increment. The United States has been
by far the largest provider of food assistance to Peru through its
multiple programs administered under the Food for Peace (Public Law 480)
projects of the United States Agency for International Development
(AID). During the 1980s, food aid amounted to over 50 percent of all
United States economic assistance. The aid was delivered as maternal and
child health assistance and food-for-work programs administered by CARE
(Cooperative for American Relief), church-related private voluntary
organizations, or by direct sale to the Peruvian government for urban
market resale.
Peru's totally inadequate social security system, operated by the
Peruvian Institute of Social Security (Instituto Peruano de Seguridad
Social--IPSS), did not remain exempt from the Fujimori government's
privatization policy. As a result of two legislative decrees passed in
November 1991, Peru's system for providing social security retirement
and health benefits underwent significant modification. The changes were
similar to those made by the military government of Chile in the early
1980s, when employees were given a choice of either remaining with the
existing system or joining private systems set up on an individual
capitalization basis. The Fujimori government decided to adopt the
Chilean social security model almost completely. The stated objectives
were to permit open market competition, alleviate the government's
financial burden by having it shared by the private sector, improve
coverage and the quality of benefits, and provide wider access to other
social sectors. Private Pension Funds Administrators (Administradoras de
Fondos de Pensiones--AFPs) were expected to begin operating in June
1993. A presidential decree in December 1992 ended the IPSS's monopoly
on pensions. This provided a boost to Peru's small and underdeveloped
capital market by allowing the AFPs to invest in bonds issued by the
government or Central Reserve Bank (Banco Central de Reservas--BCR, also
known as Central Bank) as well as in companies.
The cholera and other health and social issues in Peru were
interrelated closely with the country's steadily worsening environmental
conditions. The high levels of pollution in large sectors of Lima,
Chimbote, and other coastal centers had resulted from uncontrolled
dumping of industrial, automotive, and domestic wastes that had created
a gaseous atmosphere. The loss of irrigated coastal farmland to urban
sprawl, erosion of highland farms, and the clear-cutting of Amazonian
forest all have conspired to impoverish the nation's most valuable
natural resources and further exacerbate social dilemmas. Although Peru
is endowed with perhaps the widest range of resources in South America,
somehow they have never been coherently or effectively utilized to
construct a balanced and progressive society. The irony of Peru's
condition was captured long ago in the characterization of the nation as
being a "pauper sitting on a throne of gold." How to put the
gold in the pauper's pockets without destroying the chair on which to
sit is a puzzle that Peruvians and their international supporters have
yet to solve.
Peru
Peru - The Economy
Peru
THE PERUVIAN ECONOMY achieved a higher rate of economic growth than
the average for Latin America from 1950 to 1965, but since then has
turned from one of the more dynamic to one of the most deeply troubled
economies in the region. Even in the period of rapid growth, Peru was
characterized by exceptionally high degrees of poverty and inequality,
and since the late 1980s poverty has become much worse. Major changes in
economic strategy introduced in 1990 and 1991 offer new hope for future
growth but have not been oriented toward reduction of poverty and
inequality.
In the first post-World War II decades, Peru achieved an
above-average rate of growth with low levels of inflation and with
rising exports of its diversified primary products. Output per capita
grew 2.9 percent a year in the decade of the 1950s and then 3.2 percent
annually in the first half of the 1960s, compared with the regional
growth rate of 2.0 percent for these fifteen years. As of 1960, income
per capita was 17 percent above the median for Latin American countries.
However, since the mid1960s the economy has run into increasing
difficulties. Output per capita failed to grow at all from 1965 to 1988,
then fell below its 1965 level in 1989 and 1990. The previously moderate
rate of inflation accelerated, balance of payments deficits became a
chronic problem, and the country accumulated a deep external debt. As
poverty worsened, political violence in the countryside and cities grew
increasingly intense. The economy and the society as a whole seemed to
lose coherence and any sense of direction.
The reasons for this deterioration from 1965 to 1991 are complex and
very much open to debate. Many aspects of the debate center on two
opposing conceptions of what national economic strategy and goals should
be. One conviction is that the best course is to keep the economic
system open to foreign trade and investment, to avoid extensive
government intervention in the economy, and to rely mainly on private
enterprise for basic decisions on production and investment. The
contrary conception favors restricting foreign trade and investment
while promoting an active government role in the economy to accelerate
industrialization, to reduce inequality, and to control the actions of
private investors. The conflict between these economic models is
familiar in the experience of all Latin American countries. The failure
to reconcile them in Peru has been an important factor in the
deteriorating economic performance since the mid-1960s.
At least five interacting problems have been important in the
explanation of why the economy has deteriorated so badly since the
mid-1960s. First, natural resource limits began to handicap further
expansion of primary product exports, requiring difficult changes in the
structures of production and trade. Second, partly in response to these
constraints, and partly as a matter of a growing conviction that the
country needed to industrialize more rapidly, successive governments
began to promote industrialization through protection against imports,
reversing the country's traditional policy of relatively open trade.
Third, dissatisfaction with widespread inequality and poverty encouraged
attempts at radical social change, but the two governments that tried to
lead the way--those of General Juan Velasco Alvarado (1968-75) and Alan
Garc�a P�rez (1985-90)--failed to find any effective answers or to
maintain viable macroeconomic policies. Fourth, the temporary move back
toward a more open economy under the second government of Fernando Bela�nde
Terry (1980-85) resulted in a surge of imports and an external
crisis--mainly because of currency overvaluation and an excessively
rapid rise of government spending--that again discredited this approach.
And finally, rural violence took on a profoundly destructive character
with the growth of the Shining Path (Sendero Luminoso-- SL) and the
cocaine industry. On top of those two sources of violence, weakening
governmental capability to maintain order and worsening conditions of
employment led to growing security problems in cities.
Deteriorating conditions since the mid-1960s need to be considered
against the background of a deeply divided society and a considerable
lag, compared with many other Latin American countries, in developing
either a competitive industrial sector or a modern structure of public
administration able to implement public policies effectively. These
handicaps can be overstated. After all, the Peruvian economy functioned
well up to the mid1960s , and both private business and government
officials have gained experience since then. As of the beginning of the
1990s, however, the country's prolonged decline had seriously undermined
public confidence in the possibilities for recuperation and renewed
growth.
The most evident symptoms of the crisis at the beginning of the 1990s
were falling national output and income, high levels of unemployment and
underemployment, worsening poverty and violence, accelerating inflation,
and deep external debt. Under the Bela�nde administration, the external
debt grew too high for Peru to meet scheduled service payments, although
the government maintained the position that payments would be resumed
when possible. Under the next government, Garc�a made a point of
declaring that payments would be unilaterally limited to 10 percent of
export earnings. His more aggressive position led to a near-total cutoff
of external credit, which remained in effect throughout his term.
The government of Alberto K. Fujimori (1990- ) adopted a drastic
stabilization program to break out of this complex of problems by first
attacking the forces driving inflation. The initial shock of the new
measures, which more than doubled the consumer price level in a single
day, nearly paralyzed markets and production. After a steep fall in
output, the economy began to stabilize with a lower rate of inflation
but without any strong signs of recovery. Although the Fujimori program
included many lines of intended action beyond the initial shock, it
remained incomplete in many respects. It raised a host of questions
about what other policies would reactivate the economy while preventing
any further burst of inflation, and how long it would take to restore
something like Peru's earlier capacity for growth.
Peru
Peru - History of the Economy
Peru
Through the nineteenth century and into the mid-twentieth century,
the great majority of the Peruvian population depended on agriculture
and lived in the countryside. By 1876 Lima was the only Peruvian city
with over 100,000 people--only 4 percent of the population. Much of the
impetus for economic growth came from primary exports. In common with
the rest of Latin America up to the 1930s, Peru maintained an open
economic system with little government intervention and few restrictions
on either imports or foreign investment. Such investment became highly
important in the twentieth century, especially in the extraction of raw
materials for export.
For many Latin American countries, the impact of falling export
prices and curtailed external credit in the Great Depression of the
1930s led to fundamental changes in economic policies. Many governments
began to raise protection against imports in order to stimulate domestic
industry and to take more active roles in shaping economic change. But
Peru held back from this common move and kept on with a relatively open
economy. That put it behind many other countries in post-World War II
industrialization and led to increasing pressures for change.
Significant protection started in the 1960s, accompanied by both new
restrictions on foreign investment and a more active role of government
in the economy.
One of the country's basic problems has been that the growth of
population in the twentieth century outran the capability to use labor
productively. The ratio of arable land to population-- much lower than
the average for Latin America--continued decreasing through the 1970s.
Employment in the modern manufacturing sector did not grow fast enough
to keep up with the growth of the labor force, let alone provide enough
opportunities for people moving out of rural poverty to seek urban
employment. The manufacturing sector's employment as a share of the
labor force fell from 13 percent in 1950 to 10 percent in 1990.
Orientation Toward Primary Product Exports
Peru's most famous exports have been gold, silver, and guano. Its
gold was taken out on a large scale by the Spanish for many years
following the conquest and is of little significance now, but silver
remains an important export. Guano served as Europe's most important
fertilizer in the mid-nineteenth century and made Peru for a time the
largest Latin American exporter to Europe. The guano boom ran out about
1870, after generating a long period of exceptional economic growth.
When the guano boom ended, the economy retreated temporarily but then
recovered with two new directions for expansion. One was a new set of
primary product exports and the other a turn toward more industrial
production for the domestic market.
The alternative primary exports that initially replaced guano
included silver, cotton, rubber, sugar, and lead. As of 1890, silver
provided 33 percent of all export earnings, sugar 28 percent, and
cotton, rubber, and wool collectively 37 percent. Copper became
important at the beginning of the twentieth century, followed on a
smaller scale by petroleum after 1915. Then, in the post-World War II
period, fish meal from anchovies caught off the Peruvian coast became
yet another highly valuable primary product export. Industrial products
remained notably absent from Peru's list of exports until the 1970s. As
late as 1960, manufactured goods were only 1 percent of total exports.
Manufacturing for the home market has had many ups and downs. The
first major downturn came with the guano boom of the mid- nineteenth
century. Foreign-exchange earnings from guano exports became so abundant
and, therefore, imported goods so cheap that much of Peru's small-scale
local industry went out of production. The end of the guano boom
relieved this pressure, and in the 1890s a new factor, a prolonged
depreciation of the currency, came into play to stimulate manufacturing.
The currency was at that time based on silver, and falling world market
prices for silver in this period acted to raise both import prices and
export values (of products other than silver), relative to Peruvian
costs of production. Without any overt change in national policies, Peru
began a process of import-substitution
industrialization combined with stronger incentives
for exports. Domestic entrepreneurs responded successfully, and the
economy began to show promising signs of more diversified and autonomous
growth.
This redirection of Peruvian development was in turn sidetracked in
the 1900-1930 period, in part by a decision to abandon the silver-based
currency and adopt the gold standard instead. The change was intended to
make the currency more stable and, in particular, to remove the
inflationary effect of depreciation. The change succeeded in making the
currency more stable and to some degree in holding down inflation, but
Peruvian costs and prices nevertheless rose gradually relative to
external prices. That trend hurt exports and the trade balance,
especially in the 1920s, but instead of devaluing the currency to
correct the country's weakening competitive position, the government
chose to borrow abroad to keep up its value.
As has been noted, many Latin American countries reacted to the Great
Depression by imposing extensive import restrictions and by adopting
more activist government policies to promote industrialization. But at
that point, Peru departed from the common pattern by rejecting the trend
toward protection and intervention. After a brief experience with
populist-style controls from 1945 to 1948, Peru returned to the open
economy model and a basically conservative style of internal economic
management, in sharp contrast to the growing emphasis on import
substitution and government control in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and
Colombia.
Aided by the early recovery of some of its main exports in the 1930s,
and then by development of new primary exports in the early post-World
War II period, Peru had in many respects the most successful economy in
Latin America up to the mid-1960s. But increasing pressure on the land
from a rapidly growing population, accompanied by rising costs and
limited supplies of some of the country's natural resources, began to
intensify demands for change. One of the worst blows for continued
reliance on growth of primary exports was a sudden drop in the fish
catch that provided supplies for Peru's important fish meal exports;
over-fishing plus adverse changes in the ocean currents off Peru cut
supplies drastically in the early 1970s. That reversal coincided with supply
problems in copper mining. Costs had begun to rise steeply in the older
mines, and development of new projects required such large- scale
investment that the foreign companies dominant in copper hesitated to go
ahead with them. Further, population pressure and increasing
difficulties in raising output of food converted Peru into an importer
for a rising share of its food supply and began to work against use of
land for agricultural exports. Although new investment and better
agricultural techniques could presumably have helped a great deal, it
began to seem likely that the only way to maintain high rates of growth
would be to shift the structure of the economy more toward the
industrial sector. Evolution of Foreign Investment
During its long period of attachment to an open economic system, Peru
welcomed foreign investment and in some periods adopted tax laws
specifically designed to encourage it. That is to say, until the 1960s
the small fraction of Peruvians in a position to determine the country's
economic policies welcomed foreign investment without paying much
attention to growing signs of popular opposition. In the 1960s, many
things changed. The major change for foreign investors was that growing
criticism of their role in the economy led to nationalization of several
of the largest firms and to much more restrictive legislation.
Foreign investment played a relatively minor role in the nineteenth
century, although it included railroads, British interests in banking
and oil, and United States participation in sugar production and
exports. Its role grew rapidly in the twentieth century, concentrated
especially in export fields. In 1901, just as Peruvian copper began to
gain importance, United States firms entered and began buying up all but
the smallest of the country's copper mines. The International Petroleum
Company (IPC), a Canadian subsidiary of Standard Oil of New Jersey,
established domination of oil production by 1914 through purchase of the
restricted rights needed to work the main oil fields. The trend to
foreign entry in manufacturing as well as finance and mining was
stimulated by promotional legislation under the eleven-year government
of Augusto B. Legu�a y Salcedo (1908-12, 1919-30), an initially elected
president turned dictator who regarded foreign investment as the key to
modernization of Peru. That much-publicized partnership between a
repressive government and foreign investors was to play an important
role for the future of Peru, by feeding convictions that foreign
investment was inescapably linked to control of the country by the few
at the expense of the public.
By the end of the 1920s, foreign firms accounted for over 60 percent
of Peru's exports. The Great Depression of the 1930s changed that by
bringing new foreign investment to a halt and by driving down the prices
of the products of foreign firms (chiefly copper) much further than
those exported by Peruvian firms. That double effect brought the share
of exports by foreign firms down to about 30 percent by the end of the
1940s. Foreign investment remained low in the first postwar years, both
because investors in the industrialized countries were preoccupied at
home and because it was not encouraged by the populist government in
Peru from 1945 to 1948. After a military coup installed a conservative
dictator in 1948, the government offered a renewed welcome to foreign
investors, made particularly effective by the Mining Code of 1950. This
law offered very favorable tax provisions and quickly led to an upsurge
of new investment. History repeated itself: as in the 1920s, a
repressive government turned to foreign investors for economic growth
and for its own support, adding fuel to widespread public distrust of
foreign firms.
Public opposition to foreign ownership focused particularly on the
largest firms owning and exporting natural resources, above all in
copper and petroleum. The IPC became the center of increasing conflict
over the terms of its operating rights and its financial support of
conservative governments. When Bela�nde (1963-68, 1980-85) took office
as president in 1963, he promised to reopen negotiations over the
contract with IPC, but he then delayed the question for years and
finally backed away from this promise in 1968. His failure to act
provoked the military coup led by General Velasco, this time from the
left wing. The Velasco government promptly nationalized IPC and started
a determined campaign to restrict foreign investment. Although the
government subsequently moderated its hostility to foreign firms,
continuing disputes and then the deterioration of the economy led some
companies to withdraw and held foreign investment down to very low
levels through the 1980s.
The redirection of economic strategy under the Fujimori government in
1990-91 included a return to welcoming conditions for foreign
investment, providing a much more favorable legal context, and
disavowing completely the control-oriented policies of the governments
of Velasco and Garc�a. Several foreign oil companies responded
immediately, although the disorganized state of the economy and the
context of political violence discouraged any general inflow of new
foreign investment.
Peru
Peru - Agriculture
Peru
Perhaps the most important fact about the agricultural sector is that
its production has not kept up with the growth of population. Total
output of agriculture and fishing combined rose 63 percent between 1965
and 1988, but output per capita fell by 11 percent. Output per capita
started falling in the early 1950s, climbed back up again to its 1950
level by 1970, then began a more pronounced and prolonged fall through
the 1980s. Per capita output of food, as distinct from total
agriculture, did better: it increased 1 percent during the period from
the early 1980s to the late 1980s.
The downward trend in agricultural production per capita was
accompanied by a fall in the share of output going to exports. From 1948
to 1952, Peru exported 23 percent of its agricultural output; by 1976
the export share was down to 8 percent. The trade balance for the
agricultural sector remained consistently positive through the 1970s but
then turned into an import surplus for the 1980s.
Although agricultural production in the aggregate failed to keep up
with population growth, a few important products stood out as
exceptions. With favorable support prices, output of rice increased at
an annual rate of 7.9 percent in the 1980s. Changes in production
techniques helped raise output of chickens and eggs at a rate of 6.5
percent in this period. The Ministry of Agriculture interpreted these
positive results as evidence of what could be accomplished more
generally with better incentives and improvement of agricultural
techniques. For many crops, extremely wide variations in output per
hectare, even in similar conditions of land and water supply, suggest
that if effective extension services were implemented average
productivity could be raised to levels closer to those achieved by
leading producers. Contrary to the experience
of many other countries in the region, productivity for most crops other
than rice showed little or no improvement from 1979 to 1989.
Obstacles to increasing agricultural production include the poor
quality of much of the country's land and the high degree of dependence
on erratic supplies of water, plus the negative effects of public
policies toward agriculture. Frequent recourse to price controls on food
and in some periods to subsidized imports of food have hurt agricultural
incentives as a byproduct of efforts to hold down prices for urban
consumers. In general, government policies have persistently favored
urban consumers at the expense of rural producers.
Another important set of questions bearing on agricultural
productivity concerns the effects of the Agrarian Reform Law of 1969.
The reform itself came long after the beginning of the decline in output
per capita and was at first accompanied by a brief upturn. But the
downtrend set in again from 1972 on and continued through the 1980s. The
major question about the effects of the reform on productivity concerns
the fact that most of the large estates taken away from prior owners
were turned into cooperatives, made up of the former permanent workers
on the estates. One problem was that the workers lacked management
experience and a second was that incentives for individual participants
were often unclear. Shares in earnings of the cooperative as a whole
were not closely related to the individual member's time and effort,
with the result that many of them concentrated on small parcels
allocated to production for their own families rather than production
for the cooperative. The performances of the cooperatives turned out to
be highly varied. Some, particularly those with relatively good land and
markets were able to raise output and group earnings more successfully
than the previous landowners. But many were not, and by the end of the
1970s many of the cooperatives were either bankrupt or close to becoming
so. The tension between individual incentives and concern for the
functions of the cooperative as a whole led to a general turn toward
"decollectivization" at the end of the 1970s, breaking up the
cooperatives into individual holdings. When the practice was made legal
by the Bela�nde government in 1980, it spread rapidly. The
decollectivization has given Peruvian agriculture a much stronger
component of individual family farming than it has ever had before. The
large haciendas are gone, and the new farms are closer to a viable
family-supporting size than has been true of the minifundios of
the Sierra. The consequences for agricultural productivity and growth
were still unclear in 1991: incentives for individual effort were
greater but the smaller production units may have lost some economies of
scale. An econometric study of land productivity in north-coast
agriculture, tracing output from prior cooperatives through individual
results with the same land in the 1980s, brings out a wide variety of
results rather than any great change in total. It shows that the
individual holdings have on average done slightly better than the
preceding cooperatives on the same land, chiefly by greater inputs of
labor per hectare, but not enough better to make any convincing case of
superiority. The authors of this study rightly emphasize that results in
the 1980s cannot be explained adequately only in terms of farming
practices because productivity was also adversely affected by the
deterioration of the economic system as a whole.
In addition to the negative effects on agriculture of economy-wide
disequilibrium in the 1980s, some areas were badly hurt in this period
by increased violence and partial depopulation. The violence worsened
from 1988 through 1990, driving people out of farms and whole villages
and leaving productive land and equipment idle. In some of the worst-hit
areas, production had fallen in half.
Peru
Peru - Fishing
Peru
Peru's rich fishery has been utilized since ancient times, but it was
not until the post-World War II decades that an extensive export
industry developed. Peru's fishing industry rapidly expanded in the
1950s to make the country the world's foremost producer and exporter of
fish meal. Although a large variety of fish are caught offshore, the
rapid growth was primarily in the catching of anchovies for processing
into fish meal. The fish meal boom provided a major stimulus to the
economy and accounted for more than a quarter of exports in the mid1960s
.
In the 1960s, however, there were indications that the nation's
offshore fishing area was being overfished. Experts estimated that the
fish catch should be about 8 to 9 million tons a year if overfishing was
to be avoided. In 1965 the government attempted to limit the annual fish
catch to 7 million tons but without success, partly because investments
in ships and processing facilities greatly exceeded that level. By the
late 1960s, a finite resource was being depleted. In 1970 the anchovy
catch peaked at over 12 million tons.
Peru's rich fishing grounds are largely the result of the cold
offshore Humboldt Current (Peruvian Current) that causes a welling up of
marine and plant life on which the fish feed. Periodically, El Ni�o (The
Christ-child), a warm-water current from the north, pushes farther south
than normal and disrupts the flow of the Humboldt Current, destroying
the feed for fish. In such years, the fish catch drops dramatically. The
intrusion of El Ni�o occurred in 1965, 1972, and 1982-83, for example.
The 1972 catch, a quarter its peak size, contributed to a crisis in the
fish meal industry and the disappearance of fish meal as a leading
Peruvian export during most of the 1970s.
In 1973 the government nationalized fish processing and marketing.
However, the fish industry became a large drain on the government budget
as the national fish company paid off former owners for their
nationalized assets, reduced excess capacity, and processed a meager
catch of less than 4 million tons. Partly to reduce the drain on
revenue, in 1976 the government sold the fishing fleet back to private
enterprise. Emphasis was also shifted away from fish meal, mainly from
anchovies, to edible fish and exports of canned and frozen fish
products.
The fishing industry recovered in the late 1970s, but the return of
El Ni�o in 1982-83 devastated the industry until the mid-1980s. By 1986
the total fish catch exceeded 5.5 million tons and by 1988, 5.9 million
tons, with exports of fish meal valued at US$379 million. The 1989 catch
totaled 10 million tons, an increase of 34 percent over 1988, and fish
meal exports were worth US$410 million. In late 1991, Congress passed a
decree that eliminated all restrictions and monopolies on the production
and marketing of fish products and encouraged investment in the
industry.
Peru
Peru - Manufacturing
Peru
The industrial sector has had its problems too, especially in the
1980s. Manufacturing production grew more rapidly than the economy as a
whole up to that decade. It increased at a compound annual rate of 3.8
percent between 1965 and 1980. But it grew only 1.6 percent a year from
1980 to 1988, and then plunged 23 percent in the ghastly economic
conditions of 1989.
Of dominant importance in the 1980s were food processing, textiles,
chemicals, and basic metals; food processing alone accounted for nearly
one-third of total manufacturing output. For the period 1980-88, when
total manufacturing production increased by only about 5 percent, food
processing rose by nearly 23 percent. Production of basic metals went
the other way, falling by almost 22 percent. Output of metal products
and machinery, closely associated with capital goods and investment,
fell by 7 percent from 1980 to 1988, and then fell by one-fourth between
1988 and December 1989.
The weak picture for manufacturing in the 1980s did not result from
any intrinsic obstacle on the side of productive capacity but from the
overall weakness of the economy and of domestic markets. The sector's
ability to increase production under better economic conditions was
demonstrated by what happened between 1985 and 1987, in the successful
first half of the Garc�a administration when aggregate demand was
stimulated but inflation had not yet gotten out of control;
manufacturing output shot up 34 percent between these two years.
The modern manufacturing sector has relied on relatively
capital-intensive and import-intensive methods of production, failing to
provide much help for employment. Manufacturing value increased from 20
to 22 percent of GDP between 1950 and 1990, but its share of total
employment fell from 13 to 10 percent. Its dependence on imports of current inputs and
capital equipment has probably resulted in large measure from the
combination of an overvalued currency with high protection against
competing imports. Overvaluation holds down the prices of imported
equipment and supplies, making them artificially cheap relative to labor
and other domestic inputs. Protection adds to the problem by allowing
those firms that prefer the most modern possible equipment, even when it
is more expensive than domestic alternatives, to pass on any extra costs
to captive domestic consumers. In addition, protection saddled
industrial firms themselves with high-cost inputs from other domestic
firms, raising their costs to levels that have made it extremely
difficult for even the most efficient to compete in export markets.
Growth of manufacturing, as of the whole economy, has been held back
seriously by the failure so far to achieve any sustained growth of
industrial exports. The sector acts as a drag on the possibilities of
overall growth by using a great deal more of the country's scarce
foreign exchange to import its supplies and equipment than it earns by
its exports. This issue is key to future growth. Directing manufacturing
production more toward exports would provide a new avenue for growth
through sales to world markets and would also help relax the
foreign-exchange constraints that so frequently hold back the whole
economy.
Peru
Peru - Mining and Oil
Peru
The mining sector, including oil, accounted for only 9 percent of GDP
in 1988 but nearly half of the country's export earnings. Its share of
total exports increased from 45 percent in 1970 to 48 percent in 1988.
Copper alone accounted for 24.4 percent of total export earnings in 1970
and 22.5 percent in 1988.
Mining developed as an export sector, first for precious metals and
then chiefly for nonferrous metals needed by the industrialized
countries rather than by non-industrialized Peru. Mining has always been
an enclave, only weakly related to the domestic economy for its supplies
or for its markets. But it has been a principal provider of the foreign
exchange and tax revenue needed to keep the rest of the economy going.
That key role made the dominance of foreign ownership, especially in
copper and oil, a focus of bitter conflict for many years. The sector
became the center of intense debate over dependency, exploitation, and
national policy toward foreign investment.
Foreign investment was the main source of mining development up to
the 1960s, starting from the turn of the century in copper and extending
to a wide range of metals after the highly favorable Mining Code was
enacted in 1950. The sector was divided between the largest mines, which
produced roughly two-thirds of metal output and owned by foreign firms,
and the small-to-medium size mines , which supplied the other one-third
of output and were under Peruvian ownership. Following the Mining Code
of 1950, foreign investment flowed into iron ore, lead, zinc, and other
minerals, and metals exports grew from 21 percent of total exports in
1951 to over 40 percent a decade later.
When the military overthrew the government of Bela�nde in 1968, the
immediate issue was a conflict with IPC, the foreign firm dominating the
oil industry. The Velasco regime quickly nationalized IPC and then in
the 1970s also nationalized the largest copper mining corporation, Cerro
de Pasco. It established the Peruvian State Mining Enterprise (Empresa
de Miner�a Peruana- -Mineroper�) as the main state firm for
development of copper and the Peruvian State Mineral Marketing Company
(Mineroper� Comercial--Minpeco) as the new state mining marketing
agency.
Output of metal products was erratic in the early 1970s but then took
a big jump with completion of a major new copper-mining project,
Cuajone, in 1976. By 1980 value added in the sector, at constant prices,
was 1.5 times as high as in 1970. But then in the 1980s, value added
began to fall, along with practically everything else. By 1988 it was 14
percent below the 1980 level. The decrease could be explained to some
degree by the general disorganization of the economy, but more specific
problems were caused by increased guerrilla violence interrupting
supplies and deliveries, and by prolonged strikes.
Extraction, refining, and domestic marketing of oil were under
control of the Petroleum Enterprise of Peru (Petroleras de Per�--Petroper�)
from 1968 to 1991. Foreign firms have been allowed to participate in
exploration for new fields, although negotiations over their rights
often has proved to be difficult. One foreign firm, Belco Petroleum
Corporation, maintained offshore production until 1985, when its
operations were nationalized after a dispute over taxes with the Garc�a
government.
Output of oil products increased greatly in the course of the 1970s:
its value at constant prices was 2.7 times as high in 1980 as in 1970.
But then oil production joined the collective downtrend: it fell sharply
between 1980 and 1985. Again, both the general disorganization of the
economy and the increase in rural violence contributed to the decrease.
Additionally controls on prices of oil products held them far below
costs of production in the second half of the 1980s. That fact put
Petroper� deeply into deficit and constrained its ability to finance
both production and exploration. In 1990 petroleum contributed US$263
million to the value of the country's exports. The major changes
introduced by the Fujimori government in 1990-91 included invitations
for new investment by foreign oil companies, ending the monopoly
position of Petroper�. Several foreign oil companies immediately
entered negotiations to begin exploration activities, either
independently or in collaboration with Petroper�.
Peru
Peru - Services
Peru
The formally legalized side of the service sector includes both
government and private services. Government services, measured by
payments for inputs in the absence of any recognized standard of output,
have grown remarkably fast. As evaluated in current prices, government
services increased from 4 percent of GDP in the decade of the 1950s to 9
percent in 1990.
Among the private service-sector activities, retail and wholesale
trade has been the most important, accounting for 13.7 percent of GDP in
1988. Financial and business services were next most important at 8.5
percent of GDP, followed by transport and communications at 7.4 percent.
Electricity and water constituted a small share of output in 1988, at
1.3 percent of GDP, but they increased at a very high rate from 1970 to
1988: their output in 1988 was 3.4 times as high as in 1970. Although
these formal service-sector activities have, for the most part, shown
significant growth even during the difficult 1980s, national accounts
indicated that the largest of them--retail and wholesale trade--did not
grow at all between 1980 and 1988. But that official measure was not
readily credible, given the country's population growth and especially
the rapid growth of the urban population. The official measure
apparently reflected the fact that a growing share of trade was being
carried out by unregistered individuals and firms.
Official statistics on production and employment are always subject
to many reservations in Peru, as in all developing countries, but
especially so for the service sector. Much of what is going on among
these activities is outside the formal framework of the economy and very
difficult to measure. In 1990- 91 many service activities were legally
registered, reported sales and profits for tax purposes, and were in all
respects within the formal accounting system of the economy. But many
others were unregistered and might not even be known to exist as far as
the government's statistics were concerned. That is true in any country
for some activities, particularly those that operate against the law. It
is also true on a massive scale in Peru for people who are just
repairing shoes, making small items in their homes to sell in the
streets, or in general trying to survive by activities that are
perfectly normal and productive but not registered with the government.
Peru has a massive informal
sector, which includes more than half the total urban
labor force. This sector accounts for a high proportion of personal
services and retail sales activities, as well as considerable industrial
production.
Exactly when and why these informal sector activities moved from a
marginal to a large share of the economy are open questions. One
strongly argued view, associated particularly with the work of Hernando
de Soto, author of El otro sendero (The Other Path),
is that regulatory activities of government proliferated from the 1960s
onward, imposing intolerable costs on private business activities. A
slightly different but consistent view is that the rapid growth of the
informal sector coincided with increased business taxation, beginning at
the end of the 1960s. The two interpretations fit each other, but the
former lends itself more to a general argument against government
regulation of business, without paying much attention to the fact that
the growth of the informal sector means a shrinking tax base for the
society.
Both of these analyses surely capture much of the causation behind
the growth of the informal sector in Peru, but they may deflect
attention from two other explanations that could be more important. One
of them concerns the generalized deterioration of the economy and the
consequent weak growth of job opportunities in formal-sector employment.
With the rapid growth of the labor force, and a high rate of migration
to the cities, the number of people looking for work far outpaced the
number of formal job openings. The answer for those without regular
employment in the formal sector has been to create self-employment
activities of their own or to work for relatives in small-scale
operations, often on a basis of family sharing rather than regular wage
employment. These people do everything from selling coat hangers on
sidewalks in the center of the city to putting together computers from
discarded spare parts. In this view, the problem is not so much
government regulation or excess taxation as it is one of macroeconomic
failure of the economy as a whole. The informal sector may be in part a
way to avoid regulation, but more fundamentally it is a necessary means
of survival, a constructive answer on the individual level to lack of
success at the level of the macroeconomy.
Still another interpretation that must be considered centers on the
background of the migrants to the cities. They have been native
Americans and mestizos from rural communities in which ways of earning a living
are bound within traditional family and community relationships.
Production is carried out on a self-employed or very small-scale basis
with a minimum of the kinds of accounting, financial, and legal
complications of modern society. The new migrants to the cities look for
work and guidance from former migrants and especially relatives from the
same communities who are carrying on much the same kinds of activities
as they knew at home. They recreate in Lima the kinds of informal
activities they have always known. In this view, the informal sector is
largely a cultural phenomenon, by no means explicable in purely economic
terms.
Succeeding governments have gone back and forth in their treatment of
the informal sector, at times trying to crack down on unregistered
vendors and their sources of supply, and at other times trying to
provide them with information and technical help. The formal business
sector might be expected to press for regulation of these activities
because the legally registered firms must pay the higher costs of
following regulations and paying taxes: competition is not even. But
then the formal sector is itself divided. Because some of these firms
cut their own costs by subcontracting activities to the informal sector,
to some degree they share in the same profit from being outside the law.
Everyone recognizes that the informal sector is the source of livelihood
for a great many people without alternative opportunities and that
helping to make them more productive could yield important gains for
them and for Peru. The other side of the coin is that those in this
sector pay no attention to the legal system, to health and safety
regulations, or to the society's need for a tax base to support
necessary public functions.
Peru
Peru - Banking
Peru
In 1987 the Garc�a government attempted to nationalize Peru's banks,
financial institutions, and insurance companies. Under the legislation,
which Congress approved despite a judicial ruling against the
government's proposals, the government was to hold 70 percent of shares
of nationalized banks, with the remaining 30 percent offered for sale to
the public. The legislation excluded foreign banks operating in Peru
from the nationalization program but prohibited them from opening any
new branches in Peru. This set of proposals stimulated widespread public
opposition and provoked a breakdown of cooperation between business
leaders and the government. Private investment fell abruptly. Garc�a
attempted to pursue the nationalization despite all the opposition, but
adverse judicial rulings slowed implementation and finally killed the
proposals.
In early 1991, Peru's financial system included four development
banks, twenty-two commercial banks, eight credit firms (financieras
de cr�dito), fifteen savings-and-loan mutuals (mutuales),
twelve municipal savings-and-loans institutions, and the Savings Bank of
Lima (Caja de Ahorros de Lima). In May 1991, the Fujimori government
introduced a new package of economic measures designed to liberalize the
banking system. The government suspended the powers of the Central
Reserve Bank (Banco Central de Reservas, or BCR--hereafter Central Bank)
to set interest rates and allowed them to float according to market
forces. It also stipulated that in the future foreign banks would be
able to operate in Peru under the same conditions as Peruvian banks. In
addition, it amended the Agrarian Reform Law of 1969 by allowing farmers
to put up their land as collateral for bank loans. When it went into
effect in June 1991, the new banking law shook up the state banking
sector, which employed 20,000 people and included six state-owned banks.
The new law eliminated specialized banks, credit firms, and
mortgage-lending mutuals, forcing them to reorganize as commercial
banks.
Peru
Peru - Tourism
Peru
Lima, with its Spanish colonial architecture, and Cusco, with its
impressive stonework of pre-Inca and Inca civilizations, notably at
Machupicchu, are the centers of Peru's ailing tourism industry. Lake
Titicaca also constitutes a major tourist attraction. However, as a
result of terrorism, insurgency, common crime, the 1990-91 cholera
epidemic, and the April 1992 coup, tourism has declined drastically
since 1988, when Peru received an estimated 320,000 foreign visitors and
US$300 million in tourism earnings. One American tourist was murdered in
Cusco in early 1990, and several others died in the late 1980s because
of sabotage of a train line between Cusco and Machupicchu. Under sharply
increased taxes on tourism imposed in 1989 in response to declining
numbers of tourists, foreigners have had to pay far more than Peruvians
for internal flights and visits to museums and archaeological sites. In
1989 six flights a day shuttled tourists between Cusco and Lima, but by
late 1990 there were only two. Tourist arrivals in Peru continued to
decline in 1990 and 1991.
According to the National Tourism Board (C�mara Nacional de
Turismo--Canatur), tourism in the first half of 1992 was down 30 percent
from the first semester of 1991, which, in turn, fell 70 percent from
1988, tourism's record year. A major blow to Lima's hotel business was
the SL's car bomb attack in the exclusive Miraflores district on July
16, 1992, in which six major hotels suffered over US$1 million in
damages. The number of tourists visiting Cusco and Machupicchu had
dropped 76 percent since 1988.
<"http://accommodations-travelnow.com/latin-america/peru/">Peru
Accommodations
Peru
Peru - Employment
Peru
The Peruvian labor force increased from 3.1 million workers in 1960
to 5.6 million by 1980, and to 7.6 million by 1990. As it did so, the
share of the labor force in agriculture steadily decreased, but the
shares in manufacturing and mining failed to rise. On balance, the decreases in the agricultural share had to be
offset by increases in the share in service activities, some of them
offering productive employment at abovepoverty income levels but many of
them not.
Peru's long process of transition away from a rural society was far
from complete at the beginning of the post-World War II period.
Fifty-nine percent of the labor force was still working in agriculture
in 1950. That share fell to barely over half by 1960 and to 34 percent
by 1990. The more surprising trend is that the share of the labor force
in manufacturing also fell, from 13 percent in 1950 to 10 percent by
1990. Stable shares in both construction and mining meant that the shift
out of agriculture went mainly toward services, pulling their share of
employment up from 23 percent in 1950 to 50 percent by 1990.
The persistent decrease in the share of the labor force in
agriculture could in theory have helped to alleviate rural poverty by
leaving higher average land holdings to those remaining in agriculture.
But the absolute number of people trying to make a living from
inadequate land holdings actually increased. The labor force in
agriculture rose 52 percent between 1960 and 1990. In addition,
emigration from agriculture exerted increasing pressure on labor markets
in the cities, and the increase in rural workers kept earnings low in
that sector.
A growing labor force need not drive wages down and in most instances
does not, provided that investment and technical change keep opening up
new opportunities for productive employment fast enough to absorb the
larger number of workers. Peru managed to accomplish such growth in the
first post-World War II decades, but from the early 1970s the trend went
downward. As more and more workers tried to survive in the service
sector by selfemployment or work with families instead of formally
registered firms, they created a rapidly growing informal sector.
Workers in the informal sector are mostly employed, and they certainly
add to national income, but their earnings are often below the poverty
line.
Overt unemployment that can actually be counted has been only a small
part of the problem. The overt unemployment level in Lima was an
estimated 7 percent in 1980, rising to 8 percent by 1990. But estimates
of underemployment in part-time or very low-income activities indicate
that 26 percent of Lima's labor force was in this category in 1980, and
fully 86 percent in 1990. Such measures are invariably somewhat
arbitrary, depending on how underemployment is defined and measured.
However, the fact that the share of Lima's labor force fitting the
definition more than tripled between 1980 and 1990 is readily
understandable in the light of the deterioration of the economy in the
1980s.
Peru
Peru - Wages
Peru
Real wages in Peru rose when the economy was advancing in the 1950s
and 1960s but then began to go down persistently. From 1956 to 1972,
average wages in manufacturing increased at an annual rate of 4.1
percent. But then from 1972 to 1980, they went back down at the rate of
3.6 percent a year, and from 1980 to 1989 they went further down at the
rate of 5.2 percent a year. Although comparisons of real wage levels
over long periods are inherently uncertain, given many changes in the
structures of wages and prices, it seems evident that real wages in
Peruvian manufacturing were much lower in 1989 than they had been a
third of a century earlier.
Even in comparison with the sharp fall in manufacturing real wages
during the 1980s, the concurrent plunge in real minimum wages for urban
workers was appalling. While the average for manufacturing fell 58
percent from 1980 to 1989, the real minimum wage fell 77 percent; the
purchasing power of the minimum wage in 1989 was less than one-fourth
its level in 1980.
The minimum wage applies to legally employed workers in the formal
sector. The much larger number of workers in the informal sector, not
covered by the minimum wage, also lost purchasing power in the course of
the 1980s but apparently not as drastically. An index of real earnings
in the informal sector shows a decrease of 28 percent between December
1980 and December 1989. That index also shows extreme volatility. Real
earnings rose steeply between December 1980 and December 1987, almost
doubling in this period, and then plunged to a level far below the
starting point.
Peru
Peru - Organized Labor
Peru
In labor markets as weak as those of Peru from the early 1970s
onward, organized labor has not normally had any great bargaining power.
It could affect the political balance, but it has not been able to do
much to keep real earnings from falling when the economy declined.
Peruvian labor has never been more than moderately organized in any
case: unionization did not take off significantly until the political
climate changed with the reformist military government of 1968. Labor
has played a more active political role since that time, but has not so
far been able to prevent deterioration of real wages.
Organized labor in Peru got off to a slow start in the interwar
period (1919-40), compared with active unionism in Argentina, Chile, and
Venezuela. Still, the textile workers, in the one sizeable industry of
the time, managed to defy the government and win a famous strike in
1919. They gave the credit to a student activist who stepped in to lead
them and negotiated an impressive victory. The activist, V�ctor Ra�l
Haya de la Torre, went on at the beginning of the 1930s to found the
American Popular Revolutionary Alliance (Alianza Popular Revolucionaria
Americana- -APRA), the country's first mass-based political party. Haya
de la Torre simultaneously promoted organization of labor through the
Confederation of Peruvian Workers (Confederaci�n de Trabajadores del
Per�--CTP) and consolidated a close partnership between APRA and the
CTP. The CTP was the dominant voice of labor until Haya de la Torre
allied himself with the conservative side of the political spectrum
during the 1960s. That move to the right then stimulated the growth of a
rival Communist-led labor federation, the General Confederation of
Peruvian Workers (Confederaci�n General de Trabajadores del Per�--CGTP).
Neither APRA nor the labor movement made much headway under the
conservative governments in office up to the 1960s. But after the
reformist military government took power in 1968, unionization spread
rapidly. More new unions were given legal recognition from 1968 to 1978
than in all prior Peruvian history: there were 2,152 recognized unions
in 1968 and 4,500 by 1978. The new unions, less tied to APRA, began to
strike out more on their own to undertake joint negotiations and
demonstrations with community groups of all kinds. The military
government began to regard unions less as allies and more as sources of
opposition, and in fact labor became a center of resistance to military
authority all through the 1970s.
Although the Velasco government was committed in many respects to
support of popular organizations, its relationships with organized labor
turned into conflicts in two fundamental ways. One was purely economic;
the government was initially determined to prove its ability to avoid
inflation, which it identified as evidence of the inherent weakness of
civilian governments. Increase in wages was seen as a threat to control
of inflation, and wages in general were considered a matter to be
decided by government rather than unions.
The second and more general source of conflict was that the Velasco
government had a strongly corporatist conception of social order, in which labor unions had
their place but had no business trying to change it. The government was
deeply opposed to theories of class conflict. Labor and capital alike
were expected to recognize that their interests had to be reconciled for
the good of the society as a whole. The military welcomed and sponsored
public organizations but distrusted any signs of excessive autonomy.
Once in open conflict with the two main labor confederations, the
government tried to undercut them by creating a new one, the Federation
of Workers of the Peruvian Revolution (Central de Trabajadores de la
Revoluci�n Peruana--CTRP). The new confederation received government
help in getting favorable wage settlements and added to the scope of
labor organization but had little effect in actually weakening the more
independent unions.
In the economic contraction following 1975, labor played a more
active role of social protest than ever before. The first general strike
in the country's history, in July 1977, seemed to herald a new epoch in
labor relations in Peru. Labor's support for left-oriented parties, no
longer so predominantly for APRA, became evident in the elections of
1980. In terms of wage trends, the more active role of organized labor
has not seemed to make much difference. Organized labor certainly did
not stop the devastating fall of real wages in the 1980s. Still, average
wages for workers under collective bargaining contracts have been much
higher than those for workers without them. As of December 1986, the
average wage for those with contracts was 2.2 times that of workers
without them. That ratio fell to 1.7 by December 1989, as everyone's
real wages plunged.
Peru
Peru - Poverty
Peru
Whether poverty is measured in terms of family income or in terms of
social indicators, such as child mortality, it has been greater in Peru
than would be expected on the basis of the country's average income per
capita. Historically, this situation has been an expression of the
country's exceptionally high degree of inequality. More recently,
especially in the course of the 1980s, it increased even more than in
the other major Latin American countries, chiefly because of the drastic
deterioration of the economy's overall performance.
Measures of poverty based on family income are, of course, dependent
on the particular income level chosen as a dividing line between the
poor and the non-poor. Both the Economic Commission for Latin America
and the Caribbean (ECLAC) and the World Bank draw two lines--one for a tightly
restricted income level to define extreme poverty, or destitution, and a
second cutoff for poverty in a less extreme sense. Destitution refers to
income so low that it could not provide adequate nutrition even if it
were spent entirely on food. Poverty in the less extreme sense takes as
given the proportion of income spent on food in each society and
compares that proportion to the level needed for adequate nutrition.
A comprehensive analysis of poverty in Latin America for 1970
concluded that fully 50 percent of Peruvian families were below the
poverty line and 25 percent were below the destitution level. These
proportions were both higher than Latin America's corresponding
averages--40 percent in poverty and 19 percent in destitution. In Peru,
as in the rest of Latin America, the incidence of poverty and
destitution was much higher for rural than for urban families. Fully 68
percent of rural families were below the poverty line, compared with 28
percent of urban families.
A more recent ECLAC study provides new estimates of the incidence of
poverty for 1980 and 1986. For Latin America, the share of families in
poverty fell from 40 percent in 1970 to 35 percent in 1980 but then rose
to 37 percent in the more difficult conditions of 1986. For Peru, the
incidence of poverty also fell from 50 percent in 1970 to 46 percent in
1980, but then it increased to 52 percent by 1986, rising faster than
the rest of the region.
As in 1970, the incidence of poverty and destitution in 1986 remained
higher for rural than for urban families, but the differences had
lessened. In 1970 the incidence of poverty for rural families was 2.4
times that for urban families; in 1986 the ratio was only 1.4 times. The
proportion of rural families in poverty actually fell, from 68 percent
to 64 percent, while that of urban families rose greatly, from 28
percent to 45 percent.
Cu�nto S.A. has developed an ongoing monthly indicator of extreme
poverty in Peru, combining measures of earnings by workers paid the
minimum wage with earnings in the informal urban sector and in
agriculture. Taking January 1985 as the starting point, this index shows
a substantial fall in extreme poverty up to December 1987, in the first
years of the Garc�a government's expansion. But then it shows a
dramatic increase as the economy went rapidly downhill. At the end of
the Garc�a administration, in June 1990, the index was 91 percent
higher than in December 1987 and 32 percent higher than its starting
point in January 1985.
Peru
Peru - Income Distribution
Peru
The distribution of income in Peru has been exceptionally unequal for
a long time, but by some measures the degree of inequality apparently
decreased between 1970 and 1985. The main causes of inequality have changed as well,
in some ways for the better and in some for the worse.
In the pre-World War II years, the dominant causes of inequality were
a very high concentration of ownership of land and access to capital and
to education, along with a sociopolitical structure that condemned the
indigenous rural population to bare subsistence with little chance of
mobility. In the post-World War II period, especially since the 1960s,
access to education gradually has spread to rural areas, and increased
migration to the cities has opened up new opportunities for people
previously blocked in poverty-stricken rural occupations. The Agrarian
Reform Law of 1969 wiped out large private land holdings and led in the
1980s to a vastly less unequal distribution of individual ownership. The rise of production and export of
coca probably also played a role in raising rural incomes in the 1980s.
More positively, if only for a brief period from 1985 to 1987, the
agrarian policies of the Garc�a government helped stimulate
agricultural markets and production, and controls on prices in the
industrial sector served to raise greatly the ratio of agricultural to
industrial prices. As has been noted, the proportion of the rural
population below the poverty line fell from 68 percent in 1970 to 64
percent by 1986, while that for urban families was rising from 28
percent to 45 percent. The positive change for rural families was small,
and the negative change for urban families was large, but because urban
poverty was initially less the degree of inequality between the rural
and urban sectors decreased.
Other changes in the post-World War II years worked in the opposite
direction, toward greater inequality. The turn to industrial protection
raised profits of industrialists relative to other forms of income and
also raised the prices of their products relative to those of the
agricultural sector. Wages for organized workers in manufacturing rose
relative to wages of lower-income rural and unorganized labor, as well.
The pressure of a rapidly growing labor force against the society's
limited openings for productive employment acted in general to keep
downward pressure on labor income relative to property income. That
imbalance worsened in the 1980s when the chaotic conditions of the
economy as a whole made employment conditions more difficult.
During the period of exceptional economic growth from 1961 to 1972,
the incomes of the poorest 60 percent of Peruvian families increased at
a rate of 2.3 percent a year, just matching the rate of growth of
national income. As growth weakened from the mid1970s , both average
real wages and minimum real wages began a prolonged decline, and total
wages fell relative to incomes of property owners. But earnings of the
lowest income groups in agriculture went up, slightly reducing the
percentage of rural families falling below the poverty line. A World
Bank study concludes that these changes reduced the degree of inequality
between 1972 and 1985: the share of the poorest 60 percent increased
from 18 to 27 percent of total income.
An alternative measure of inequality, the Gini index, shows a similar
improvement. The higher the coefficient, the higher the degree of
inequality. In the early 1960s and again in the early 1970s, Peru had
either the highest or the second highest Gini coefficient for all the
Latin American countries measured, at 0.61 for 1961 and 0.59 for 1972.
By 1985 it had come down to 0.47, far below Brazil and only slightly
higher than Colombia. These countries all have high inequality by world
standards, but in 1985 Peru no longer stood out as the worst.
The latest estimate available, for 1988, suggests that inequality had
increased slightly compared with 1985, with the Gini coefficient rising
from 0.47 to 0.50. Although not a drastic change in itself, its
connotations are worsened by the simultaneous rise in poverty. The
latter may well be considered to be the more important matter: it would
not mean much to reduce inequality if that just meant more equal sharing
of greater poverty. The one clearly positive combination of indicators
is that for the period 1980-85 the incidence of poverty fell, if only
slightly, for the rural households who have always constituted the
majority of Peru's poor.
Peru
Peru - The Velasco Government
Peru
The economic strategy of the Velasco government was shaped by a
conception frequently advocated in Latin America but rarely put into
practice. The idea was to find a "third way" between
capitalism and socialism, with a corporatist society much more
inclusionary than that possible under capitalism but without rejecting
private ownership or adopting any of the compulsory methods identified
with communism. Under this strategy, land reform was designed to
override existing property interests in order to establish cooperative
ownership, rejecting both individual private farming and state farms.
Promoting worker participation in ownership and management was intended
to reshape labor relations. Foreign influences were reduced through
tight restrictions on foreign investment and nationalization of some of
the largest foreign firms. On a more fundamental plane, the Velasco
government saw its mission as one of eliminating class conflict and
reconciling differences among interest groups within its own vision of a
cooperative society.
Land Reform
The most striking and thorough reform imposed by the Velasco
government was to eliminate all large private landholdings, converting
most of them into cooperatives owned by prior workers on the estates.
The reform was intended to destroy the basis of power of Peru's
traditional elite and to foster a more cooperative society as an
alternative to capitalism. Such socialpolitical purposes apparently
dominated questions of agricultural production or any planned changes in
patterns of land use. It was as if the questions of ownership were what
mattered, not the consequences for output or rural incomes. In fact, the
government soon created a system of price controls and monopoly food
buying by state firms designed to hold down prices to urban consumers,
no matter what the cost to rural producers.
As mentioned earlier, the cooperatives had very mixed success; and
the majority were converted into individual private holdings during the
1980s. The conversions were authorized in 1980 by changes in the basic
land reform legislation and were put into effect after majority votes of
the cooperative members in each case. The preferences of the people
involved at that point clearly went contrary to the intent of the
original reform. But the whole set of changes was not a reversion to the
pre-reform agrarian structure. In fact, the conversions left Peru with a
far less unequal pattern of landownership than it had prior to the
reform and with a much greater role for family farming than ever before
in its history.
Labor and Capital in the Industrial Sector
In line with its basic conception of social order, the military
government also created a complex system of "industrial
communities." Under this system, firms in the modern sector were
required to distribute part of their profits to workers in the form of
dividends constituting ownership shares. The intent was to convert
workers into property owners and property ownership into a form of
sharing for the sake of class reconciliation. But in practice, the
system never functioned well. The firms did all they could to avoid
reporting profits in order to postpone sharing ownership, sometimes by
setting up companies outside the system to which they channeled profits,
sometimes by adjusting the books, and in general by keeping one step
ahead of intended regulations. A small fraction of the industrial
workers gained shares in firms, but as a rule workers were not so much
interested in long-term claims of ownership as they were in immediate
working conditions and earnings. For organized labor, the whole approach
seemed an attempt to subvert any role for union action and to make
organization irrelevant. The system was not popular with either side. It
was quickly abandoned when the more conservative wing of the military
took power away from General Velasco in 1975.
Attempted reform of labor relations in the mid-1970s also included
severe restrictions on rights to discharge workers once they passed a
brief trial period of employment. A review process set up to examine
disputes was implemented in a way that made discharges practically
impossible. Businesspeople circumvented the restrictions to some degree
by hiring workers on a temporary basis up to the point at which they
would have to be kept and then letting them go before the restrictions
applied. Businesspeople remained unremittingly hostile to this type of
regulation, primarily on the grounds that it took away their main means
of exercising discipline over their workers. This form of regulation was
also eliminated shortly after Velasco lost power.
Protection and Promotion of Industry
Along with the intention of resolving internal class conflict, the
Velasco government determined to lessen Peru's dependency on the outside
world. The two most important components of the strategy were a drive to
promote rapid industrialization and an attack on the role of foreign
firms. In contrast to the industrialization strategies of most other
Latin American countries, the intention of the Velasco regime was to
industrialize without welcoming foreign investment.
The preceding Bela�nde administration had started Peru on the path
of protection to promote industry, and in this respect the Velasco
government reinforced rather than reversed the existing strategy. Beyond
the usual recourse to high tariffs, Velasco's government adopted the
Industrial Community Law of 1970 that gave any industrialist on the
register of manufacturers the right to demand prohibition of any imports
competing with his products. No questions of exceptionally high costs of
production, poor product quality, or monopolistic positions fostered by
excluding import competition were allowed to get in the way. Before the
succeeding government of General Francisco Morales Berm�dez Cerrutti
(1975- 80) began to clean up the battery of protective exclusions in
1978, the average tariff rate reached 66 percent, accompanied by
quantitative restrictions on 2,890 specific tariff positions.
In addition to the protective measures, the Velasco government
promoted industrial investment by granting major tax exemptions, as well
as tariff exemptions on imports used by manufacturers in production. The
fiscal benefits given industrialists through these measures equaled 92
percent of total internal financing of industrial investment in the
years 1971 through 1975.
Investment rose strongly in response to these measures, as well as to
the concurrent rise in aggregate demand. But the tax exemptions also
contributed to a rising public-sector deficit and thereby to the
beginning of serious inflationary pressure. In addition, the exemptions
from tariffs given to industrialists on their own imports of equipment
and supplies led to a strong rise in the ratio of imports to production
for the industrial sector.
Nationalizations and State Firms
The industrialization drive was meant to be primarily a Peruvian
process not totally excluding foreign investors but definitely not
welcoming them warmly. In that spirit, the Velasco regime immediately
nationalized IPC in October 1968 and, not long after that, the largest
copper mining company, while taking over other foreign firms more
peacefully through buy-outs. The government put into place new
restrictions on foreign investment in Peru and led the way to a regional
agreement, the Andean
Pact, that featured some of the most extensive
controls on foreign investment yet attempted in the developing world.
The decision to nationalize the foreign oil firm was immensely
popular in Peru. It was seen as a legitimate response to many years of
close collaboration between the company, which performed political
favors, and a series of possibly selfinterested Peruvian presidents,
who, in exchange, preserved the company's exclusive drilling rights.
Nationalization was perhaps less a matter of an economic program than a
reaction to a public grievance, a reaction bound to increase public
support for the new government.
Subsequent nationalizations and purchases of foreign firms were more
explicitly manifestations of the goals of building up state ownership
and reducing foreign influence in Peru. The leaders of the military
government subscribed firmly to the ideas of dependency
analysis, placing much of the blame for problems of
development on external influences through trade and foreign investment.
Foreign ownership of natural resources in particular was seen as a way
of taking away the country's basic wealth on terms that allowed most of
the gains to go abroad. Ownership of the resources was expected to bring
in revenue to the government, and to the country, that would otherwise
have been lost.
In contrast to its abrupt nationalization of the IPC and then of the
largest copper mining company, the government turned mainly to purchases
through negotiation to acquire the property of the International
Telephone and Telegraph Company (ITT) and foreign banks. Partly in
response to United States reactions to the earlier nationalizations, and
perhaps also partly in response to the realization that foreign
investment might play a positive role in the industrialization drive,
the government began to take a milder position toward foreign firms. But
at the same time, it pursued a policy of creating new state-owned firms,
in a sense competing for position against domestic private ownership, as
well as against foreign ownership.
State ownership of firms was, of course, consistent with the
nationalizations but reflected a different kind of policy objective.
Whereas the nationalizations were intended to gain greater Peruvian
control over the country's resources and to reduce the scope of foreign
influence, the proliferation of state-owned firms was meant to increase
direct control by the government over the economy. State firms were seen
as a means to implement government economic policies more directly than
possible when working through private firms, whether domestic or
foreign-owned. The goal was not to eliminate the private sector-- it was
encouraged at the same time by tax favors and protection-- but to create
a strong public sector to lead the way toward the kind of economy
favored by the state.
The new state firms created in this period established a significant
share of public ownership in the modern sector of the economy. By 1975
they accounted for over half of mining output and a fifth of industrial
output. One set of estimates indicates that enterprises under state
ownership came to account for a higher share of value added than
domestic private capital: 26 percent of GDP for the state firms,
compared with 22 percent for domestic private firms. The share produced
by foreign-owned firms dropped to 8 percent from 21 percent prior to the
Velasco government's reforms.
Contrary to the expectation that the earnings of the state firms
would provide an important source of public financing for development,
these companies became almost immediately a collective drain. In some
measure, the drain was a result of decisions by the government to hold
down their prices in order to lessen inflation or to subsidize
consumers. In addition, deficits of the state-owned firms were
aggravated by the spending tendencies of the military officers placed in
charge of company management and by inadequate attention to costs of
production. The collective deficits of the state enterprises plus the
subsidies paid directly to them by the government reached 3 percent of
GDP by 1975. State enterprises were not able to finance more than about
one-fourth of their investment spending. The government attempted to
answer the investment requirements of the state firms by allowing them
to borrow abroad for imported equipment and supplies. They did so on a
large scale. The external debt rose swiftly, for this and for other
reasons discussed below.
Nationalizations and the creation of new state firms stopped abruptly
after Velasco lost power. In 1980 the Bela�nde government announced a
program to privatize most of the state firms, but it proved difficult to
find private buyers, and few of the firms were actually sold. In the
opposite direction, the subsequent Garc�a government, in addition to
nationalizing in 1985 the offshore oil production of the Belco
Corporation, a United States company, tried in 1987 to extend state
ownership over banks remaining in private hands. The attempted banking
nationalization created a storm of protest and was eventually ruled to
be illegal. The failures under both Bela�nde and Garc�a to change the
balance left the state-enterprise sector basically intact until Fujimori
implemented major changes.
Macroeconomic Imbalance: Domestic and External
Whatever the promises and the costs of the many kinds of reform
attempted by the Velasco government, the ship sank because of inadequate
attention to balances between spending and productive capacity, and
between export incentives and import demand. The Velasco government
inherited recessionary conditions in 1968, with a positive external
balance and productive capacity readily available for expansion. It
maintained effective restraint on spending and deficits for several
years but then let things get out of control. The central government's
deficit was no more than 1 percent of gross national product (GNP) in
1970, but its own deficit plus that of the greatly expanded group of
state firms reached 10 percent of GNP by 1975. Correspondingly, the
external current-account balance was positive in the period 1968-70 but
showed a deficit equal to 10 percent of GNP by 1975.
The external deficit was driven up primarily by high rates of growth
of domestic demand and production through 1974. But in addition, the
government's policy of holding to a fixed nominal exchange rate, in an
increasingly inflationary context, allowed the real exchange rate to
fall steadily from 1969 to 1975. The government refused to consider
devaluation for fear it would worsen inflation and managed to avoid it
by borrowing abroad to finance the continuing deficit. By 1975 external
creditors had lost confidence in Peru's ability to repay its debts and
began to put on the brakes. Whether because of such external pressure or
because of growing internal opposition to the increasingly arbitrary
decisions of the government, the Peruvian military decided to replace
Velasco in 1975. The experiment ended on a note of defeat, not so much
of its objectives as of its methods.
Peru
Peru - The Second Bela�nde Government
Peru
The return to democracy allowed Peruvians to choose among strongly
left, strongly conservative, or middle-of-the-road parties. They chose
Bela�nde and his party as the middle road, but it led nowhere. The Bela�nde
government tried to return the economy to a more open system by reducing
barriers to imports, implementing financial reforms intended to foster
private markets, and reversing the statist orientation of the Velasco
system. But the new approach never had a chance to get very far because
of a series of macroeconomic problems. On one side, the government was
rightly concerned about continuing inflation but made the mistake of
focusing the explanation on monetary growth arising from the export
surplus it inherited at the start. That position made it seem
undesirable to continue trying to promote exports and desirable to raise
domestic spending and imports. On the other side, President Bela�nde's
personal and political objectives included using public investment
actively to develop the interior of the country and to answer evident
needs for improved infrastructure. Seeing the export surplus as the key
macroeconomic source of imbalance, the government decided to eliminate
it by removing import restrictions, slowing nominal devaluation to allow
the real exchange rate to appreciate, and increasing government
investment spending.
The real exchange rate appreciated through 1981 and 1982, public
sector investment rose 54 percent in real terms from 1979 to 1982, and
public sector consumption rose 25 percent during the same three-year
period. The combination effectively turned the current-account surplus
into a large deficit, as increased spending plus import liberalization
practically doubled imports of goods and services between 1979 and 1981.
The appreciation also turned manufacturing exports back downward, and a
plunge in external prices of primary exports brought them down too. And
then the mistake of focusing on the earlier export surplus as the main
cause of inflation became clear: the increases in spending led to a leap
of inflation despite the return to an external deficit. The rate of
inflation went from 59 percent in 1980 to 111 percent by 1983.
Nothing improved when the government then tried to go into reverse
with contractionary macroeconomic policies and renewed depreciation.
Output plunged, but inflation once more went up instead of down, to 163
percent by 1985. By this time, pessimism about the government's capacity
to solve anything, inflationary expectations turning into understandable
convictions, and the price-increasing effect of devaluation all combined
to give Peru a seemingly unstoppable inflation despite the elimination
of anything that might be considered excess demand. The government
apparently lost its sense of direction, retreated from its attempt to
reopen the economy by returning to higher tariff levels, and otherwise
did little except wait for its own end in 1985.
Peru
Peru - The Garc�a Government
Peru
With the market-oriented choice of economic strategy discredited by
results under Bela�nde, Peruvians voted for the dynamic
populist-reformist promise of Garc�a and responded enthusiastically to
his sweeping changes. Garc�a's program worked wonders for two years,
but then everything began to go wrong.
The main elements of the economic strategy proposed by the Garc�a
government were full of promise. They recognized the prior neglect of
the agricultural sector and called for redirecting public programs
toward promotion of agricultural growth and reduction of rural poverty.
Correspondingly, economic activity was to be decentralized to break down
its high concentration in Lima, and within the cities resources were to
be redirected away from the capital-intensive and import-intensive
modern sector to the labor-intensive informal sector. A strategy of concertaci�n
(national understanding) with private business leaders on economic
issues was to be used systematically to avoid disruptive conflict.
Problems of external balance were to be answered both by restructuring
production to lessen dependence on imports and by reorienting toward
higher exports over the long-term.
These goals for structural change could have improved the efficiency
of resource allocation while doing a great deal to lessen poverty. But
the goals clearly required both time and the ability to restore
expansion without worsening inflation and external deficits. The
government initially emphasized such macroeconomic objectives as
necessary conditions for the structural changes. The first step was to
stop the built-in inflationary process, but to do it without adopting
orthodox measures of monetary and fiscal restraint.
To stop inflation, the government opted for heterodox policies of
control within an expansionary program. Prices and wages in the modern
sector were to be fixed, after an initial one-shot increase in wage
rates. The increase in wages was intended to raise living standards of
workers and stimulate production by raising sales to consumers. To
offset the effects of higher wages on costs of production, financial
costs of the business sector were cut by intervention in order to reduce
and control interest rates. After making one adjustment of the exchange
rate to minimize negative effects on exports, the government stopped the
process of continuing devaluation in order to help hold down inflation.
Imports were rightly expected to go up as the economy revived; to help
finance them, Garc�a made his controversial decision to stop paying
external debt service beyond 10 percent of the value of exports.
Unorthodox as they were, all the pieces seemed to fit. At least, they
went together well at the start under conditions of widespread idle
capacity, with an initially strong balance of payments position.
The macroeconomic measures worked wonders for production. GDP shot up
9.5 percent in 1986 and a further 7.7 percent in 1987. Manufacturing
output and construction both increased by more than one-fourth in these
two years. An even greater surprise was that agricultural production per
capita went up, running counter to its long downward trend. And the rate
of inflation came down from 163 percent in 1985 to 78 percent in 1986,
although it edged back up to 86 percent in 1987. In response to stronger
market conditions and perhaps also to growing confidence that Peru's
economic problems were at last being attacked successfully, private
fixed investment went up by 24 percent in 1986, and capital flight went
down.
The government avoided any spending spree of its own: central
government spending was actually reduced in real terms each year. But
because the government also reduced indirect taxes in order to encourage
higher private consumption and to reduce costs for private business, its
originally small deficit grew each year. The economic deficit of the
nonfinancial public sector as a whole (excluding interest payments) went
up from 2.4 percent of GDP in 1985 to 6.5 percent by 1987.
Although the government reduced its total spending, it managed to
support a new public works program to provide temporary employment and
to direct more resources to rural producers as intended in its program
for structural change. Three lines of policy helped especially to raise
rural incomes. The first was to use generous guaranteed prices for key
food products. The second was to provide greatly increased agricultural
credit, financed essentially by credit from the Central Bank. The third
was to exempt most of the non-guaranteed agricultural prices from
controls, allowing their prices to rise sharply relative to those of
industrial products from the modern sector. From July 1985 to December
1986, prices of goods and services not under control increased more than
three times as much as those under control. Wholesale prices in
manufacturing increased 26 percent, but those for agricultural products
increased 142 percent.
Besides higher employment and living standards, the first two years
of economic revival seemed to offer a break in the cycle of rising rural
violence. The flow of displaced peasants from the Sierra eased, and a
good many peasants began to return to the countryside. That reverse
might be explained by Garc�a's initial efforts to reduce reliance on
military force to combat the guerrillas and thereby to lessen the degree
of two-way violence driving people out of their villages. But the trend
may also have been a response to the reality of better economic
conditions and earning possibilities in the agricultural sector.
The first two years of the Garc�a government gave new hope to the
people of Peru, with rising employment, production, and wages suggesting
a clear turn for the better after so many years of increasing
difficulties. It was hence doubly tragic to see the whole process
unravel so quickly, once things started going wrong again. The first
sign of trouble came, as it often had, from the balance of payments. The
economic boom naturally raised imports swiftly, by 76 percent between
1985 and 1987. But the real exchange rate was allowed to fall by 10
percent in 1986 and by a further 9 percent in 1987. The boom pulled
potential export supply into the domestic market, and the fall in the
real exchange rate reduced incentives to earn foreign exchange. Exports
fell slightly in 1985 and remained below that level through 1987. The
external current account went from a surplus of US$127 million in 1985
to deficits of nearly US$1.1 billion in 1986 and nearly US$1.5 billion
in 1987.
The Garc�a government reacted to the growing external deficit in
exactly the same way as had the governments of Velasco and of Bela�nde--by
postponing corrective action while the problem continued to worsen. As
ever, a major fear was that devaluation would worsen inflation.
Inflationary pressures were, in fact, beginning to worsen behind the fa�ade
of control. To some degree, they were growing in response to the high
rate of growth of demand and output, reducing margins of previously
underutilized productive capacity. But the more explosive pressures were
being built up by relying on price controls that required a dramatic
expansion of credit to keep the system in place. Prices of public sector
services--gasoline above all, oil products in general, electricity,
telephones, and postal services--were frozen at levels that soon became
almost ridiculous in real terms. The restrictions on prices charged by
state firms drove them ever deeper into deficits that had to be financed
by borrowing. The borrowing came from wherever it could, but principally
from the Central Bank. At the same time, Central Bank credit rose
steadily to keep financing agricultural expansion. Still another
direction of Central Bank credit creation was the financing used to
handle the government's new structure of multiple exchange rates.
Differential rates were used to hold down the cost of foreign exchange
for most imports, again with the dominant goal of holding down
inflation, while higher prices of foreign exchange were paid to
exporters to protect their incentives to export. The Central Bank thus
paid more for the foreign exchange it bought than it received for the
exchange it sold.
The term used for these leakages--for extensions of Central Bank
credit that did not count in the government's budget deficit--is the
"quasi-fiscal deficit." Its total increased from about 2
percent of GDP in 1985 to about 4 percent in 1987. Meanwhile, the
government's tax revenue fell steadily in real terms, partly because of
tax reductions implemented to hold down business costs and partly
because of the effect of inflation in cutting down the real value of tax
payments. Added together, the fiscal deficit plus the quasi-fiscal
deficit increased from 5 percent of GDP in 1985 to 11 percent by 1987.
The two horsemen of this particular apocalypse--the external deficit
and the swift rise of Central Bank credit--would have made 1988 a bad
year no matter what else happened. But President Garc�a guaranteed
financial disaster by his totally unexpected decision in July 1987 to
nationalize the banks not already under government ownership. No one has
yet been able to explain why he decided to do so. It would not seem to
have been a move necessary for any component of his program, or needed
for government control in a banking sector in which it already had a
dominant position. In any case, the action underlined the unilateral
character of economic policy action under Peru's presidential system and
wrecked any possibilities of further cooperation with private sector
leadership. Private investment began to fall, and the whole economy
followed it down shortly thereafter.
The Garc�a government tried a series of major and minor new policy
packages from early 1988 into 1990 to no avail. The new policies never
succeeded in shutting off the rapid infusion of Central Bank credit that
was feeding inflation, even when they did succeed in driving production
down significantly in 1989. Manufacturing production fell 18 percent in
that year, agricultural output 3 percent, and total GDP 11 percent.
Simultaneously, inflation increased from a record 666 percent in 1988 to
a new record of 3,399 percent for 1989. The one positive change was the
external current-account deficit: the fall in domestic production and
income was so steep that the current account went from a deep deficit to
a substantial surplus. The internal cost was perhaps clearest in terms
of real wages: the minimum wage in real terms for urban labor fell 61
percent between 1987 and 1989, and average real wages in manufacturing
fell 59 percent.
Peru
Peru - The Fujimori Government
Peru
The Fujimori administration began with yet another reversal of
practically all the economic policies of the preceding government, in
conditions that clearly required drastic corrective action. Its main
immediate target was to stop the runaway course of inflation. Beyond
that, the goals included repudiating protection and import substitution,
returning to full participation in the world trading and financial
systems, eliminating domestic price controls and subsidies, raising
public revenue and holding government spending strictly to the levels of
current revenue, initiating a social emergency program to reduce the
shock of adjustment for the poor, and devoting a higher share of the
country's resources to rural investment and correction of the causes of
rural poverty. In practice, new measures came out in bits and pieces,
dominated by immediate concern to stop inflation; actions taken in the
first year did not complete the program.
Preoccupation with inflation was natural enough, after the steep rise
of 1989 and the months immediately preceding the change of government.
The monthly rate of inflation ranged between 25 percent and 32 percent
in the second half of 1989, exceeded 40 percent in June 1990, and
amounted to 78 percent by July. The deficit of the central government
increased from 4 percent of GDP in January 1990 to 9 percent by May. The
money supply of the country increased six times over from January to the
end of July. The new government had to act quickly, and did.
The most dramatic immediate action was to eliminate price controls
for private-sector products and to raise prices of public-sector
products to restore financial balance for public firms. The price of
gasoline, previously driven down to the equivalent of twelve United
States cents a gallon, was multiplied by thirty times. For the consumer
price index (CPI), the shocks caused an increase of 136 percent in one day.
Eliminating price controls in the private sector and raising prices
charged by state firms had three objectives. First, the price increases
for the public-sector firms and government services were meant to
restore revenue to a level that would allow the government to stop
borrowing from the Central Bank. Second, the rise in prices was intended
to reduce aggregate demand by cutting the liquidity of business and the
purchasing power of the public. Third, with everything priced far higher
relative to public purchasing power, it was expected that market forces
would begin to operate to drive some prices back down, reversing the
long trend of increases in order to help break the grip of inflationary
expectations.
To back up the impact of the price shocks, the government declared
that it would keep its own expenditure within the limit of current
revenue and stop the other two large streams of Central Bank credit
creation: Central Bank financing for agricultural credit and for the
system of subsidies supporting differential exchange rates. The multiple
exchange rates in effect under Garc�a were to be unified, and the
unified rate was to be determined by market forces. Further, competition
from imports to restrain inflation and access to imported supplies for
production would both be improved by taking away quantitative
restrictions and reducing tariff rates.
The new policies helped greatly to bring down the rate of inflation,
although they fell short of accomplishing full stabilization. Against an
inflation rate that had reached approximately 2,300 percent for the
twelve months to June 1990, the rate of 139 percent for the twelve
months to December 1991 can be seen as a dramatic improvement. But the
latter was still more than double the government's intended ceiling for
1991 and still extremely high relative to outside world rates of
inflation. The last quarter of 1991 looked more promising, with the
monthly rate down to 4 percent, but it had risen to 7 percent by March
1992. Inflationary dangers clearly remained troublesome, especially in
view of two factors that should have stopped inflation more decisively:
a deeply depressed level of domestic demand and an unintended increase
in the real exchange rate, making dollars cheaper.
Domestic demand has been held down by the combination of the price
shock at the start of the stabilization program, steeply falling real
wages, reduced government deficits, and much tighter restraint of
credit. All these were deliberate measures to stop inflation, accepting
the likely costs of higher unemployment and restraint of production as
necessary to that end. In 1990 GNP fell 3.9 percent, aggravating the
plunge of 19 percent between 1988 and 1990. In 1991 production turned up
slightly, with a gain of 2.9 percent in GNP. That situation left output
per capita essentially unchanged from 1990 and at 29 percent below its
level a decade earlier.
The incomplete success in stopping inflation created an extremely
difficult policy conflict. Recovery could in principle be stimulated by
more expansionary credit policies and lower interest rates, which would
favor increased investment, depreciation of the currency to help
producers compete against imports, and improved exports. But continuing
inflation and the fear of accelerating its rate of increase argued
instead for keeping a very tight rein on credit and thereby blocked the
actions needed for recovery. This conflict became particularly acute
over the question of what to do about the exchange note: the real
exchange rate went in exactly the wrong direction for recovery by
appreciating when depreciation was both expected and needed.
The decision to remove controls on the exchange rate had been
expected to lead to a much higher foreign-exchange price, to encourage
exports, and to permit import liberalization without a surging external
deficit. But when the rate was set free, the price of dollars went down
instead of going up. That initial effect could be explained by the tight
restraints imposed on liquidity, which drove firms and individuals who
held dollar balances to convert them to domestic currency in order to
keep operating. This movement should presumably have gone into reverse
when holdings of dollars ran out, but fully eighteen months later no
reversal had occurred. Dollars remained too cheap to make exports
profitable and too cheap for many producers to compete against imports
for several reasons, including the continuing influx of dollars from the
drug trade into street markets and then into the banking system. A
second reason has involved the continuing low level of domestic income
and production, and corresponding restraint of demand for imports as
compared with what they would be in an expanding economy. But perhaps
the most fundamental reasons have been the continuing squeeze on
liquidity in terms of domestic currency and the resulting high rates of
interest for borrowing domestic currency, which strongly favor borrowing
dollars instead or repatriating them from abroad. All this means that
the economy has had no foreign-exchange problem, but also that
incentives to produce for export have been held down severely, when both
near-term recovery and longer-term growth badly need the stimulus of
rising exports.
The government was more successful in the part of its program aimed
at trade liberalization. As has been noted, the average tariff rate was
cut greatly in two steps, in September 1990 and March 1991. Quantitative
restrictions were eliminated, and the tariff structure was greatly
simplified. Effective protection was brought down to a lower level than
at any point since the mid1960s , with a more coherent structure that
left much less room for distorted incentives.
Although stabilization and structural reform measures have thus shown
some success, the government's program has not taken adequate action to
prevent worsening poverty. Its announced programs of short-term aid in
providing food and longer-term redirection of resources to get people
out of poverty by programs designed to help them raise their
productivity have not yet been implemented in any meaningful way.
Private charitable agencies, the United Nations (UN), and the United
States Agency for International Development (AID) have helped
considerably through food grants to stave off starvation. But the
government itself has done little, either to alleviate current strains
on the poor or to open up new directions that promise gains for them in
the future.
Peru
Peru - Government
Peru
PERU, IN 1980, was one of the first countries in South America to
undergo the transition from long-term institutionalized military rule to
democratic government. By 1990, however, Peru was in the midst of a
social, economic, and political crisis of unprecedented proportions that
threatened not only the viability of the democratic system but also
civil society in general.
More than a decade of steep economic decline had resulted in a
dramatic deterioration in living standards for all sectors of society
and a vast increase in the large proportion of society that was
underemployed and below the poverty line. Per capita incomes were below
their 1960 levels. Accompanying the economic decline in the 1980s was a
rise in insurgent violence and criminal activity. There was also a
marked deterioration in the human rights situation--over 20,000 people
died in political violence during the decade.
The crisis had partial roots in the failure of successive governments
to implement effective economic policy and to fully incorporate the
marginalized (informal) sector of the population into the formal
economic and political systems. Politics were dominated by personalities
rather than programs and by policy swings from populist policies to
neoliberal stabilization strategies.
The concentration of decision-making power in the persona of the
president and the major swings in policy took an enormous toll on the
nation's political system and state institutions. The judicial and
legislative branches, already inadequately funded and understaffed, were
constantly bypassed by the executive. State institutions, meanwhile,
already burdened by excessive bureaucracy, were virtually inoperative
because government resources had all but disappeared. Political parties
had been increasingly discredited, having failed to provide credible
alternatives to the malfunctioning state system with which they were
associated. Both extrasystem movements, such as neighborhood
organizations and grassroots groups, and antisystem movements, such as
guerrilla forces, particularly the Shining Path (Sendero Luminoso--SL),
had increased in size and importance. The breach between the Peruvian
state and civil society had widened. The political system was fragmented
and polarized to an unprecedented degree, and society, which was
immersed in a virtual civil war, had become increasingly praetorian in nature.
Despite the desperate nature of the socioeconomic situation and the
extent of political polarization, Peru successfully held its third
consecutive elections in April and June 1990. Agronomist Alberto K.
Fujimori, a virtual unknown, defeated novelist Mario Vargas Llosa by a
wide margin. The victory of Fujimori and his Cambio '90 (Change '90)
front was seen as a rejection of traditional politicians and parties, as
well as of Vargas Llosa's proposed orthodox economic "shock"
program.
Despite his wide popular margin, Fujimori faced substantial
constraints early on. One was his lack of an organized party base or a
working majority in either of the two houses of Congress. Another was
that, as a result of hyperinflation, the lack of government resources,
and the clear preferences of international lending agencies, such as the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World
Bank, he had little choice but to implement the
orthodox shock program that he had campaigned against.
Although Fujimori made impressive strides during his first year in
the implementation of structural economic reforms, there was substantial
popular disaffection owing to the high social costs of the
"Fujishock" program and to the government's failure to follow
through on promises of a social emergency program to alleviate those
shocks. Resource constraints inherited from the previous government
severely limited the Fujimori administration's ability to act on the
social welfare front. Fujimori lost the support of much of his Cambio
'90 front when he turned to orthodox economics. In addition, he was
forced to rely on a series of "marriages of convenience" with
various political forces in Congress in order to pass legislation. He
also had to rely on a sector of the army for institutional support.
On April 5, 1992, Fujimori suspended the constitution, dissolved the
Congress and the judiciary, and placed several congressional leaders and
members of the opposition under house arrest. The measures, which were
fully supported by all three branches of the armed forces, were
announced in the name of fighting drug traffic. They amounted to an autogolpe
(self-coup): a military coup against the government led by the president
himself. The government held elections for the Democratic Constituent
Congress (Congreso Constituyente Democr�tico) on November 22, 1992, and
municipal elections on January 29, 1993.
<>GOVERNMENTAL SYSTEM
Constitutional Development
<>The President
<>The Legislature
<>The Judiciary
<>Public Administration
<>Local and Regional
Government
<>The Electoral System
<>POLITICAL PARTIES
American Popular Revolutionary Alliance
<>Popular Action
<>The Christian Democrats
<>The Democratic Front
<>The Left
<>Change '90
<>Nonparty Organizations
<>INTEREST GROUPS
The Military
<>The Church
<>Economic Associations
<>Labor Unions
<>Students
<>News Media
<>POLITICAL TRENDS
Roots of the 1990-91 Crisis
<>The Transition to
Democracy
<>The Garc�a Government,
1985-90
<>The 1990 Campaign and
Elections
<>The Fujimori Government
<>FOREIGN RELATIONS
Peru
Peru - GOVERNMENTAL SYSTEM
Peru
During the first five months of 1992, Peru was a republic with a
civilian government, which had a popularly elected president, a
bicameral legislature, and an independent judicial branch. Peru's
civilian government ended indefinitely as a result of Fujimori's autogolpe
of April 5, 1992. The constitution of 1979 remained suspended and its
Congress and judiciary remained dissolved during the rest of 1992. The
following sections describe Peru's legitimate civilian government as it
existed prior to April 5, 1992.
Constitutional Development
Until April 5, 1992, Peru was governed according to a constitution
that became effective with the transition to civilian government in
1980. From the time of the declaration of independence by Jos� de San
Mart�n on July 18, 1821, up until the constitution of 1979, Peru had
ten constitutions. All of them established a presidential form of
government, with varying degrees of power concentrated in the executive.
The French- and Spanish-influenced constitution of 1823, which abolished
hereditary monarchy, was the first formal organic law of the Peruvian
state drawn up by a constituent assembly under a popular mandate.
The departure of Sim�n Bol�var Palacios (1824-25, 1826) on
September 3, 1826, ushered in a long period of revolt and instability
with only brief periods of peace. The presidency changed twelve times
between 1826 and 1845. During this period, Peru was governed under three
constitutions--those of 1828, 1834, and 1839. There was little variation
in the basic form of these constitutions. All provided for separate
executive, legislative, and judicial branches, for indirect election of
the president and Congress, for a centralized regime, and for extensive
personal rights and guarantees. The only major variations were in
details regarding specific powers of the executive.
The 1828 constitution moved toward decentralization and showed
considerable influence by the United States. For example, it provided
for presidential election by popular vote. In subsequent constitutions,
there was a varying emphasis on executive versus legislative power, and
gradual, progressive improvements, such as the subordination of the
military to civilian rule, direct popular elections, and the granting of
the right to association. The 1839 constitution extended the
presidential term from four to six years, with no reelection.
When Marshal Ram�n Castilla (1845-51, 1855-62) emerged as dictator
in 1845, a period of relative peace and prosperity began. The 1856
constitution, promulgated during Castilla's rule, was more liberal and
democratic than any of its predecessors. It provided for the first time
for direct popular election of the president and Congress. However, a
more conservative constitution was promulgated in 1860 and remained in
force, with two brief interruptions--1862-68 and 1879-81--for sixty
years. Although it reduced the presidential term to four years (with
reelection after an intervening term), it greatly increased the powers
of the president and provided for a much more centralized government.
Nevertheless, it laid important bases for the future
executive-legislative relationship. In particular, it established a
requirement that cabinet ministers, although responsible to the
president, report to Congress. Furthermore, it explicitly permitted
Congress, at the end of each legislative session, to examine the
administrative acts of the president to determine their conformity with
the constitution and the laws.
The 1920 constitution was generally more liberal than its
predecessor, the 1860 charter, and provided for more civil guarantees.
Although it established a strong executive and lengthened the
presidential term from four to five years, it placed several new checks
on that branch. It deprived the president of his traditional right to
suspend constitutional guarantees during periods of national emergency
and strengthened the principle of ministerial responsibility to
Congress. In particular, it gave Congress the right to force the
resignation of ministers by a vote of no confidence. Having promulgated
the constitution, however, Augusto B. Legu�a y Salcedo (1908-12,
1919-30) ignored it almost completely and established himself as one of
Peru's strongest dictators.
The 1933 constitution was, at least in theory, operative until 1980,
although civilian government was interrupted from 1933 to 1939, 1948 to
1956, and 1968 to 1980. The 1933 constitution reduced presidential
powers and instituted a mixed presidential-parliamentary system. It also
instituted compulsory and secret balloting, as well as provisions for
religious tolerance and freedom of speech. The president could not
remove or nominate cabinet members without parliamentary consent. This
resulted in a considerable number of executive-legislative stalemates,
the most notable of which occurred during the first government of
President Fernando Bela�nde Terry (1963-68, 1980- 85).
After a prolonged stalemate over issues ranging from tax and agrarian
reforms to a contract with the International Petroleum Corporation, Bela�nde
was overthrown on October 3, 1968, by the armed forces, led by General
Juan Velasco Alvarado (1968-75). The resulting "revolutionary
government" was a progressive, left-wing military regime, which
attempted to implement a series of structural reforms; it maintained
dictatorial powers but was only mildly repressive. After an intraregime
coup in 1975 and a turn to orthodox economic management in the face of
rising fiscal deficits and inflation, as well as increasing levels of
social unrest, the military government called for a civilian-run
Constituent Assembly to draft a new constitution and hold elections.
The constitution of 1979, signed by the president of the Constituent
Assembly, V�ctor Ra�l Haya de la Torre, on July 12, 1979--while he was
virtually on his death-bed--sought to restore strong presidential power.
Largely influenced by the French Fifth Republic, the constitution of
1979 established a presidential system with a bicameral legislature and
a Council of Ministers, which was appointed by the president. An
excessively broad document, the 1979 charter covered a host of rights
and responsibilities of government, private persons, and businesses. It
also established the structure of government and mandated measures to
effect social changes, including the eradication of illiteracy and
extreme poverty. The constitution could be amended by a majority of both
houses of Congress.
The constitution guaranteed a series of liberties and rights,
including the freedom of expression and association and the right to
life, physical integrity, and "the unrestricted development of
one's personality." Although the Roman Catholic Church is entitled
to the cooperation of the government, Catholicism is not the official
religion of the country, and religion is a matter of personal choice.
Workers were guaranteed collective bargaining rights and had the right
to strike and to participate in workplace management and profits. Public
servants, with the exception of those with decision-making power and the
armed forces and police, also had the right to strike.
Constitutional guarantees could be suspended during a state of
emergency, defined as the disruption of peace or the domestic order, a
catastrophe, or grave circumstances affecting the life of the nation. A
state of emergency could not last longer than sixty days but could be
renewed repeatedly. During such a time, the armed forces retained
control of internal order. Guarantees of freedom of movement and of
assembly, and freedom from arbitrary or unwarranted arrest and seizure
were suspended. Constitutional guarantees could also be suspended during
states of siege, defined as an invasion, a civil war, or imminent danger
that one of these events may occur. At least half of the nation lived
under state-of-emergency conditions beginning in the second half of the
1980s, owing to the increase in insurrectionary activities by the
nation's two major guerrilla groups.
Peru
Peru - The President
Peru
The president, who must be Peruvian and over thirty-five years of
age, was elected to a five-year term by direct popular vote, along with
the first and second vice presidents. The president could not serve two
consecutive terms.
The constitutional president had a wide range of powers and served as
chief of state and commander in chief of the armed forces. He had the
power to appoint members to the Council of Ministers and the Supreme
Court of Justice, submit and review legislation enacted by Congress,
rule by decree if so delegated by the Congress, declare states of siege
and emergency, and dissolve the Chamber of Deputies, if it voted to
censure the Council of Ministers three times in one term of office.
In practice, the constitutional president had even more power, as he
had a remarkable amount of freedom to rule by decree. Hernando de Soto,
an adviser to the Fujimori government, stated in October 1988 that 95
percent of Peruvian laws were passed by presidential decree. Article 211
of the constitution gave the president the authority "to administer
public finances, negotiate loans, and decree extraordinary measures in
the economic and financial fields, when the national interest so
mandates and with responsibility to give account to Congress." An
extraordinary number of measures--134,000 per five-year mandate, or 100
per working day--were passed in this manner in the 1970s and 1980s. In
the words of De Soto, "every five years we elect a dictator".
As no midterm elections for Congress were held, opposition parties
had no means of strengthening their position once the president was
elected. Moreover, local and regional governments have remained
underdeveloped and largely dependent on the central government for
resources. Thus, power has remained concentrated in the central
government. As the president could bypass Congress with relative ease
and rule by decree, power was even more centralized in the persona of
the chief executive. Without consecutive reelection or midterm
elections, there was no mechanism by which to make the president
accountable to the electorate.
Under the Fujimori government, De Soto was instrumental in initiating
a reform of this process, the Democratization of the System of
Government, which required laws to be submitted to public referendum
before they could be passed. A watered-down version of this reform was
passed in March 1991. Although this version was not expected to have
notable effects on the actual process, the debate over reform played an
important role in heightening public awareness of the accountability
issue.
The Council of Ministers consists of a prime minister and the
specific sectoral ministers, in areas such as economics, education,
health, and industry. In 1986, during the government of Alan Garc�a P�rez
(1985-90), a Ministry of Defense was created, unifying the three armed
forces under the auspices of one ministry. Prior to this, the army,
navy, and air force each had its own ministry. The ministers could be
called to appear in Congress for an interpellation (interpelaci�n)
at any time, as could the entire cabinet (the latter no more than three
times per term). It is traditional for all ministers to resign if the
prime minister resigns.
It has also been traditional for the prime minister to serve
concurrently as economics minister, although there have been several
exceptions. After the resignation of a very popular and powerful prime
minister, Juan Carlos Hurtado Miller, in February 1991, President
Fujimori separated the posts of prime minister and minister of economy,
appointing Carlos Torres y Torres and Carlos Bolo�a Behr, respectively,
to those positions. The president was purportedly uncomfortable with the
degree of power that Hurtado Miller had and wanted to retain firmer
control of the cabinet in general and economic policy in particular. At
the same time, Fujimori combined the positions of prime minister and
minister of foreign affairs. In a strong presidential system such as
Peru's, the position of prime minister, without control of some other
functional ministry, is a relatively impotent one.
Peru
Peru - The Legislature
Peru
The legislature had two houses: a Senate composed of 60 members and a
Chamber of Deputies composed of 180 members. Members of Congress were
elected to five-year terms of office, which ran concurrently with those
of the president and vice presidents. Members of both chambers had to be
native Peruvians; senators had to be at least thirty-five years of age;
deputies, twenty-five. There was no prohibition on the reelection of
congressional representatives.
Congress had the power to initiate and pass legislation; interpret,
amend, and repeal existing legislation; draft sanctions for violation of
legislation; approve treaties; approve the budget and general accounts;
authorize borrowing; exercise the right of amnesty; and delegate the
legislative function to the president. A vote of two-thirds of each
house was required to pass or amend legislation. The constitution
mandated a balanced budget. If Congress did not come up with a balanced
budget by December 15 of each year, the president promulgated a budget
by executive decree. Congress convened twice annually, from July 27 to
December 15 and again from April 1 to May 31.
Members of Congress were elected according to their position on party
lists, rather than on the basis of local or regional representation, and
thus did not have a strong regional or executive base of support. This
is not to say that they had no regional representation. Whereas members
of the Senate were elected by regions, members of the Chamber of
Deputies were distributed in accordance with the d'Hondt system of
proportional representation, which is based primarily on electoral
density, with at least one deputy from each district.
Voters cast votes for a particular party, which presented a list of
candidates in numerical order of preference. Voters were allowed to
indicate a first-choice candidate, and these votes were tallied as
"preferential votes," which might determine a candidate's
position on the list in future elections, or which region he or she
represents. According to the percentage of votes per region or
department, a certain number of seats were allotted in the Congress for
that party. A candidate's position on the party list determined whether
or not he or she obtained a congressional seat. There was, however, no
direct regional representation in the central government, a situation
that would not be changed by the introduction of regional governments,
as their role was to be strictly limited to the regions.
Congress had the power to censure the Council of Ministers and to
demand information through interpellation. Yet, this gave it more of a
reactive power than anything else. If the Chamber of Deputies used its
vote of no confidence three times, the president could dissolve the
body. Although Congress could make life difficult for the executive
branch through censure, interpellation, or the creation of special
investigative commissions, these processes occurred largely
after-the-fact.
Particularly with the increase in insurgent violence and the large
proportion of the country under emergency rule, the power of the
Congress to pass legislation with an impact on significant sectors of
the population was increasingly limited. At times, though,
after-the-fact processes had resulted in the halting or repeal of
damaging legislation. For example, President Garc�a's decree
nationalizing banks in July 1987 was repealed in late 1990, and
President Fujimori's Decree Law 171, which legislated that all crimes
committed by the military in the emergency zones be tried in military
courts, was repealed in early 1991. In addition, the Congress's special
investigative commissions on issues such as human rights and judicial
corruption, although perhaps unable to have immediate impact on policy,
have been quite successful at bringing such matters to public attention.
The discretionary power accorded the president was designed to avoid
the stalemate that occurred prior to 1968, yet it resulted in a system
that was highly concentrated in the power of the executive, with little
or no public accountability and little significant input on the part of
the legislature. Although the Congress could hold ministers accountable
for their actions, there was little it could do, short of impeachment,
to affect the operations of the president. The president, meanwhile,
unconstrained by midterm elections or immediate reelection, had little
incentive to build a lasting base of support in the legislature.
Peru
Peru - The Judiciary
Peru
The Supreme Court of Justice was the highest judicial authority in
the nation. The twelve Supreme Court justices were nominated by the
president and served for life. The nominations had to be approved by the
Senate. The Supreme Court of Justice was also responsible for drawing up
the budget for the judiciary, which was then submitted to the executive.
The budget could be no less than 2 percent of the government's
expenditures. Under the Supreme Court of Justice were the Superior
Courts, which were seated in the capitals of judicial districts; the
Courts of First Instance, which sat in provincial capitals and were
divided into civil, criminal, and special branches; and the justices of
the peace in all local centers.
Several other judicial functions are worthy of note. The public
prosecutor's office was appointed by the president and was responsible
for overseeing the independence of judges and the administration of
justice, representing the community at trials, and defending people
before the public administration. Public attorneys, who are also
appointed by the president, defend the interests of the state. The
office of the Public Ministry was made up of the attorney general and
attorneys before the Supreme Court of Justice, Superior Courts, and the
Courts of First Instance. Public attorneys defended the rights of
citizens in the public interest against encroachment by public
officials.
The National Elections Board established voting laws, registered
parties and their candidates, and supervised elections. It also had the
power to void elections if the electoral procedures were invalid. The
six-member board was composed of one person elected by the Supreme Court
of Justice, one by the Bar of Lima, one by the law faculty deans of the
national universities, and three Peru's regional boards.
Although in theory the judicial system was independent and guaranteed
at least minimal operating financial support, in practice this was far
from the case. The system had been hampered by scarce resources, a
tradition of executive manipulation, and inadequate protection of
officials in the face of threats from insurgents and drug traffickers.
Even without the existence of guerrilla movements, the system was
inadequately staffed to deal with the number of cases from criminal
violations. It was not uncommon for detainees to spend several years in
prison awaiting a hearing. In addition, in the emergency zones, where
guerrillas were operating, security forces have had virtual carte
blanche in the areas of interrogation and detention, and suspects often
have been held incommunicado. Imprisoned suspects awaiting trial have
subsisted in medieval conditions. In 1990 the Ministry of Justice
recorded 60 deaths from starvation and a backlog over several years of
50,000 unheard cases.
The executive branch traditionally manipulated the judiciary for its
own purposes, using its ability to appoint and remove certain judges for
its own political ends. For example, when a Superior Court judge ruled
that President Garc�a's nationalization of Peru's banks was
unconstitutional, Garc�a merely replaced him with a judge from his
party, the American Popular Revolutionary Alliance (Alianza Popular
Revolucionaria Americana--APRA), who then ruled in his favor.
It also was common for known terrorists or drug traffickers to be
released for "insufficient evidence" by judges with no
protection whatsoever but with responsibility for trying those suspected
of terrorism. Largely because of corruption or inefficiency in the
system, only 5 percent of those detained for terrorism had been
sentenced by 1991. Those responsible for administering justice were
under threat from all sides of the political spectrum: guerrilla
movements, drug traffickers, and military-linked paramilitary squads.
Notable cases included the murder of the defense attorney for the SL's
number two man, Osm�n Morote Barrionuevo, by an APRA-linked death
squad, the Rodrigo Franco Command; the self-exile of a public attorney
after repeated death threats during his investigation of the military's
role in the massacre of at least twenty-nine peasants in Cayara,
Ayacucho Department, on May 14, 1988; a bloody letter-bomb explosion at
the headquarters of the Lima-based Pro-Human Rights Association
(Asociaci�n Pro-Derechos Humanos--Aprodeh); and the March 1991
resignation of an attorney general of the military court martial, after
he received death threats for denouncing police aid and abetment of the
rescue by the T�pac Amaru Revolutionary Movement (Movimiento
Revolucionario T�pac Amaru-- MRTA) of one of its leaders, Mar�a Lucero
Cumpa Miranda. The judicial terrorism was hardly surprising, given the
lack of protection for judges dealing with terrorism cases; many of them
normally rode the bus daily to work, totally unprotected. Finally, owing
to neglect of the judicial system by successive governments, the Supreme
Court of Justice lacked a significant presence at the national level.
In the context of widespread terrorism, what was legal in theory and
what happened in practice had little to do with each other. As the
situation increasingly became one of unrestrained violence, the
capability of the judicial system to monitor the course of events was
reduced markedly. In addition, the judicial system was unable to escape
the loss of confidence in state institutions in general that had
occurred among the Peruvian public. The discrediting of the judicial
system was a significant step toward the total erosion of constitutional
order.
Peru
Peru - Public Administration
Peru
Public administration in Peru, already one of the weakest on the
continent as of 1968, has experienced a dramatic increase in the size of
state enterprises and the number of civil servants. That increase has
been accompanied by a gradual decrease in available funds to run the
administration, partly because of the inefficiency of several of the
state-sector enterprises. The Petroleum Enterprise of Peru (Petroleras
de Per�--Petroper�), for example, lost US$700 million in 1987 alone.
Tax collection has been virtually nonexistent, with the government
having to rely on a tax base of 7 percent of gross national product (GNP), a figure comparable to Bangladesh's 8.6 percent and Uganda's
8.2 percent. Public expenditures per person were US$1,100 in 1975; in
1990 they were only US$180.
These trends were exacerbated markedly during the 1985-90 APRA
government of Garc�a, as party patronage practices dominated the
administration of the state, and the number of state employees increased
from about 282,400 in 1985 to almost 833,000 in 1990, while government
resources all but disappeared because of enormous fiscal deficits and
hyperinflation. State-sector workers were not even paid during the last
few months of the Garc�a government.
The result was a rise in corruption and inefficiency, and Peru had
one of the most inefficient state sectors in the world. Improvements in
the future were likely to be guided by budgetary constraints, as the
resources simply did not exist to maintain the existing number of civil
servants in the public administration. The short-term costs would be a
cutback in already scarce public services and a possible increase in
political protest among displaced civil servants. Most Peruvians simply
did without the services that even a minimal public administration would
normally offer, or else they found some way of attaining them in the
informal sector, usually at a much higher price.
Peru
Peru - Local and Regional Government
Peru
Municipal Governments
The process of independent municipal government was initiated with
the first nationwide municipal elections in December 1963. This process
was halted by twelve years of military rule after 1968, but was
reinitiated with the November 1980 municipal elections. Each
municipality has been run autonomously by a municipal council (consejo
municipal), a provincial council (consejo provincial), and
a district council (consejo distrital), all of whose members
were directly elected. Municipalities had jurisdiction over their
internal organization and they administered their assets and income,
taxes, transportation, local public services, urban development, and
education systems.
Yet, the autonomy of municipalities may have been reduced by their
financial dependence on the central government. Their funds have come
primarily from property taxes, licenses and patents required for
professional services, market fees, vehicle taxes, tolls from bridges
and roads, fines, and donations from urban migrant clubs. In the
majority of municipalities, where the bulk of the inhabitants are poor,
those with legal title to a home are in the minority; few people even
own their own vehicles; roads are not paved; and there is a dramatic
shortage of basic services, such as water and electricity. Most
municipalities can hardly generate the revenue to cover operating costs,
much less to provide desperately needed services. Thus, a degree of
dependence on the central government for resources may limit somewhat
the potential for autonomous initiative. Although this is hardly unique
in Latin America,the shortage of resources in Peru is particularly
extreme.
The municipal process has also come under substantial threat from the
SL. An important component of its strategy was to sabotage the 1989
municipal and presidential elections. The group launched a ruthless
campaign in which elected officials or candidates for electoral offices
were targeted. During the 1985- 89 period, the SL assassinated 45
mayors. In a campaign of violence prior to the 1989 elections, it killed
over 120 elected officials or municipal candidates, resulting in the
resignation or withdrawal of 500 other candidates. In December 1988,
dozens of Andean mayors resigned, citing lack of protection from
terrorist threats; many rural towns were left with no authorities
whatsoever. Voters were also threatened with having their index fingers
chopped off by the SL. The threats were most effective in the more
remote regions, such as Ayacucho, where null and blank voting in the
1990 elections was the highest in the country.
Regional Governments
The constitution of 1979 mandated the establishment of regional
governments in Peru. Regionalization was part of the original APRA
program of the 1920s. In 1988 the APRA government finally imitated the
process with a law providing for the creation, administration, and
modification of regions, which would replace the former departments.
Between 1987 and 1990, the APRA government also issued corresponding
laws creating eleven of the twelve regions called for under law, with
the Lima/Callao region remaining under negotiation. In 1991 debates in
Congress continued on the Lima/Callao and San Mart�n regions, with the
latter voting to separate from La Libertad Department. The highly
politicized debates centered on whether senators should be elected by
region or by national district, and on the method that regional
assemblies are elected. Five of the regions held their first elections
for regional assemblies on November 12, 1989, in conjunction with the
municipal elections, and the other six regions held elections in
conjunction with the April presidential elections.
By law each regional assembly consisted of provincial mayors (30
percent), directly elected representatives (40 percent), and delegates
from institutions representative of the social, economic, and cultural
activities of the region (30 percent). In 1990 APRA and the United Left
(Izquierda Unida--IU) dominated the regions, with APRA controlling six,
IU three, and the Democratic Front (Frente Democr�tico--Fredemo) only
one.
The process of regionalization was more one of administrative
shuffling than of substance. However, the regional governments faced the
same resource constraints that substantially limited the ability of
municipal governments to implement independent activities. The central
government is in theory supposed to transfer funds and assets, such as
state sector enterprises, to the regions, but in practice this has only
happened piecemeal. This tendency had been exacerbated by the severity
of the economic crisis and the poor fiscal situation inherited by the
Fujimori government. The dynamic was made more conflictive as the
regional governments were controlled by parties in opposition to the
central government. The cutting of resources allocated to regional
governments in the 1991 budget was a good indication of the constraints
that regional governments would face for the foreseeable future.
Moreover, the executive had taken back some powers that were originally
given to the regions, such as control over the national tourist hotels.
The regional governments, meanwhile, had heightened the debate with
actions such as the refusal to pay the executive what was owed for
electricity tariffs.
Peru
Peru - The Electoral System
Peru
Suffrage was free, equal, secret, and obligatory for all those
between the ages of eighteen and seventy. The right to participate in
politics could only be taken away when one was sentenced to prison or
given a sentence that stripped a person of his or her political rights.
No political party was given preference by the government, and free
access to the governmentowned mass media was given in proportion to the
percentage of that party's results in the previous election. The
National Elections Board, which was autonomous, was responsible for
electoral processes at the national and local levels.
National elections for the presidency and the Congress were held
every five years. If no one presidential candidate received an absolute
majority, the first- and second-place candidates were in a runoff
election. The president could not be reelected for a consecutive term,
but deputies and senators could be.
Direct municipal elections were held every three years. Regional
governments were elected every five years. Elections of regional
governments were held in conjunction with either the December 1989
municipal or April 1990 national elections.
In the late 1980s and early 1990s, the electoral process came under
substantial threat from the SL, which made the sabotaging of elections
an explicit goal. Despite terrorist threats in the 1990 presidential
elections, voter turnout was higher than in 1985, with the exception of
some emergency zones in the southern Sierra, where the abstention rate
was as high as 40 percent. Null and blank voting was about 14.5 percent
of the total in the first round in 1990 and 9.5 percent in the second.
The threat from the SL was such that in some remote rural towns,
there were no local officials at all, because potential candidates were
not willing to jeopardize their lives in order to run for office.
Although there was no doubt that the SL failed to jeopardize the 1990
elections, it managed to pose a significant threat to the process,
particularly in remote rural areas. Given the severity and brutality of
the SL's threat, it was actually a credit to the Peruvian electoral
process that elections were held regularly and with such high
voter-turnout ratios, although fines for not voting were also a factor.
Peru
Peru - POLITICAL PARTIES
Peru
Until April 5, 1992, Peru had a multiparty system and numerous
political parties, some of which had been in existence for several
decades. Yet, in 1990 the Peruvian electorate by and large rejected
established parties and voted for a virtual unknown from outside the
traditional party system. Alberto Fujimori's rapid and sudden rise to
power and the resulting government with no political party base
signified a crisis for Peru's party system, and a crisis of
representation more generally. These crises resulted from the severity
of the socioeconomic situation, and also from the poor performance of
several of the traditional parties in government.
American Popular Revolutionary Alliance
APRA, Peru's oldest and only well-institutionalized party, was
founded by V�ctor Ra�l Haya de la Torre in Mexico City in May 1924.
The APRA program espoused an anti-imperialist, Marxistoriented but
uniquely Latin American-based solution to Peru's and Latin America's
problems. APRA influenced several political movements throughout Latin
America, including Bolivia's Nationalist Revolutionary Movement
(Movimiento Nacionalista Revolucionario--MNR) and Costa Rica's National
Liberation Party (Partido Liberaci�n Nacional--PLN). Years of
repression and clandestinity, as well as single-handed dominance of the
party by Haya de la Torre, resulted in sectarian and hierarchical traits
that were analogous to some communist parties. In addition,
opportunistic ideological swings to the right by Haya de la Torre in the
1950s, in exchange for attaining legal status for the party, resulted in
an exodus of some of APRA's most talented young leaders to the Marxist
left. These shifts created cleavages between APRA and the rest of
society, and were significant obstacles to democratic consensus-building
during APRA's 1985-90 tenure in government.
In any case, the party maintained a devoted core of followers that
remained permanent party loyalists. In May 1989, APRA chose as its
standard bearer Luis Alva Castro, a long-time rival to President Garc�a.
APRA was as much a social phenomenon as a political movement, with a
significant sector of society among its membership whose loyalty to the
party and its legacy was unwavering. Despite APRA's disastrous tenure in
power, in the first round of the 1990 elections it obtained 19.6 percent
of the vote, more than any other of the traditional parties.
Peru
Peru - Popular Action
Peru
Fernando Bela�nde Terry founded Popular Action (Acci�n Popular--AP)
in 1956 as a reformist alternative to the status quo conservative forces
and the controversial APRA party. Although Bela�nde's message was not
all that different from APRA's, his tactics were more inclusive and less
confrontational. He was able to appeal to some of the same political
base as APRA, primarily the middle class, but also to a wider base of
professionals and white-collar workers. The AP had significant electoral
success, attaining the presidency in 1963 and 1980, but the party was
more of an electoral machine for the persona of Bela�nde than an
institutionalized organization. In addition, whereas in the 1960s the AP
was seen as a reformist party, by the 1980s--as Peru's political
spectrum had shifted substantially to the left--the AP was positioned on
the center-right. With the debacle of the second Bela�nde government,
the AP fared disastrously in 1985, attaining only 6.4 percent of the
vote. In 1990 the AP participated in the elections as a part of the
conservative coalition behind Mario Vargas Llosa and suffered, as did
all political parties, an electoral rejection.
Peru
Peru - The Christian Democrats
Peru
The Christian Democratic Party (Partido Dem�crata Cristiano-- PDC)
was a relatively small, center-right party influenced by Christian
Democratic thought. Slightly more conservative than the AP, the PDC,
which was founded in 1956, also was perceived to be more to the right as
Peru's spectrum shifted left. The PDC on its own was not able to garner
an electoral representation of over 10 percent after 1980. A splinter
group, the Popular Christian Party (Partido Popular Cristiano--PPC), was
founded by Luis Bedoya Reyes (the mayor of Lima from 1963 to 1966) in
1966.
Peru
Peru - The Democratic Front
Peru
The AP and the PPC together provided the organizational basis for
Mario Vargas Llosa and his independent Liberty Movement (Movimiento de
Libertad). Vargas Llosa, who entered politics to protest Garc�a's
nationalization of Peru's banks in 1987, started out as an independent,
backed by the Liberty Movement. In late 1988, however, Vargas Llosa made
a formal alliance, known as Fredemo, with the AP and the PPC, because he
felt this provided him with a necessary party organizational base. By
doing so, he alienated several members of his own coalition, including
one of his primary backers, Hernando de Soto, who felt that Vargas Llosa
was allying with the "traditional" right. Analysis of the
electoral results indicated that the majority of voters were also
reluctant to support Peru's traditional, conservative politicians. The
Fredemo campaign spent inordinate amounts of money on advertising--US$12
million, versus US$2 million spent by the next highest spender, APRA.
This, in conjunction with the use in television campaign advertisements
of white, foreign-born singers, revealed how these parties continued to
represent the interests of the nation's elite, who were of European
ancestry, and how out of touch they were with the nation's poor, who
were of indigenous heritage.
Peru
Peru - The Left
Peru
The 1990 results also demonstrated that the population was unwilling
to vote for the nation's hopelessly divided left. Split into Leninist,
Maoist, Marxist, Trotskyite, and Socialist camps, the left in Peru had
been severely fragmented since its origins. It had its first experience
as a legally recognized electoral force in the 1978-80 Constituent
Assembly, in which the left made up approximately one-third of the
delegates. Despite its relative strength at the grassroots level, the
left was unable to unite behind one political front in the 1980
elections, and it contested the elections as nine separate political
factions. This limited its potential in those elections and played into
the hands of Bela�nde. The left together attained a total of 16.7
percent of the vote; APRA, divided and leaderless after the death of
Haya de la Torre, garnered 27.4 percent; Bela�nde won 45.4 percent.
Shortly after the 1981 elections, the majority of the factions of the
Socialist, Marxist, and Maoist left (with the obvious exception of the
SL, which had gone underground in the early 1970s), formed the United
Left (IU) coalition. By 1986, under the leadership of Alfonso Barrantes
Ling�n, the IU was strong enough to take the municipality of Lima, as
well as to become the major opposition force to the APRA government.
Barrantes had been the runner-up in the 1985 national elections, winning
22.2 percent of the vote.
Yet, there were irreparable divisions from the outset between the
moderate Barrantes faction, which remained committed, first and
foremost, to democracy, and the more militant factions, which were
sympathetic to, if not overtly supportive of, "armed struggle"
as a potential route. The existence of two active guerrilla movements
made this a debate of overriding importance. Although much of the
militant left condemned the brutal tactics of the SL, they remained
sympathetic with and indeed often had ties to the more
"conventional" tactics of the MRTA.
This breach came to a head in 1989, when Barrantes, the most popular
politician the left had in its ranks, and the bulk of the moderates
split off and formed the Leftist Socialist Accord (Acuerdo Socialista
Izquierdista--ASI). The larger and bestorganized parties, including the
radical Mariateguist Unified Party (Partido Unificado
Mariateguista--PUM) and the Peruvian Communist Party (Partido Comunista
Peruano--PCP), remained in the IU. A divided left quarrelling over
ideological differences hardly seemed the solution to Peru's quagmire in
1990. In the 1990 elections, the left had its poorest showing since the
formation of the IU, with the ASI and IU together garnering less than 12
percent of the vote.
Peru
Peru - Change '90
Peru
Cambio '90 only entered the Peruvian political spectrum in early
1990, but by June 1991 it was the most powerful political force in the
nation. Cambio's success hinged largely on the success of its candidate
for the presidency, Alberto Fujimori, an agricultural engineer and
rector of the National Agrarian University (Universidad Nacional
Agrario--UNA) in Lima's La Molina District from 1984 to 1989. Fujimori's
appeal to a large extent was his standing as a political outsider.
At the same time, Cambio's success was also attributed largely to its
eclectic political base and its active grassroots campaign. Cambio's two
main bases of support were the Peruvian Association of Small- and
Medium-Sized Businesses (Asociaci�n Peruana de Empresas Medias y Peque�as--Apemipe)
and the informal sector workers who associated their cause with Apemipe,
and the evangelical movement. Less than 4 percent of the Peruvian
population was Protestant, but the Evangelicals were extremely active at
the grassroots level, particularly in areas where traditional parties
were weak, such as the urban shantytowns and rural areas in the Sierra.
Although Cambio only began activities in January 1990, by the time of
the elections it had 200,000 members in its ranks.
However, Cambio's success at the polls did not translate into a
lasting party machinery. Cambio was much more of a front than a
political party, and its ability to hold together was called into
question within a few weeks after attaining power. Cambio's two bases of
support had little in common with each other except opposition to Vargas
Llosa. Their links to Fujimori were quite recent and were ruptured to a
large extent when Fujimori opted, out of necessity, for an orthodox
economic shock program. Less than six months into his government,
Fujimori broke with many of his Cambio supporters, including the second
vice president and leader of the Evangelical Movement, Carlos Garc�a y
Garc�a, and Apemipe. The latter became disenchanted with Fujimori
because small businesses were threatened by the dramatic price rises and
opening to foreign competition that the "Fujishock" program
entailed.
Peru
Peru - Nonparty Organizations
Peru
The rapid rise of Cambio reflected a more far-reaching phenomenon in
Peru: the growth of extrasystem democratic political activity. In
conjunction with the rise in economic importance of the informal sector
was a rise in activity and importance of a host of "informal"
political groups: neighborhood organizations, communal kitchens, popular
economic organizations, and nongovernment organizations. Although
originating largely outside the realm of traditional parties and
politics, these groups became critical actors in local-level democratic
politics. Usually autonomous and democratic in origin and structure,
they were often wary of political parties, which attempted to co-opt
them, or at least to elicit their support for wider-reaching political
goals. These organizations were primarily concerned with micro-level
survival issues, such as obtaining basic services like water and
electricity. They tended to support political parties as a convenient
way to attain their goals, but just as easily withdrew that support when
it did not provide tangible ends. They had a tendency, but by no means a
constant one, to vote for parties of the left. This could be explained
in part by the Peruvian left's approach to grassroots movements, which
was usually--but not always--less sectarian and hierarchical than that
of traditional parties, such as APRA.
Thus, the relations that informal groups had with political parties
were by no means simple or clear-cut. As the varied results from the
1980-90 elections demonstrate, the urban poor had a tendency, which was
not without shifts, to vote for the left. They had few binding ties to
political parties, and were quite willing to vote for nonparty actors,
from Manuel A. Odr�a (president, 1948-50, 1950-56) in the 1950s to
Ricardo Belmont (as mayor of Lima in 1989) and Fujimori in 1990. Because
the urban poor's need for basic services was so grave, their vote was
most often determined by the most credible promise for basic-service
delivery. Broader political goals of the parties were only a concern
once basic needs had been met. Still, the gap between these groups and
parties was significant. Parties play a role in virtually all
consolidated democracies, and the difficulties of governing a fragmented
society and polity such as Peru's became increasingly evident as the
Fujimori government was forced to implement unpopular economic policies
in the absence of an organized political base.
Electoral defeats usually trigger internal party changes and
democratization. In 1990 all Peruvian parties faced electoral losses.
The parties were well aware of the need to reform in order to remain
politically viable entities. In early 1991, the Christian Democrats, for
example, launched a process of internal party reform and an evaluation
of their relations with groups where their support base was weak, such
as the shantytowns. The left underwent a process of ideological and
strategic reflection at approximately the same time. Most of the other
political parties likely would have followed suit. To the extent that
parties failed to reform to adapt to new political realities and to the
needs and strategies of the plethora of grassroots groups and local
organizations in Peru, a crisis of representation in Peruvian democracy,
if and when it was restored, appeared more likely for the foreseeable
future, threatening its viability.
Peru
Peru - INTEREST GROUPS
Peru
The Military
The military in Peru has traditionally played an influential role in
the nation's politics, whether directly or indirectly. Prior to the 1968
revolution, the military was seen as caretaker of the interests of
conservative elites, and its involvement in politics usually entailed
the repression of "radical" alternatives, particularly APRA.
An APRA uprising and brutal military retaliation in Trujillo in 1932
initiated a long period of violence and strained relations between the
two. As late as 1962, when General Ricardo P�rez Godoy led a military
coup to prevent Haya de la Torre from becoming president, the military
was willing to resort to extraconstitutional means to prevent APRA from
coming to power.
By 1962, however, it was evident that the military was no longer
solely the preserver of elite interests, and that it was increasingly
influenced by a new military school of thought, the National Security
Doctrine, which posited that development and social reform were integral
to national security. The Advanced Military Studies Center (Centro de
Altos Estudios Militares-- CAEM) in Lima was a proponent of this
philosophy in the 1950s and 1960s. In addition, the Peruvian military's
involvement in fighting guerrilla uprisings in the southern Sierra in
the mid1960s gave many officers a first exposure to the destitute
conditions of the rural poor, and to the potential unrest that those
conditions could breed.
Thus, the military's 1968 intervention was far from a typical
military coup. Rather, it was a military-led attempt at implementing
far-reaching economic and social reforms, such as the Agrarian Reform
Law of 1969 and the Industrial Community Law of 1970. The military's
lack of understanding of civil society, demonstrated by its
authoritarian attempts to control popular participation through a
government-sponsored social mobilization agency, the National System for
Supporting Social Mobilization (Sistema Nacional de Apoyo a la
Mobilizaci�n Social--Sinamos), was largely responsible for the failure
of its reforms. When the military left power in 1980, it left a legacy
of economic mismanagement, incomplete reforms, and a society more
radicalized and politicized than when it had taken over.
Yet, the military's revolutionary experiment changed the image of the
institution, as well as its own views about the benefits of direct
government control. It was, at least for the foreseeable future, immune
from direct intervention in politics. It was no longer seen, however,
and no longer perceived itself, as a monolithic conservative
institution, but rather as the institution that had attempted to do what
no political force had been able to do: radically transform the nation's
economy and society. Its failure may have strengthened the voice of
conservatives within its ranks, but it retained the awareness that
social reform and economic development were critical to Peru's social
stability and ultimately its national security. And as keeper of
national security, it, more than any other force in the nation, was
constantly reminded of this by the presence of the SL and other
insurgent groups.
The large proportion of the country under state of emergency rule,
coupled with the military's desire to fight against the SL unconstrained
by civilian control, had understandably created tensions between
successive civilian governments and the military. As in the case of
several other transitions to democracy in Latin America, the Peruvian
military took precautions to protect its institutional viability and to
increase its strength vis-�-vis civilian government. From the outset,
the Bela�nde government was forced to accept certain conditions set by
the military pertaining to budgetary autonomy and states of emergency.
Nineteen days before the surrender of power to the Bela�nde
administration, the military passed the Mobilization Law, with minimum
publicity in order to avoid civilian reaction. The law enabled the
military to expropriate or requisition companies, services, labor, and
materials from all Peruvians or foreigners in the country at times of
national emergency. These times included cases of "internal
subversion and internal disasters." In addition, because the Bela�nde
government failed to take the SL seriously until it was too late, the
government defaulted to the military in the design and implementation of
a counterinsurgency strategy.
The Garc�a government began with a different approach. Garc�a fired
three top generals responsible for civilian massacres in the emergency
zones, and in a blow to traditional budgetary autonomy, halved an air
force order for French Mirage jets. However, Garc�a's image suffered a
major blow after he personally gave orders for the military to do
whatever was necessary to put down a revolt of the SL inmates in Lima's
prisons in June 1986, resulting in the massacre of 300 prisoners, most
of whom had already surrendered. As the government lost coherence and as
economic crisis and political stalemate set in, pressure on the military
subsided, and its de facto control over the counterinsurgency campaign
increased.
Because the Fujimori government had no organized institutional base,
it was in a difficult position vis-�-vis the military. Although the
military had no desire to take direct control of the government, it
indicated the one scenario that would force it to intervene--if no one
were running the state. Even at the height of the APRA government's
crisis, when President Garc�a was in virtual hiding in the government
palace, the military could rely on APRA to run the state. If a similar
loss of control by President Fujimori occurred, there would be no such
institution with a stake in running the state, a scenario that might
force the military to act. Fujimori had clearly made a point of building
strong support in one sector of the army and in return seemed to be
backing increased independence for the military in the counterinsurgency
war.
A good example of the military's independence was the passage of
Decree Law 171, which stipulated that military personnel in emergency
zones were on active duty full time and therefore could only be tried in
military courts, which try only for neglect of duty and not for
offenses, such as murder or torture. In addition, the government
exacerbated tensions with some sectors of the military in September 1990
by refusing to sign a US$93- million aid agreement with the United
States that included US$36 million in military aid. The Fujimori
government felt the accord's coca eradication policy did not
sufficiently take economic development into account. Some within the
armed forces, which in general were desperately short of funds, felt
that the government should take what it could get. In May 1991, Fujimori
conceded to both United States and Peruvian military pressure and signed
the accord.
In short, the situation under Fujimori was one of de facto military
control, not just of the emergency zones, but of the areas of government
that the military perceived to be its domain. Demonstrative of the
military's increasing influence over certain areas of government was the
fact that the Ministry of Defense and the Ministry of Interior were both
headed by generals.
Peru
Peru - The Church
Peru
Although Peru does not have an official religion, the Roman Catholic
Church--to which over 90 percent of Peruvians belonged-- is recognized
in the constitution as deserving of government cooperation.
Traditionally, the Roman Catholic Church has monopolized religion in the
public domain.
In the Peruvian Catholic Church hierarchy, staunch conservatives,
such as Archbishop Juan Landaz�ri Ricketts, wielded a great deal of
influence. Six of the total eighteen bishops, including Landaz�ri,
belonged to the ultraconservative Opus Dei movement. At the same time,
the founder of liberation
theology, Gustavo Guti�rrez, was a member of the
official church in Peru, and liberation theology had a strong presence
at the grassroots level. Unlike Brazil, where the official church could
be described as liberal and critical of the more conservative Vatican,
or Colombia, where the church was a loyal follower of the Vatican's
policies, in the Peruvian Church hierarchy both trends coexisted, or at
least competed for influence. Conservatives followed the dictates of
Pope John Paul II, a strong proponent of theological orthodoxy and
vertical control of the church. This contrasted sharply with the
progressives in the Latin American church, who espoused the mandate of
Vatican II, which exhorted the clergy to become actively involved in
humanity's struggle for peace and justice, and to help the poor to help
themselves rather than accept their fate.
At the grassroots level, the church was extremely active at
organizing neighborhood organizations and self-help groups, such as
communal kitchens and mothers' clubs. Church activities at this level had little
to do with theoretical debates at higher levels, although they tended to
emanate from the more progressive sectors within. Church-related
organizations, such as Caritas (Catholic Relief Services), were active
in providing local efforts with donations of food and funds from abroad.
Indeed, Caritas had a nationwide network of coverage superior to or at
least rivaling that of any state ministry or institution.
In addition to Caritas, the other major nongovernment organizer of
communal kitchens and mothers' clubs in Lima was the Seventh Day
Adventist Church, which reflected the increasing importance of the
Evangelical Movement. Although only about 4.5 percent of Peru's
population was Protestant, the Evangelical Movement was extremely active
at the grassroots level, and, as aforementioned, was critical to the
victory of Fujimori and Cambio '90 in poor areas. The Catholic Church
hierarchy felt sufficiently threatened by the Evangelicals' support for
Fujimori that it unofficially backed Vargas Llosa, an agnostic, against
Fujimori, a Catholic.
The church, to the extent that it was an organizer of the poor, had
increasingly come into conflict with the SL. Initially, the SL paid
little attention to the clergy. In Ayacucho, for example, where the
traditionally oriented church hierarchy had little involvement with
social issues, the church was of little relevance to the SL. However, in
the late 1980s, the SL's strategy shifted, and the group became more
concerned with the church's organizational potential. The SL had a more
difficult challenge in organizing support, particularly in areas where
the church had been active in encouraging close community bonds, such as
parts of Cajamarca and Puno. In such areas, as in the shantytowns
surrounding Lima, clergy had increasingly become targets of SL
assassinations as well.
In the face of the weakening of other state institutions, the
church's role, at least at the grassroots level, had increased in
importance. Caritas was the primary mobilizer of food donations and aid
during the most critical stage of the Fujimori government's shock
stabilization plan. Although the government promised its own social
emergency programs, none materialized, and the church surfaced as the
primary vehicle for channeling aid to the poor. This activity increased
the visibility of the clergy as a target of SL attacks, and posed
difficult choices for members of the clergy who continued to operate in
the regions where the SL had a strong presence--the majority of the
areas where most of the poor of Peru resided.
Peru
Peru - Economic Associations
Peru
The major economic associations in Peru were the National Industries
Association (Sociedad Nacional de Industrias--SNI), the National
Confederation of Private Business (Confederaci�n Nacional de
Instituciones Empresariales Privadas--Confiep), and the Apemipe
(Peruvian Association of Small and Medium-Sized Businesses).
Traditionally, such organizations had played a minimal role in politics.
In the 1980s, however, they became actively involved in the nation's
politics.
Garc�a's national understanding (concertaci�n) strategy
called for cooperation between government and business in economic
policy-making. Nevertheless, Garc�a bypassed organized business
sectors, the foremost among them being Confiep, and dealt instead
directly with the twelve most powerful businesspeople in the country,
the so-called twelve apostles. Thus, when Garc�a threatened the entire
private sector with his surprise nationalization of the nation's banks,
Confiep became one of the most active supporters of the bankers
protesting Garc�a's move, and subsequently of Vargas Llosa's Liberty
movement. Meanwhile, two former presidents of Confiep--now senators
Francisco Pardo Mesones of Somos Libres (We Are Free) and Ricardo Vega
Llona of Fredemo--launched independent candidacies in the 1990
elections.
Ironically, Apemipe became politically active in opposition to Vargas
Llosa and his proposed policies, which threatened the viability of many
small-businesspeople. The former president of Apemipe, M�ximo San Rom�n,
ran as first vice president for Cambio, and became president of the
Senate.
Organized business, per se, has never been particularly influential
in Peru. Instead, strong influence has been wielded by foreign
companies, such as the International Petroleum Corporation (IPC), or by
families, such as the Romeros and the Wieses, who had substantial
holdings across a variety of industries. Yet with the economic situation
in May 1991 and the substantial reduction of foreign investment, the
domestic private sector had increased in its relative economic
importance. Thus, the sector's tendency to use its organizations to
influence political trends was likely to continue for the foreseeable
future.
Peru
Peru - Labor Unions
Peru
The labor movement in Peru has traditionally been weak, and its fate,
until 1968, was inextricably linked to APRA. Very much affected by the
enclave or anti-union enterprises and by the rural or community
background of many of its members, labor was unable to articulate a
coherent set of class interests. APRA, with its organizational capacity
and popular following, was perhaps the only existing mobilization
vehicle for organized labor. APRA dominated the Confederation of
Peruvian Workers (Confederaci�n de Trabajadores del Per�--CTP), which
it founded in 1944 and which was officially recognized in 1964. The
major labor dispute was traditionally between the CTP and APRA, and
there was a direct correlation between union activity and the legal
status of APRA, which was usually banned by military governments. APRA
was more concerned with using the labor movement for its own ends than
with enhancing the objectives of organized labor. APRA curtailed strike
activity, for example, during its years of collaboration with the
government of Manuel Prado y Ugarteche (1939-45, 1956-62).
Union activity increased dramatically during the military years with
the introduction of a new labor code and the Industrial Reform Law,
culminating in the union-led general strikes of 1977 and 1978. Yet, the
labor and industries laws, which made it more difficult to dismiss a
worker in Peru than in any industrialized nation, acted as a major
disincentive to formal sector employment. This, coupled with the
dramatic economic decline of the 1980s, led to a substantial decrease in
the relative power of labor unions by 1990.
After 1968 the communist labor movement, the General Confederation of
Peruvian Workers (Confederaci�n General de Trabajadores del Per�--CGTP),
was legalized and began to erode APRA's monopoly on union support, owing
in part to the party's relinquishing its radical stance. The Federation
of Workers of the Peruvian Revolution (Central de Trabajadores de la
Revoluci�n Peruana--CTRP), which was set up by the military as an
attempt to control the workers' movement, never really got off the
ground, particularly in the face of the powerful CGTP. In 1991 the CGTP
remained the most important union confederation in Peru.
The traits that were held typical of APRA union support-- marginal,
socially ambitious, and socially frustrated--began to characterize the
Maoist left and its affiliated unions under the CGTP umbrella in the
1970s. These groups, such as the powerful teachers' union, the Trade
Union of Education Workers (Sindicato nico de Trabajadores de la Ense�anza--SUTEP),
and the miners' confederation, the National Federation of Syndicated
Mining and Metallurgical Workers of Peru (Federaci�n Nacional de
Trabajadores Mineros y Metal�rgicos Sindicalistas del Per�-- FNTMMSP),
were key actors in the general strikes that virtually brought down the
military regime in the late 1970s. In addition, the expansion of state
industries, each of which had its own affiliated union, substantially
increased the number of organized workers.
By the early 1980s, economic decline began to erode the power of
unions, as did the neoliberal strategy adhered to by the Bela�nde
government. The APRA government completely bypassed organized labor, as
it did organized industry in its concertaci�n strategy. Garc�a's
populist tactics left little room for organized labor. Although there
was a high number of strikes by state sector workers during the Garc�a
government, particularly during the last two "crisis" years,
they were generally more defensive, in the face of economic decline,
than political. Most of the general strikes that were called during the
Garc�a government were largely a failure, attaining only minimal
support.
One reason that organized labor was less able to pursue political
goals was the SL, which launched several "armed strikes" in
various cities throughout the Garc�a years. Although these had varying
degrees of success, they rarely had union support, as supporting the
strikes meant supporting the SL. Increasingly, street protest for
political purposes signified support for armed insurrection, which the
majority of unions rejected. Indeed, there were even violent clashes
between the SL and the CGTP during one general strike.
The SL had its own affiliated union, the Class Movement of Workers
and Laborers (Movimiento de Obreros y Trabajadores Clasistas--MOTC),
which operated primarily in the industries along Lima's Central Highway
(Trans-Andean Highway), the industrial belt of the city. Of the four
major companies along this highway, the MOTC had made substantial
inroads in three. The MOTC did not necessarily control unions, but was
tenacious in its support of strikes and was able to establish a strong
presence in these industries. Yet, it also created rifts in the labor
movement in general, because many workers did not necessarily want to be
affiliated with the SL. Indicative of the extent of conflict was the
SL's killing of fifty-one union leaders, primarily mineworkers, between
January and May 1989, and its assassination of a prominent textile
leader in October 1989.
The one labor sector that was able to exert substantial pressure
during the APRA government was the miners' federation, the FNTMMSP,
which in 1989 staged a strike involving 90,000 miners and costing the
government hundreds of millions of dollars in lost export earnings.
Meanwhile, the federation was also targeted by the SL. Although able to
infiltrate the union to some extent, staging armed strikes and attacking
mining facilities, the SL was by no means able to gain control of it.
Nevertheless, the SL's presence caused violence from both the left
(there were clashes between the SL and nonsympathetic miners) and the
right (the leader of the miners' federation was assassinated by the
APRA- and military-linked paramilitary squad, the Rodrigo Franco
Command). Finally, some critics felt that the government and the
National Mining and Petroleum Company (Sociedad Nacional de Miner�a y
Petr�leo--SNMP) found the SL infiltration of the mines a convenient
excuse for declaring a state of emergency in the region.
Only 15 to 20 percent of the labor force was unionized in 1990,
making that force a rather privileged sector of the working class.
Underemployment was as high as 75 percent; and only 9 percent of Lima's
economically active population was fully employed.
The prospects for the union movement in Peru in the early 1990s were
dismal at best. On the one hand, the economic crisis made access to a
job a luxury. Protest by organized labor was a last attempt at
protecting salary levels that had deteriorated by over 50 percent in the
1985-90 period. On the other, the SL's drive to establish influence
among organized labor presented a challenge to all the unions that
wished to retain their independence.
In the event of an economic recovery and the adoption of a more
realistic labor code that did not make access to a job a privilege for a
small minority, organized labor might be able to enhance its status as
the protector of workers rights rather than the proponent of political
radicalism. Still, these developments also hinged on the defeat of the
foremost proponent of radicalism, the SL--an unlikely scenario in the
short term.
Peru
Peru - Students
Peru
Like the labor unions, the student movement has seen its rise and
fall in Peru, and its fate was also inextricably linked to that of the
SL. Compared with Peru's other social welfare indicators, Peru had a
relatively high rate of literacy (80 percent), owing in large part to
the strong emphasis that both Bela�nde regimes placed on education. The
numbers of students enrolled in universities increased dramatically in
the 1960s, and, consequently, so did their level of organization.
Critics had justifiably contended that the emphasis on education was at
the expense of other key social welfare expenditures, such as health.
Students had a strong tradition of political organization in Peru.
For example, APRA began as a student and workers union. Student leaders,
both of APRA and of the left, also played an important role in the
protests against the military regime in the late 1970s. Congruent with
the growth in relative strength of the Marxist left in politics was an
increase in their presence in student organizations. In early 1991,
there was a host of university student organizations, most allied with
different factions of the left or with APRA. Some organizations were
also allied with the SL or MRTA. Student supporters of the
"new" right, such as the Liberty Movement, had also emerged,
although they were by far in the minority. The increase in student
organization had occurred in conjunction with the curbing of financing
for universities and the shrinking of economic opportunities for
university graduates, which had resulted in a radicalization of the
university community in general. Although a few prestigious private
universities continued to guarantee their students top degrees and
professional opportunities, the quality of the education attained by
large numbers of students at state universities was by no means
universal and was often quite poor. Thus, many universities increasingly
had become havens for frustration.
The extreme manifestation of this phenomenon was the birth and growth
of the SL in the University of Huamanga (Universidad de Huamanga) in
Ayacucho in the 1970s. Abim�el Guzm�n Reynoso, a professor at the
university and eventually director of personnel, was the founder and
leader of the SL. The SL virtually controlled the university for several
years, and students were indoctrinated in the SL philosophy. The
university trained students, mainly from the Ayacucho area, primarily in
education; but a degree from Huamanga was considered inferior to the
Lima universities, and students had few opportunities other than
returning to their hometowns to teach. As jobs for graduates were few
and far between, becoming an active militant in the SL provided an
opportunity of sorts.
An analogous phenomenon occurred in most of the Lima universities in
the 1980s. Poorly funded and staffed, universities had far more students
than they could adequately train. Employment opportunities had virtually
disappeared, and university graduates often ended up driving taxis. The
oldest university in the Americas, the state-funded San Marcos
University, had become the center of Peru's student radicalism. SL
graffiti covered the walls; police raids on the university yielded large
caches of weapons and ammunition, as well as arrests. Professors who
openly sympathized with the SL were the norm. In 1989 student elections,
members of the student organization that supported the SL won in first
place and controlled facilities such as the cafeteria.
Like union members, university students often were confronted with a
dire predicament. They were the focus of SL organizational efforts, and
at the same time their economic opportunities had virtually disappeared.
Peaceful organizational efforts to improve their position had little
potential in the current context, yet violent efforts were inextricably
linked to the SL. Radicalism was in theory an appealing alternative, but
in reality the ultraviolent form in which it manifested itself in the SL
was hardly an alternative. Unfortunately, finding a job was also less
and less a realistic alternative.
Peru
Peru - News Media
Peru
In 1990 Peru had one of the freest and most varied presses in the
world, with virtually no curbs on what was published. The
best-established and largest circulating newspaper was the slightly
conservative daily, El Comercio. Expreso, owned by
former minister of economy and finance Manuel Ulloa, was also slightly
to the right of center. A variety of left-leaning dailies included Cambio,
El Diario de Marka, and La Rep�blica. Hoy
was the pro-APRA daily. El Di�rio was a pro-SL newspaper that
used to be published daily in Lima and circulated approximately 5,000
copies a day. The government closed it in late 1988, after the editor
was accused of being a member of the SL, but it reappeared the next year
as a weekly. A state-owned newspaper, El Peruano, published a
daily listing of decrees and government proceedings. Oiga
magazine was a right wing weekly, Caretas and S� were
centrist weeklies. Quehacer was a bimonthly research
publication sympathizing with the left.
Peru had a total of 140 state and privately owned television
channels. Channel 4, the state-owned channel, provided relatively
well-balanced news, as it had fierce competition from its private
competitors. The popular weekly news program, "Panorama,"
which broadcast in-depth interviews with a wide range of intellectuals,
politicians, and even guerrillas, was quite influential. The MRTA, for
example, made its entrance into national politics when its takeover of
Juanju� in San Mart�n Department was aired on Panorama.
Peru's media were in general varied, competitive, and highly
informative, and options from all sides of the political spectrum were
available. Peru's population was a highly informed one, with even the
poorest people usually having access to television. In early 1991, when
the intelligence police found a video of Abim�el Guzm�n Reynoso
dancing in a drunken stupor, it was aired on national television. When
in early 1991 President Fujimori passed Decree Law 171, the media played
a major role in raising public awareness as to the impunity that it
imparted onto the armed forces and the threat that it posed to
investigative journalism in the emergency zones. The publicity was in
part responsible for the repeal of the decree in Congress. Indeed, the
extent to which freedom of the press continued to exist in Peru, despite
the many other obstacles to democratic government, was an important and
positive force for Peru's democracy.
Peru
Peru - POLITICAL TRENDS
Peru
Roots of the 1990-91 Crisis
There was no single explanation for the nature and severity of the
crisis Peru faced in the early 1990s. The temptation to blame Garc�a
and APRA was a strong one, given their dismal performance in government,
but the crisis had much deeper roots. APRA inherited a nation beset with
economic and social problems, but a political climate in which the
consensus on the need for reform was unprecedented. The manner in which
APRA governed resulted in an exacerbation of an existing breach between
state and society. Consensus gave way to polarization and fragmentation
of the party system, and economic policy fell prey to internal party
politics, with disastrous results.
Peru
Peru - The Transition to Democracy
Peru
Like many other military establishments on the continent, the
Peruvian military halted the civilian political process for a prolonged
period of time (1968-80), attempted major structural economic change
without a great deal of success, accumulated a large debt without public
accountability, and then turned the political system back over to the
same politicians it had previously ousted. The transition to democratic
government, meanwhile, raised popular expectations that a fragile new
democracy with severely constrained resources could hardly hope to meet.
The 1980 elections were won, ironically, by Fernando Bela�nde, whom
the military had overthrown in 1968. His victory was no surprise, given
that the elections were contested by a leaderless and divided APRA,
recovering from the recent death of Haya de la Torre, and by a
fragmented left that presented what political scientist Sandra Woy
Hazelton described as a "cacophony" of candidates and parties.
Although Bela�nde was a charismatic personality, he had spent the
military years in exile, and was hopelessly out of touch with Peru's
political realities in 1980. His government stuck stubbornly to a
neoliberal, export-oriented economic model at a time when the world
recession caused the prices of Peru's major export products to plummet.
At the same time, the government fueled inflation through fiscal
expenditures on major infrastructure projects, ignoring the better
judgment of the president of the Central Reserve Bank (Banco Central de
Reservas--BCR, also known as Central Bank). Popular expectations
raised by the transition to democracy were soon frustrated.
Despite the SL's launching of activities in 1980 and its substantial
presence in Ayacucho by 1982, Bela�nde refused to take the group
seriously, dismissing them as narcoterrorists. When the government
finally realized that the SL was a substantial security threat as a
guerrilla and terrorist group, its reaction was too little, too late,
and ultimately counterproductive. The government sent special
counterinsurgency forces, the Sinchis, to the Ayacucho region, where
they were given a free hand. The repressive nature of the military
activities and the military's lack of understanding of the SL resulted
in unwarranted repression against the local population. This, if
anything, played into the SL's hands.
Natural disasters--floods and droughts--and economic decline and
triple-digit inflation heightened the negative image of a government
that was distant and detached from the population. This image was also
exacerbated by Bela�nde's continuous insistence, amid economic crisis
and the onset of guerrilla violence, that the solution to Peru's
problems was the building of the Jungle Border Highway (la carretera
marginal de la selva or la marginal), linking the Amazon
region of the country to the coast. The severity of the economic crisis
of the Bela�nde years and his government's poor public relations image
opened the door for a major shift of the political spectrum to the left.
By late 1983, Garc�a, as leader of the opposition in Congress, began to
tap the increasing support for a radical solution to Peru's problems.
Peru
Peru - The Garc�a Government, 1985-90
Peru
By 1985 Garc�a and APRA were well-positioned to win the presidential
elections. Garc�a was a charismatic orator who was convinced that he
needed to "open up" APRA in order to win the nation's vote. He
dropped all of APRA's sectarian symbols, such as the Aprista version of
the Marseillaise and its six-pointed star, and replaced them with the
popular song, "Mi Per�," and with slogans such as "my
commitment is with all Peruvians." His attacks on neoliberal
economics were directed primarily at foreign capital and the IMF, a
convenient beating board because Peru was unlikely to get any capital
inflow in the near future; he carefully avoided attacks on domestic
capital. Thus, while cultivating the image of a radical among the poor,
Garc�a also was perceived as the mal menor, or lesser
evil, by the private sector, as opposed to the Marxist left. Finally,
even conservatives recognized the need for reform in Peru by 1985, given
the increasing presence of the SL. Garc�a defeated Alfonso Barrantes of
the IU, taking 47.8 percent of the vote versus 22.2 percent for the IU.
A run-off election (required if an absolute majority is not attained)
was not held because Barrantes declined to run.
The first two years of the APRA government were a honeymoon of sorts.
Garc�a enjoyed unprecedented popularity ratings of over 75 percent,
owing in part to his populist personality and oratorical talents, and in
part to the concertaci�n strategy the government pursued. It
was highly successful as a short-term strategy for a severely depressed
economy, but obviously had its limits as a long-term plan. The private
sector, meanwhile, gave Garc�a and his concertaci�n strategy
cautious support.
By mid-1987 it was clear that concertaci�n had run its
course, and a change of emphasis was necessary. At the same time, Garc�a
was also under pressure from the left and from some sectors within his
own party to implement more radical structural change. In June he
suffered a defeat within the party when his main rival, former prime
minister Luis Alva Castro, was elected president of the Chamber of
Deputies. Garc�a at this point opted for a radical measure that was
intended to retake the political initiative from his rivals. In his
annual independence day address on July 28, 1987, Garc�a announced the
surprise nationalization of the nation's banks. The measure was designed
with a small group of advisers in the two weeks prior to its
announcement, and few members of the APRA party or government were
consulted. For example, the octogenarian vice president of the republic,
Luis Alberto S�nchez, learned of the measure just prior to Garc�a's
announcement, and he was told by none other than former president Bela�nde.
The measure in and of itself may not have been all that significant
because only 20 percent of the nation's banks remained in private hands
in 1987. However, the manner in which Garc�a presented it clearly
indicated a change of political course. His rhetoric pitted the rich,
lazy bankers against the poor, exploited people, and from that point on
he began to speak of the "bad" capitalists. He launched a
tirade of attacks on the domestic private sector, using precisely the
kind of rhetoric he had avoided in the campaign and for the first two
years of his presidency.
The private sector's fragile trust in Garc�a and the historically
confrontational APRA was undermined. This was exacerbated by the manner
in which APRA silently supported the measure, and those members of the
party who spoke out against the measure were expelled. Foremost among
these was the influential senator Jorge Torres Vallejo, who ironically
was the person who launched Garc�a's candidacy as secretary general of
APRA in 1983.
The measure marked the beginning of the end. Political polarization
set in, and the government increasingly lost coherence. The then
moribund right found a cause and a candidate for its renovation, and
latched onto the protest movement against the measure that was launched
by Mario Vargas Llosa and his Liberty Movement. The left had no real
cause to support the measure or to ally with the highly sectarian APRA.
The poor, who lacked savings accounts, were hardly likely to rally to
Garc�a's cause. The private sector withdrew its plans for investment as
economic policy-making fell prey to political infighting in APRA and to
Garc�a's own erratic behavior. In September 1988, the time when an
austerity package was announced, Garc�a went into hiding in the palace
and did not appear for a period of over thirty days.
Although reserves had run out, the government continued to maintain
unrealistic subsidies, such as the five-tier exchange rate, funded by a
growing fiscal deficit, which fueled hyperinflation. This was
exacerbated by the constant resource drain from inefficient state
enterprises, whose bureaucracy increased markedly during the APRA
government. The combination of hyperinflation and public sector debts
that could not be paid resulted in a state that virtually ceased to
function. Living standards dropped dramatically as real wages were
eroded by inflation, and services for the public, such as public
hospital staff, were curbed markedly. By the end of the APRA government,
shortages of the most basic goods, such as water and electricity, were
the norm. Economist Jeffrey D. Sachs, on a visit to Lima in June 1990,
described the country as "slipping away from the rest of the
world."
To make matters worse, a host of corruption scandals involving APRA
became publicly evident at this point. The atmosphere of chaos and
economic disorder, the virtual nonfunctioning of the state, and the
perception of corruption in the highest ranks of government and law
enforcement all served to discredit state institutions and political
parties, particularly APRA.
Economic decline was accompanied by a dramatic surge in insurgent and
criminal violence. In addition to violence from the SL and MRTA, there
was a rise in death squads linked to the government and armed forces.
These included the Rodrigo Franco Command. Deaths from political
violence in the 1980s approached 20,000, and in 1990 alone there were
3,384, a figure greater than that from Lebanon's civil war that year.
Peru also ranked as the country with the highest number of
disappearances in the world. In the context of political violence and
economic disorder, criminal violence also surged.
Peru
Peru - The 1990 Campaign and Elections
Peru
Although Alberto Fujimori was elected by a large popular margin, he
had no organized or institutionalized base of support. There were
countless theories as to why Fujimori was able to rise from virtual
anonymity to the national presidency in the course of three months. More
than anything else, the Fujimori tsunami, as it was called, was a
rejection of all established political parties: the right, despite its
refurbished image; the squabbling and hopelessly divided far left; and
certainly the left-of-center APRA because of its disastrous performance
in government. Fujimori was able to capture the traditional support base
of APRA: small entrepreneurial groups and those sectors of the middle
class for whom APRA was no longer an acceptable alternative, but for
whom the conservative Fredemo was also unacceptable. In addition,
Fujimori's success was attributed largely to a great deal of support at
the grassroots level.
After serving as a UNA rector and host of a popular television
program called "Concertando," Fujimori entered politics in
1989, running on a simple, if vague, platform of "Work, Honesty,
and Technology." His appeal had several dimensions. First, his
experience as an engineer, rather than a politician, and his lack of
ties to any of the established parties clearly played into his favor.
APRA's incoherent conduct of government had led to an economic crisis of
unprecedented proportions; at the same time, the polarized political
debate and the derogatory mudslinging that characterized the electoral
campaign did not seem to offer any positive solutions. The right
preached free-market ideology with a fervor and made little attempt to
appeal to the poor. The left was hopelessly divided and unable to
provide a credible alternative to the failure of "heterodox"
economic policy. Thus, not only APRA was discredited, but so were all
established politicians.
In addition, and key to his popular appeal, were Fujimori's nonelite
origins as the son of Japanese immigrants. His Japanese ties also
aroused some hopes, whether realistic or not, that in the event of his
victory the Japanese would extend substantial amounts of aid to Peru. He
capitalized on Vargas Llosa's lack of appeal to the poor by promising
not to implement a painful "shock" economic adjustment program
to end inflation, and with slogans like "un presidente como t�"
("a president like you"). The claim of this first-generation
Japanese-Peruvian that he was just like the majority in a predominantly mestizo
and native American nation seemed less than credible, and
his vague promises of "gradually" ending hyperinflation seemed
glibly unrealistic. Nevertheless, his message was much more palatable to
an already severely impoverished population than Vargas Llosa's more
realistic but bluntly phrased calls for a shock austerity program to end
inflation. "El shock" had become a common term in the
electoral campaign and among all sectors of society.
Fujimori's success was also enhanced by his rather eclectic political
team, Cambio '90, which was extremely active in campaigning at the
grassroots level. Cambio had an appeal at this level precisely because
it was an unknown entity, and was not affiliated with the traditional
political system.
In the first round of elections, Vargas Llosa attained 28.2 percent
of the vote; Fujimori, 24.3 percent; the APRA, 19.6 percent; IU, 7.1
percent; and ASI, 4.1 percent. Null and blank votes were 14.4 percent of
the total. It was then clear that the left and APRA would back Fujimori,
if for no other reason than to defeat Vargas Llosa in the second round.
Vargas Llosa was seen as a representative of the traditional,
conservative elite, and thus was unacceptable for ideological reasons.
In Luis Alva Castro's words to APRA: "Compa�eros
(partners), our support for Fujimori is a given, but there is no need to
make an institutional commitment." A similar stance was taken by
the left.
The support of the left and APRA virtually guaranteed Fujimori's
victory in the second round, but it by no means signified an organized
or institutionalized support base, either inside or outside Congress,
which presented a formidable obstacle for an already uncertain future
for the Fujimori government. The electoral campaign, meanwhile, was
waged in extremely negative and ad hominem terms, and took on both
racial and class confrontational overtones. It became a struggle between
the "rich whites" and the "poor Indians,"
exacerbating the existing polarization in the system. The political
mudslinging and personal attacks, first by Fredemo against APRA and
President Garc�a, and then between the Fujimori and Vargas Llosa teams,
offended the average voter.
The conduct of the 1990 electoral campaign, in conjunction with the
prolonged period of political polarization that preceded it, severely
undermined faith in the established system and the political parties and
leaders that were a part of it. This, more than anything else, played
into the hands of Fujimori, and was responsible for his victory. In the
second round, he attained 56.5 percent of the vote over 33.9 percent for
Vargas Llosa on June 10, 1990.
The Fujimori government came to power without a coherent team of
advisers, a program for governing, or any indication of who would hold
the key positions in the government. Fujimori's advisers were from
diverse sides of the political spectrum, and he made no clear choices
among them, as they themselves admitted. At the same time, he made it
clear that he would re-establish relations with the international
financial community, and that he was not interested in a radical
economic program. How he would reconcile those goals, in the context of
hyperinflation, with his promise not to implement a shock-stabilization
plan was the cause of a great deal of uncertainty.
The 1990 electoral results reflected a total dissatisfaction and lack
of faith on the part of the populace in traditional politicians and
parties. Fredemo's dogmatic and heavy-handed campaign was partially to
blame for undermining that faith, as were a succession of weak or inept
governments for the past several decades. Yet, in the short-term, the
disastrous failure of APRA, the country's only well-institutionalized
political party, was most directly to blame. The results of the 1990
elections merely demonstrated the exacerbation that occurred from 1985
to 1990 of a preexisting breach between state and society in Peru. The
rejection of traditional parties did not necessarily reflect a rejection
of the democratic system. Instead, it reflected an ongoing evolution of
participation occurring outside the realm of traditional political
institutions, as well as the increased importance of autonomous local
groups and the informal economy.
The 1990 electoral results also indicated a crisis of representation.
Political parties play a fundamental representative role in virtually
all consolidated democracies; their utility in formulating and
channeling demands in both directions--from society to state and state
to society--is an irreplaceable one. In Peru, as in many developing
countries, demands on the state for basic services had clearly outpaced
its ability to respond. Thus, the role of parties in channeling those
demands, and--through the party platform or doctrine--indicating their
relative importance, was critical. How Fujimori would govern a
fragmented and polarized political system without an institutionalized
party base remained unclear at best.
Peru
Peru - The Fujimori Government
Peru
In 1990 Peru's political spectrum and party system were polarized to
an unprecedented degree. In addition, the vote for Fujimori was to a
large extent a vote against the shock stabilization plan that Vargas
Llosa had proposed to implement. After less than a month in government,
however, Fujimori was convinced--both by domestic advisers and prominent
members in the international financial community--that he had to
implement an orthodox shock program to stabilize inflation and generate
enough revenue so that the government could operate. During his visits
to the United States and Japan in July 1990, it was made very clear to
Fujimori that unless Peru adopted a relatively orthodox economic
strategy and stabilized hyperinflation, there would be no possibility of
Peru's reentry into the international financial community, and therefore
no international aid. At this point, Fujimori opted for an orthodox
approach and appointed Juan Carlos Hurtado Miller as minister of economy
and prime minister. Later that month, many of Fujimori's original
advisers, who were heterodox economists, left the Cambio team. Thus, on
August 8, 1990, Fujimori implemented precisely the program that he had
campaigned against.
The shock program was more extreme than even the most orthodox IMF
economist was recommending at the time. Plans for liberalization of the
trading system and for privatization of several state industries were
made for the near future. Overnight, Lima became a city which had, in
the words of several observers, "Bangladesh salaries with Tokyo
prices."
Despite widespread fears that the measures would cause popular
unrest, reaction was surprisingly calm for several reasons. First of
all, the measures were so extreme that they made day-to-day economic
survival the primary concern of the majority of the population,
including the middle class. Taking time to protest was an unaffordable
luxury. Second, street protest and violence were increasingly associated
with insurrectionary groups and political violence, with which the
average Peruvian had no desire to be associated. Third, the benefits
from ending hyperinflation and recovering some sort of economic
stability were immediately evident to Peruvians at all levels, even the
very poor. Even several months after the shock, the most popular man in
Peru was the architect of the program, Hurtado Miller. Although
Fujimori's popularity suffered a decline after his first few months in
office, it was not necessarily a result of the economic program.
Finally, and perhaps most importantly, most people voted for Fujimori
not only because of his vague promises, but also because of the
perception that, unlike Vargas Llosa, he was much more a man of the
people. Thus, his implementing an "antipopular" economic
program was far more acceptable politically than Vargas Llosa's doing
virtually the same thing.
Prospects for the Fujimori Government
In some ways, these trends signified positive prospects for the
Fujimori government. The degree of consensus on the economic approach
was remarkable for a country as polarized both ideologically and
politically as Peru. Fujimori's original cabinet was an eclectic and
pragmatic one, which included members of virtually all political camps.
Despite this diversity, a consensus eventually emerged.
Yet, there were some extremely worrisome trends as well. In addition
to the economic shock program, the government promised a social
emergency program to protect the poorest by providing temporary food aid
and employment. However, no such program materialized over a year into
the government. Although this was explained in part by resource
constraints, it was also explained, in large part, by lack of political
will, as no one person had any bureaucratic responsibility for the needs
of the poor.
In other countries implementing shock economic programs, temporary
measures to compensate the poor have played important social welfare and
political roles in making economic reform more acceptable and viable. In
addition, they have played an important role in providing foreign donors
with a single bureaucratic entity through which to channel necessary
aid. The lack of such a program on any significant scale in Peru was
unfortunate, as socioeconomic indicators had already deteriorated
markedly prior to the adjustment program, and in areas where the threat
of increasing insurrectionary violence was a realistic one.
Despite the new political dynamics, the tradition of centralized and
authoritarian presidential leadership remained intact. Fujimori had a
strong tendency to attempt to control his ministers and to appoint
loyalists. Some of the most talented and independent-minded ministers
left the cabinet after a few months because Fujimori undermined their
authority. These included Carlos Amat y Le�n y Ch�vez, the minister of
agriculture; Gloria Helfer Palacios, the minister of education; Carlos
Vidal Layseca, the minister of public health; and even Prime Minister
Hurtado himself in March 1991. After Hurtado's resignation, Fujimori
separated the positions of prime minister and economics minister,
presumably so that he could have more relative control than he had with
the popular Hurtado. Also telling was Fujimori's insistence on the
appointment of Jorge Ch�vez Alvarez, a young and relatively
inexperienced doctoral student, as president of the Central Bank,
despite the misgivings of virtually all respected economists. Ch�vez
was seen as a Fujimori loyalist through whom the president could
manipulate and control the Central Bank.
In addition, Fujimori's need to make an "unholy" alliance
with APRA in Congress to get measures passed acted as a barrier to the
reform of the state sector. APRA had been the only political force to
back the Ch�vez appointment, and it was widely perceived that Fujimori
would have a political price to pay for that backing in the future.
Indicative of the price was a debate within the Ministry of Education,
in which Fujimori supported APRA against his own minister, Gloria
Helfer. She was trying to trim the size of the ministry, which had grown
to unrealistic proportions during the APRA government owing to its
filling of posts for party reasons. The row resulted in the resignation
of Helfer and a stalling of the reform of the public education sector.
The age-old tradition of centralism also prevailed. For financial
reasons and lack of political will, the regionalization process was
stalled. Under existing conditions, regional governments were little
more than politicized bureaucracies.
Finally, and most worrisome, was the resurgence of another tradition
in Peru--government reliance on the military for power. Fujimori lacked
any institutionalized base and had cultivated strong ties with the
military by granting it what it wished, as demonstrated by his attempt
to legalize its impunity through Decree Law 171.
There are many plausible explanations for the autogolpe. The
most significant one, which has been noted here, was Fujimori's lack of
organized or party-based support, resulting in his increasing reliance
on the armed forces and on rule by decree. By early 1992, APRA stopped
supporting Fujimori and coalesced the opposition in Congress, somewhat
ironically, under the leadership targeted by government repression after
the coup, indicative of the extent to which the government felt
threatened by APRA opposition. In March there had been a politically
damaging scandal among Fujimori's close circle of advisors, in which his
wife publicly accused his brother, his closest advisor, of misuse of
foreign aid donations. Another of Fujimori's close advisors, Vladimiro
Montesinos Torres, the de facto head of the National Intelligence
Service (Servicio de Inteligencia Nacional--SIN), had been pressuring
the president for some time to free the counterinsurgency struggle from
judicial interference. This coincided with a major SL assault on the
city of Lima. At the same time, relations with the United States were at
an all-time low owing to disagreements over counternarcotics strategy,
possibly leading Fujimori to conclude that there was not all that much
to lose from jeopardizing relations with the United States.
There was the possibility that Fujimori would abide by the timetable
that he set out and reinstate the parliament one year later. Yet, the
undermining of the constitutional system had farreaching costs. First,
democratic development is not attained by rescinding the constitution
and the institutions of government whenever a crisis is perceived.
Second, Fujimori had been able to pass virtually all the laws pertaining
to his economic program by the decree powers awarded to him by the
Congress; continuing the economic program was not the reason for its
closing. If anything, the program was seriously jeopardized by the
international isolation that the coup precipitated, owing to the
critical role that international financial support played. Third, the
elimination of important constitutional rights, such as habeas corpus,
for over a year was likely to result in a worsening of Peru's already
poor human rights record. The coup also played into the SL's strategy of
provoking a coup in order to polarize society into military and
nonmilitary camps. Finally, a yes or no plebiscite is a tool that has
been used to establish popular support by a number of dictators,
including Benito Mussolini and Ferdinand Marcos. Given short-term
popular support for almost any kind of drastic solution to Peru's many
problems, there was a very high risk that Fujimori and the military
would use the plebiscite as a tool to justify further undermining Peru's
constitutional system.
Peru was clearly in a critical situation, where extreme economic
deterioration and spiraling political violence had to be reversed as a
prerequisite to democratic consolidation. Neither was a simple process,
and there was no guarantee that Peru's fragile institutions would
survive the challenge; they were jeopardized severely by the measures
taken on April 5, 1992. In the short term, in addition to the rapid
restoration of constitutional democracy, an important first step would
be a more visible and tangible commitment to the poorest sectors, which
were suffering the most from the economic program, had the smallest
margin for deterioration in their living standards, and were the primary
focus of insurgent groups as well. The outbreak of a cholera epidemic in
1991 was a prime example of the extent to which social welfare
infrastructure and other needs of the poor had been sorely neglected for
several years. Otherwise, despite all good intentions on the economic
front, the social peace necessary to reestablish and consolidate
democratic government would be unattainable.
Peru
Peru - FOREIGN RELATIONS
Peru
The emergence of highly nationalistic forces in Peru's political
system during the 1960s was accompanied by a marked shift in the
nation's approach to foreign relations. A desire to alter Peru's
traditionally passive role in foreign affairs, which had led to what was
perceived as inordinate influence by foreign countries--and particularly
the United States--in the political and economic life of the nation,
became a central objective of the Velasco Alvarado regime. During the
1970s, Peru's military government sought an independent, nonaligned
course in its foreign relations that paralleled the mixed socioeconomic
policies of its domestic reform program. Diplomatic dealings and foreign
trade were thus diversified; official contacts with the nations of the
communist world, Western Europe, and Asia were significantly expanded
during the decade, while the United States' official presence receded
from its once predominant position. Multilateral relations, particularly
with Latin American neighbors that shared economic and political
interests common to many Third World nations, also assumed a new
importance.
Peru's foreign policy initiatives were undertaken in part as an
effort to gain international support for the military government's
experiment in "revolution from above." The initial success of
many programs of the military government brought it considerable
international prestige and thus, during the early 1970s, Peru became a
leading voice for Third World nations. As the fortunes of the Peruvian
experiment fell during the late 1970s, however, its international
profile receded markedly. The Bela�nde government deemphasized further
the nonaligned stance of the military government while working toward
closer relationships with the United States and the nations of Latin
America.
Foreign Relations Under Garc�a
Traditionally, Peru was an active and initiating member of regional
multilateral organizations, such as the Andean Pact. Yet, the nation's
economic crisis and Garc�a's loss of prestige, both within and outside
Peru, forced the country to turn inward and abandon its high-profile
stance. Peru's stance on the international front was influenced to a
great extent by the rise and fall of Garc�a's anti-imperialist
strategy. His antiimperialist and anti-IMF rhetoric, as well as his
unilateral limitation of debt payments, placed a major strain on
relations with the international financial community and the United
States in particular.
Under Bela�nde, a de facto moratorium on debt service already had
existed. By 1985 it was clear that no new capital was headed in Peru's
direction, and that the country could not afford to pay its debt. Garc�a
took an openly confrontational approach, with the hope that the rest of
Latin America would follow. At the time, there were speculations that
the threat posed by Garc�a was one reason the Ronald Reagan
administration (1981-89) presented the Baker debt-reduction plan in
October 1985.
Although Garc�a's debt policy limited payments to 10 percent of
export earnings, in reality the government paid approximately 20 percent
for the first few years, but then stopped making any payments at all.
Garc�a's insistence on maintaining a confrontational stance, even after
its political utility was exhausted, was counterproductive. On several
occasions, accords in principle with the IMF were prepared with
representatives of the APRA government and the IMF, and then cancelled
at the last minute by Garc�a. Garc�a's stance initially had some
appeal among Third World debtor countries, and a few even followed his
example. As the limits to Peru's economic strategy became evident both
at home and abroad, however, his stubborn adherence to the policy became
the subject of ridicule rather than respect. Peru was declared
ineligible for IMF funds in August 1986, and was threatened with
expulsion from the organization in October 1989.
Garc�a also made heightening Peru's visibility in the Nonaligned
Movement and in the Socialist International a priority. Ties were
expanded with a number of Third World socialist nations, including
Angola, Mozambique, and Zimbabwe; and Garc�a took a staunchly
pro-Sandinista position in the Central American conflict. Improving
Peru's relations with its neighbors, particularly Ecuador and Chile, was
also a priority early on. Although some productive discussions were held
with Ecuador, including a historic visit by Peru's minister of finance
to Quito in October 1985, progress was limited by competition with both
the Ecuadorian and Chilean military establishments. Garc�a's attempts
to curb military expenditures were not reciprocated by Chile, for
example.
As the economic crisis in Peru deepened, meanwhile, Garc�a took a
lower profile stance on the foreign policy front. Relations with the
United States remained remarkably good despite Garc�a's stances on debt
and on Central America. This was in part owing to Washington's desire to
maintain good bilateral relations because of the threat of instability
caused by the SL. Thus, foreign aid flows were maintained despite Peru's
violation of the Brooke Alexander Amendment, which makes a country
ineligible for United States aid if it is over a year late in repaying
military assistance. Garc�a's willingness to collaborate, at least
rhetorically, on the drug issue, in sharp contrast to his stance on
debt, helped ameliorate relations. Finally, relations were maintained
owing to a good working relationship between United States ambassador
Alexander Watson and President Garc�a.
Peru's relations with its neighbors were strained also by the extent
of the economic crisis and the cholera epidemic. In late 1989, over
6,000 Peruvians crossed the border to Chile in order to buy bread, which
was scarce and expensive in Peru. Chile's dictator Augusto Pinochet
Ugarte (1973-90), when campaigning prior to the 1988 plebiscite, warned
of the dangers of populist democracy by pointing out neighboring Peru.
Contraband trade along the Chilean and Ecuadorian borders at times has
been a contentious issue. Another concern were the thousands of
Peruvians emigrating to neighboring countries seeking employment. The
fear of the spread of subversion over neighboring borders also worried
Peru's neighbors, a concern heightened by events such as the SL's
assassination of a Peruvian military attach� in La Paz, and by the
MRTA's support of the 19th of April Movement (Movimiento 19 de
Abril--M-19), a Colombian guerrilla group.
Foreign Relations Under Fujimori
Fujimori set out to repair Peru's foreign relations, particularly
with its creditors. He campaigned on, and was committed to, a strategy
of "reinsertion" into the international financial community.
This commitment forced him to change his adherence to
"gradualist" economics and to open dialogue with the major
multilateral institutions.
Peru's foreign relations situation changed dramatically with the
April 5 self-coup. The international community's reaction was
appropriately negative. Most international financial organizations
delayed planned or projected loans, and the United States government
suspended all aid other than humanitarian assistance. Germany and Spain
also suspended aid to Peru. Venezuela broke off diplomatic relations,
and Argentina withdrew its ambassador. The coup threatened the entire
economic recovery strategy of reinsertion. In addition, the withdrawal
of aid by key members of Peru's support group made the process of
clearing arrears with the IMF virtually impossible. Yet, despite
international condemnation, Fujimori refused to rescind the suspension
of constitutional government, and the armed forces reasserted their
support for the measures.
Even before the coup, relations with the United States were strained,
because they were dominated by the drug issue and Fujimori's reluctance
to sign an accord that would increase United States and Peruvian
military efforts in eradicating coca fields. Although Fujimori
eventually signed the accord in May 1991 in order to get desperately
needed aid, the disagreements did little to enhance bilateral relations.
The Peruvians saw drugs as primarily a United States problem, and the
least of their concerns, given the economic crisis, the SL, and the
outbreak of cholera.
The cholera outbreak at first resulted in neighboring countries'
banning Peruvian food imports, further straining relations. Even after
the ban was lifted for certain products, fear of the spread of cholera
was confirmed by cases reported in Colombia, Ecuador, Chile, and Brazil.
By the early 1990s, economic trends in Latin America were moving
increasingly toward free-trade agreements with the United States and
regional market integration, such as the Southern Cone Common Market
(Mercado Com�n del Sur-- Mercosur). Although the Andean Pact agreed to
form a common market in late 1990, Peru's role, owing to the extent and
nature of its crisis, remained marginal, at least in the short term.
Fujimori was so overwhelmed with domestic problems early into his
government, moreover, that he was unable to attend the Group of Eight
meeting in late 1990.
Although Peru could have been eligible for special drugrelated
assistance and trade arrangements with the United States under the
Andean Initiative, Peruvian-United States relations were hardly smooth
on the drug front during Fujimori's first year in office. Peru's
eligibility for debt reduction and grants for investment-related reforms
under the George H.W. Bush administration's Enterprise for the Americas
Initiative, meanwhile, were restricted by its arrears with multilateral
credit agencies and private banks.
On the debt front, relations with international institutions were
improving, and after six months of negotiations, Peru was able to obtain
the US$800-million bridge loan required to re-establish its borrowing
eligibility from the IMF. Yet, Peru still had to pay US$600 million to
international creditors. It seemed that for the foreseeable future, any
credit inflows would merely be recycled to pay existing debts and
arrears. Prior to the coup of April 5, 1992, however, almost all of the
US$1.3 billion necessary to clear arrears with the IMF had been
attained.
Peru had established a strong military relationship with the Soviets
and Eastern Europe during the Velasco years, and was the Soviets'
largest military client on the continent in the 1970s. Owing to a
reliance on Soviet military equipment, this relationship has continued,
although Peru has diversified its source of supply of weapons to
countries ranging from France to North Korea. In addition, like its
relationship with Cuba, Peru's relationship with the Soviets is certain
to diminish in importance as both countries turn inward to deal with
domestic crises and economic rather than strategic issues dominate the
agenda. Reflecting this change is a new importance placed on relations
with the United States and also with Japan, largely because of
Fujimori's heritage and the emphasis that he himself placed on the
Japanese role during the electoral campaign. More than anything else,
Peru's foreign relations were expected to be dominated by the nation's
need for foreign aid, capital, and credit, all of which hinged on the
republic's solving its internal economic problems, cooperating with the
United States on the drug issue, and dealing with the challenge from
insurgent groups. Additionally, most of the international community
remained unwilling to provide credit or aid until democratic government
was restored.
Peru
Peru - Bibliography
Peru
Alexander, Robert, ed. Aprismo: The Ideas and Doctrines of
V�ctor Ra�l Haya de la Torre. Kent: Kent State University
Press, 1973.
Andrien, Kenneth J. Crisis and Decline: The Viceroyalty of Peru
in the Seventeenth Century. Albuquerque: University of
New Mexico Press, 1985.
Anna, Timothy E. The Fall of the Royal Government in Peru.
Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1979.
Arz�ns de Ors�a y Vela, Bartolom�. Tales of Potos�. (Ed.,
R.C. Padden.) Providence: Brown University Press, 1975.
Bakewell, Peter. Silver and Entrepreneurship in Seventeenth-
Century Potos�: The Life and Times of Antonio L�pez de
Quiroga. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press,
1988.
Becker, David G. The New Bourgeoisie and the Limits of
Dependency: Mining, Class, and Power in "Revolutionary"
Peru. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1983.
Bertram, Geoffrey. "Peru 1930-1962." Pages 385-450 in Leslie
Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin
America, 8. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Bethell, Leslie (ed.). The Cambridge History of Latin
America, 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984.
------. The Cambridge History of Latin America, 5.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.
------. The Cambridge History of Latin America, 8.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.
Blanchard, Peter. The Origins of the Peruvian Labor Movement,
1883-1919. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press,
1982.
Blondet M., Cecilia. Las mujeres y el poder: Una historia de
Villa El Salvador. Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos,
1991.
Bonilla, Heraclio. "Peru and Bolivia." Pages 539-582 in Leslie
Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin
America, 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984.
Booth, David, and Bernardo Sorj (eds.). Military Reformism and
Social Classes: The Peruvian Experience, 1968-80. New
York: St. Martin's Press, 1983.
Bourque, Susan C., and Kay B. Warren. Women of the Andes:
Patriarchy and Social Change in Two Peruvian Towns. Ann
Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1981.
Bowser, Frederick P. The African Slave in Colonial Peru.
Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1974.
Brown, Kendall W. Bourbons and Brandy: Imperial Reform in
Eighteenth-Century Arequipa. Albuquerque: University of
New Mexico Press, 1986.
Burga, Manuel, and Alberto Flores Galindo. Apogeo y cr�sis de
la Rep�blica aristocr�tica. (3d ed.) Lima: Ediciones
Rikchay Peru, 1984.
Burkholder, Mark A. Politics of a Colonial Career:
Jos� Baqu�jano and the Audiencia of Lima, 2d ed.
Wilmington, Delaware: Scholarly Resources Books, 1990.
Burkholder, Mark A., and Lyman L. Johnson. Colonial Latin
America. New York: Oxford University Press, 1990.
Cameron, Ian. The Kingdom of the Sun God: A History of the
Andes and Their People. New York: Facts on File, 1990.
Campbell, Leon G. The Military and Society in Colonial Peru,
1750-1810. Philadelphia: American Philosophical Society,
1978.
Chavarr�a, Jes�s. Jos� Carlos Mari�tegui and the Rise of Modern
Peru, 1890-1930. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico
Press, 1979.
Clayton, Larry. Grace: W.R. Grace, the Formative Years, 1850-
1930. Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1985.
Cole, Jeffery A. Potos� Mita, 1573-1700: Compulsory Indian
Labor in the Andes. Stanford: Stanford University Press,
1985.
Collier, David. Squatters and Oligarchs: Authoritarian Rule and
Policy Change in Peru. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press, 1976.
Contreras, Carlos. Mineros y campesinos en los Andes: Mercado
laboral y economic compesina en la Sierra Central, siglo
XIX. Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, 1988.
Cook, Noble David. Demographic Collapse: Indian Peru, 1520-
1620. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.
Cotler, Julio. "Peru since 1960." Pages 451-508 in Leslie Bethell
(ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin America, 8.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Cushner, Nicholas P. Lords of the Land: Sugar, Wine, and Jesuit
Estates of Coastal Peru, 1600-1767. Albany: State
University of New York Press, 1980.
Davies, Keith A. Landowners in Colonial Peru. Austin:
University of Texas Press, 1984.
Degregori, Carlos Iv�n. El nacimiento de Sendero Luminoso.
Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, 1990.
De la Vega, Garcilasco. Royal Commentaries of the Incas and
General History of Peru. Austin: University of Texas
Press, 1987.
Derpich, Wilma, Jos� Luis Huiza, and Cecilia Israel. Lima a�os
30: Salarios y costo de vida de la clase trabajadora.
Lima: Fundaci�n Friedrich Ebert, 1985.
De Soto, Hernando. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in
the Third World. New York: Harper and Row, 1990.
Deustua, Jos�. La miner�a peruana y la iniciaci�n de la
Rep�blica, 1820-1840. Lima: Instituto de Estudios
Peruanos, 1986.
Deustua, Jos�, and Jos� Luis R�nique. Intelectuales,
indigenismo y descentralismo en el Per�. Cusco:
"Bartolom� de las Casas," 1984.
DeWind, Josh. Peasants Become Miners: The Evolution of
Industrial Mining Systems in Peru, 1902-1974. New York:
Garland, 1987.
Dietz, Henry A. Poverty and Problem-Solving under Military
Rule: The Urban Poor in Lima, Peru. Austin: University of
Texas Press, 1980.
Dobyns, Henry F., and Paul L. Doughty. Peru: A Cultural
History. New York: Oxford University Press, 1976.
Dore, Elizabeth. The Peruvian Mining Industry: Growth,
Stagnation, and Crisis. Boulder, Colorado: Westview
Press, 1988.
Drake, Paul. The Money Doctor in the Andes: The Kemmerer
Missions, 1923-1933. Durham: Duke University Press, 1989.
Duviols, Pierre. La lutte contre les religions autochtones dans
le P�rou colonial: "L'extirpation de l'idolatrie entre 1532 et
1660". Lima: Instituto Franc�s de Estudios Andinos, 1971.
Economic Intelligence Unit. Country Report: Peru, Boliva
[London], No. 1, 1992.
------. Country Report: Peru, Bolivia, No. 2, 1992.
Eckstein, Susan. "The Impact of Revolution on Social Welfare in
Latin America." Pages 280-306 in Jack Goldstone (ed.),
Revolutions: Theoretical, Comparative, and Historical
Studies. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1986.
El Comercio [Lima], April 12, 1992, F20.
Espinoza Soriano, Waldemar. La destrucci�n del imperio de los
Incas: La rivalidad pol�tica y se�orial de los Curacazgos
andinos. Lima: Retablo de Papel Ediciones, 1977.
------. Los incas: Econom�a, sociedad y estado en la era del
Tahuantinsuyo. La Victoria, Peru: Amaru Editores, 1987.
Figueroa, Adolfo. Capitalist Development and the Peasant
Economy of Peru. Cambridge [Cambrigeshire]: Cambridge
University Press, 1984.
Fisher, John R. Government and Society in Colonial Peru: The
Intendant System, 1784-1814. London, 1970.
------. Silver Mines and Silver Miners in Colonial Peru, 1776-
1824. Liverpool: University of Liverpool, 1977.
Fitzgerald, Edmund V.K. The Political Economy of Peru, 1956-
1978: Economic Development and the Restructuring of
Capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979.
Flores Galindo, Alberto. Buscando un inca: Identidad y utopia
en los Andes. Lima: Instituto de Apoyo Agrario, 1987.
Flores Galindo, Alberto (ed.). Independencia y revoluci�n,
1780-1840. (2 vols.) Lima: Instituto Nacional de Cultura,
1987.
------. T�pac Amaru II-1780: Sociedad colonial y sublevaciones
populares. Lima: Retablo de Papel Ediciones, 1976.
Gardiner, C. Harvey. The Japanese and Peru, 1873-1973.
Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, 1975.
Gilbert, Dennis. La oligarqu�a peruana: Historia de tres
familias. Lima: Editorial Horizonte, 1982.
Glave, Luis Miguel. Trajinantes-caminos ind�genos en la
sociedad colonial siglos XVI-XVII. Lima: Instituto de
Apoyo Agrario, 1989.
Glave Testino, Luis Miguel, and Mar�a Isabel Remy. Estructura
agraria y vida rural en una regi�n andina: Ollantaytambo entre
los siglos XVI-XIX. Cusco: Centro de Estudios Rurales
Andinos "Bartolom� de las Casas," 1983.
Goldstone, Jack (ed.). Revolutions: Theoretical, Comparative,
and Historical Studies. New York: Harcourt Brace
Jovanovich, 1986.
Gonzales, Michael J. Plantation Agriculture and Social Control
in Northern Peru, 1875-1933. Austin: University of Texas
Press, 1985.
Gootenberg, Paul E. Between Silver and Guano: Commercial Policy
and the State in Postindependence Peru. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1989.
Gorman, Stephen M. (ed.). Post-Revolutionary Peru: The Politics
of Transformation (Westview Special Studies on Latin
America and the Caribbean.). Boulder, Colorado: Westview
Press, 1982.
Gorriti Ellenbogen, Gustavo. Sendero: Historia de la guerra
milenaria en el Per�, 1. Lima: Editorial Apoyo, 1990.
Haya de la Torre, V�ctor Ra�l. Obras completas. (7 vols.)
Lima: Editorial Mejia Baca, 1976-77.
Hemming, John. The Conquest of the Incas. New York:
Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1970.
Huam�n Poma de Ayala, Felipe. Letter to a King: A Peruvian
Chief's Account of Life under the Incas and under Spanish
Rule. New York: Dutton, 1978.
Huayhuaca, Jos� Carlos. Mart�n Chambi: Fot�grafo, Cusco 1920-
1950. Lima: Banco de Lima, 1989.
Jacobsen, Nils P. Mirages of Transition: The Peruvian
Altiplano, 1780-1930. Berkeley: University of California
Press, 1993.
Jacobsen, Nils P., and Hans-J�rgen Puhle (eds.). The Economies
of Mexico and Peru during the Late Colonial Period, 1760-
1810. Berlin: Colloquium Verlag, 1986.
Juan, Jorge, and Antonio de Ulloa. Discourse and Political
Reflections on the Kingdoms of Peru. Norman: University
of Oklahoma Press, 1978.
K�psoli Escudero, Wilfredo. Los movimientos campesinos en el
Per� 1879-1965. Lima: Delva Editores, 1977.
Keith, Robert G. Conquest and Agrarian Change: The Emergence of
the Hacienda System on the Peruvian Coast. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 1976.
Kendall, Ann. Everyday Life of the Incas. New York: Dorset
Press, 1989.
Klaiber, Jeffrey L. The Catholic Church in Peru, 1821-1985: A
Social History. Washington: Catholic University of
America Press, 1992.
------. Religion and Revolution in Peru, 1824-1976. Notre
Dame: University of Notre Dame Press, 1977.
Klar�n, Peter F. "The Indian Question in Latin America: Peru's
Great Divide." The Wilson Quarterly 15, No. 3,
Summer, 1990, 23-32.
------. Modernization, Dislocation, and Aprismo: Origins of the
Peruvian Aprista Party, 1870-1930. Austin: University of
Texas Press, 1973.
------. "Origins of Modern Peru, 1850-1930." Pages 587-640 in
Leslie Bethell (ed.), Cambridge History of Latin
America, 5. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.
Kristal, Efrain. The Andes Viewed from the City: Literary and
Political Discourse on the Indian in Peru, 1848-1930. New
York: Peter Lang, 1987.
Kuczynski, Pedro-Pablo. Peruvian Democracy under Economic
Stress: An Account of the Bela�nde Administration, 1963-
1968. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977.
Laite, Julian. Industrial Development and Migrant Labour in
Latin America. Austin: University of Texas Press, 1981.
Lee, Rensselaer W. The White Labyrinth: Cocaine and Political
Power. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Books,
1989.
Lockhart, James. The Men of Cajamarca: A Social and
Biographical Study of the First Conquerors of Peru.
(Latin American Monographs, No. 27.) Austin: University of
Texas Press, 1972.
------. Spanish Peru, 1532-1566: A Colonial Society.
Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1968.
Loveman, Brian, and Thomas M. Davies, Jr. (eds.). The Politics
of Antipolitics: The Military in Latin America. (2d ed.)
University of Nebraska Press, 1989.
Lumbreras, Luis Guillermo, and Carlos Aran�bar (eds.). Nueva
historia general del Per�: Un compendio. Lima: Mosca Azul
Editores, 1980.
Macera, Pablo. Trabajos de historia: Econom�a y sociedad.
Lima: Instituto Nacional de Cultura, 1977.
Mallon, Florencia E. The Defense of Community in Peru's Central
Highlands: Peasant Struggle and Capitalist Transition, 1860-
1940. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1983.
Manrique, Nelson. Campesinado y naci�n: Las guerillas ind�genas
en la guerra con Chile. Lima: Centro de Investigaci�n y
Capacitaci�n/Editora Ital Per�, 1981.
------. Mercado interno y regi�n: La sierra central, 1820-
1930. Lima: Centro de Estudios y Promoci�n de Desarrollo,
1987.
------. Yawar Mayu: Sociedades terratenientes serranas, 1879-
1910. Lima: Institut fran�ais d'�tudes andines, Cento de
Investigaci�n y Capacitaci�n, 1988.
Mari�tegui, Jos� Carlos. Seven Interpretive Essays on Peruvian
Reality. Austin: University of Texas Press, 1971.
Masterson, Daniel M. Militarism and Politics in Latin America:
Peru from S�nchez Cerro to Sendero Luminoso. New York:
Greenwood Press, 1991.
Mathew, W.M. The House of Gibbs and the Peruvian Guano
Monopoly. London: Royal Historical Society, 1981.
Matos Mar, Jos�. Un desborde popular: El nuevo rostro del Per�
en la d�cada de 1980. Lima: Instituto de Estudios
Peruanos, 1984.
McClintock, Cynthia. Peasant Cooperatives and Political Change
in Peru. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1981.
------. "Why Peasants Rebel: The Case of Peru's Sendero Luminoso."
World Politics 37, No. 1, October 1984, 48-84.
McClintock, Cynthia, and Abraham Lowenthal (eds.). The Peruvian
Experiment Reconsidered. (2d ed.) Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1983.
Mej�a Baca, Juan (ed.). Historia del Per�. (12 vols.)
Lima: Editorial Mej�a Baca, 1980.
Miller, Roy, (ed.). Region and Class in Modern Peruvian
History. Liverpool: Institute of Latin American Studies,
University of Liverpool, 1987.
M�rner, Magnus. The Andean Past: Land, Societies,
Conflicts. New York: Columbia University Press, 1985.
Murra, John V. "Andean Societies Before 1532." Pages 59-90 in
Leslie Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin
America, 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984.
------. Research in Economic Anthropology: The Economic
Organization of the Inka State. Supplement I. Greenwich,
Connecticut: JAI Press, 1980.
North, Liisa. The Peruvian Revolution and the Officers in
Power, 1967-1976. Montreal: Centre for Developing-Area
Studies, McGill University, 1981.
O'Donnell, Guillermo. Modernization and Bureaucratic
Authoritarianism: Studies in South American Politics.
Berkeley, California: Institute of International Studies,
University of California, 1973.
O'Phelan Godoy, Scarlett. Rebellions and Revolts in Eighteenth-
Century Peru and Upper Peru. Colongne: Bohlau, 1985.
Palmer, David Scott. "The Origins and Evolution of Sendero
Luminoso." Comparative Politics 18, No. 2, January
1986, 127-146.
------. Peru: The Authoritarian Tradition. New York:
Praeger, 1980.
Pastor, Manuel, Jr., and Carol Wise. "Peruvian Economic Policy in
the 1980s: From Orthodoxy to Heterodoxy and Back," Latin
American Research Review, 27, No. 2, 1992, 83-117.
Pease, Franklin, G.Y. Del Tawantinsuyu � la historia del
Per�. Lima: Fondo Editorial, 1989.
Peru. Instituto Nacional Estad�stica. Poblaci�n total proyecta
da al 30 de junio de 1990. Lima: 1989.
Pike, Frederick B. The Politics of the Miraculous in Peru: Haya
de la Torre and the Spiritualist Tradition. Lincoln:
University of Nebraska Press, 1986.
------. The United States and the Andean Republics: Peru,
Bolivia, and Ecuador. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press, 1977.
Preeg, Ernest H. The Evolution of a Revolution: Peru and Its
Relations with the United States, 1968-1980. Washington:
NPA Committee on Changing International Realities, 1981.
Prescott, William H. History of the Conquest of Peru. New
York: Modern Library, 1936.
Quiroz, Alfonso W. La deuda defraudada: Consolidaci�n de 1850
y dominio econ�mico en el Per�. Lima: Instituto Nacional
de Cultura/Editorial y Productora Gr�fica "Nuevo Mundo," 1987.
------. Banqueros en conflicto: Estructura financiera y
econom�a peruana, 1884-1930. Lima: Centro de
Investigaci�n/Universidad del Pac�fico, 1989.
Ramirez-Horton, Susan E. Land Tenure and the Economics of Power
in Colonial Peru. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press,
1977.
------. Provincial Patriarchs: Land Tenure and the Economics of
Power in Colonial Peru. Albuquerque: University of New
Mexico Press, 1986.
Reid, Michael. Peru: Paths to Poverty. London: Latin
America Bureau/Third World Publications, 1985.
R�nique C., Jos� Luis. Los sue�os de la sierra: Cusco en el
siglo XX. Lima: CEPES, 1991.
Rodr�guez Pastor, Humberto. Hijos del celeste imperio en el
Per� (1850-1900): Migraci�n, agricultura, mentalidad, y
explotaci�n. Lima: Instituto de Apoyo Agrario, 1989.
Rostworowski de Diez Canseco, Mar�a. Do�a Francesca Pizarro:
una ilustre mestiza, 1534-1598. Lima: Instituto de
Estudios Peruanos, 1989.
S�nchez Albornoz, Nicol�s. Indios y tributos en el Alto
Per�. Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, 1978.
Scheetz, Thomas. Peru and the International Monetary Fund.
Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1986.
Sempat Assadourian, Carlos. El sistema de la econom�a colonial:
Mercado interno, regiones y espacio econ�mico. Lima:
Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, 1982.
Silverblatt, Irene M. Moon, Sun, and Witches: Gender Ideologies
and Class in Inca and Colonial Peru. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1987.
Soto, Hernando de. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in
the Third World. New York: Harper and Row, 1990.
Spalding, Karen. Huarochir�: An Andean Society under Inca and
Spanish Rule. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1984.
Stein, Steve. Lima obrera 1900-1930. (2 vols.) Lima:
Ediciones El Virrey, 1986-87.
------. Populism in Peru: The Emergence of the Masses and the
Politics of Social Control. Madison: University of
Wisconsin Press, 1980.
Stein, Steve, and Carlos Monge. La cr�sis del estado
patrimonial en el Per�. Lima: Instituto de Estudios
Peruanos, 1988.
Stein, William W. El levantamiento de Atuspar�a. Lima:
Mosca Azul, 1988.
Stepan, Alfred. The State and Society: Peru in Comparative
Perspective. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978.
Stern, Steve J. Peru's Indian Peoples and the Challenge of
Spanish Conquest: Huamanga to 1640. Madison: University
of Wisconsin Press, 1982.
Stern, Steve J. (ed.). Resistance, Rebellion and Consciousness
in the Andean Peasant World, 18th to 20th Centuries.
Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1987.
Sulmont, Denis. El movimiento obrero peruano, 1890-1979.
Lima: Tarea, 1985.
Tamayo Herrera, Jos�. Historia social del Cuzco
republicano. (2d ed.) Lima: Editorial Universo, 1981.
Tarazona-Sevillano, Gabriela. Sendero Luminoso and the Threat
of Narcoterrorism. New York: Praeger, 1990.
Taylor, Lewis. Bandits and Politics in Peru: Landlord and
Peasant Violence in Hualgayoc, 1900-30. Cambridge: Center
of Latin American Studies, Cambridge University, 1987.
Thorp, Rosemary, and Geoffrey Bertram. Peru 1890-1977: Growth
and Policy in an Open Economy. New York: Columbia
University Press, 1978.
Uriarte, F. Manual. Transnational Banks and the Dynamics of
Peruvian Foreign Debt and Inflation. New York: Praeger,
1985.
Vega, Garcilaso de la. Royal Commentaries of the Incas and
General History of Peru. Austin: University of Texas
Press, 1987.
Villanueva, V�ctor. Ej�rcito Peruano: Del caudillaje an�rquico
al militarismo reformista. Lima: Juan Mej�a Baca, 1973.
------. "Military Professionalization in Peru." Pages 79-85 in
Brian Loveman and Thomas M. Davies, Jr. (eds.), The
Politics of Antipolitics. Lincoln: University of Nebraska
Press, 1978.
Wachtel, Nathan. The Vision of the Vanquished: The Spanish
Conquest of Peru Through Indian Eyes. New York: Barnes
and Noble, 1977.
------. "The Indian and Spanish Conquest." Pages 207-48 in Leslie
Bethell (ed.), Cambridge History of Latin America, 1.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984.
Webb, Richard C., and Graciela Fern�ndez Baca de Valdez (eds.).
Per� en n�meros, 1990: Almanaque estad�stico. Lima:
Cu�nto, 1990.
Webb, Richard, and Adolfo Figueroa. Distribuci�n del ingreso en
el Per�. Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, 1975.
Weeks, John. Limits to Capitalist Development: The
Industrialization of Peru, 1950-1980. Boulder, Colorado:
Westview Press, 1985.
Werlich, David P. Peru: A Short Hisotry. Carbondale:
Southern Illinois University Press, 1978.
Wightman, Ann M. Indigenous Migration and Social Change: The
Forasteros of Cuzco, 1570-1720. Durham: Duke University
Press, 1990.
Wilgus, Alva Curtis. Historical Atlas of Latin America:
Political, Geographic, Economic, Cultural. New York:
Cooper Square, 1967.
Yepes del Castillo, Ernesto. Per� 1820-1920: Un siglo de
desarollo capitalista? Lima: Ediciones SIGNO
Universitario, 1981.
Zook, David H., Jr. Zarumilla-Mara��n: The Ecuador-Peruvian
Border Dispute. New York: Bookman, 1964.
Zuidema, R. Tom. Inca Civilization in Cuzco. Austin:
University of Texas Press, 1990.
Peru